e8vk
UNITED STATES SECURITIES AND EXCHANGE COMMISSION
Washington, DC 20549
FORM 8-K
CURRENT REPORT
Pursuant to Section 13 or 15(d) of the Securities Exchange Act of 1934
December 5, 2005
Date of Report (Date of earliest event reported)
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Exact Name of Registrant as Specified in Its Charter; State of |
|
IRS Employer |
Commission File |
|
Incorporation; Address of Principal Executive Offices; and |
|
Identification |
Number |
|
Telephone Number |
|
Number |
1-16169
|
|
EXELON CORPORATION
|
|
23-2990190 |
|
|
(a Pennsylvania corporation) |
|
|
|
|
10 South Dearborn Street 37th Floor |
|
|
|
|
P.O. Box 805379 |
|
|
|
|
Chicago, Illinois 60680-5379 |
|
|
|
|
(312) 394-7398 |
|
|
1-1839
|
|
COMMONWEALTH EDISON COMPANY
|
|
36-0938600 |
|
|
(an Illinois corporation) |
|
|
|
|
10 South Dearborn Street 37th Floor |
|
|
|
|
P.O. Box 805379 |
|
|
|
|
Chicago, Illinois 60680-5379 |
|
|
|
|
(312) 394-4321 |
|
|
333-85496
|
|
EXELON GENERATION COMPANY, LLC
|
|
23-3064219 |
|
|
(a Pennsylvania limited liability company) |
|
|
|
|
300 Exelon Way |
|
|
|
|
Kennett Square, Pennsylvania 19348 |
|
|
|
|
(610) 765-6900 |
|
|
Check the appropriate box below if the Form 8-K filing is intended to simultaneously satisfy the
filing obligation of the registrant under any of the following provisions:
o Written communications pursuant to Rule 425 under the Securities Act (17 CFR 230.425)
o Soliciting material pursuant to Rule 14a-12 under the Exchange Act (17 CFR 240.14a-12)
o Pre-commencement communications pursuant to Rule 14d-2(b) under the Exchange Act (17 CFR 240.14d-2(b))
o Pre-commencement communications pursuant to Rule 13e-4(c) under the Exchange Act (17 CFR 240.13e-4(c))
Section 8 Other Events.
Item 8.01. Other Events.
Procurement Rider Case
As previously reported, on February 25, 2005, Commonwealth Edison Company (ComEd), a subsidiary of
Exelon Corporation (Exelon), made filings at the Illinois Commerce Commission (ICC) to commence a
proceeding (referred to as the Procurement Rider Case) to establish the process by which ComEd will
procure electricity beginning in 2007 and recover the costs from retail customers. In the
Procurement Rider Case, ComEd is seeking approval to use the results of a competitive bidding
process to procure electricity for its customers in the open market, using a reverse-auction
process, to set retail rates. In that process, qualified energy suppliers would compete in a
structured auction to provide energy to ComEd and its customers; the lowest bidders would provide
the power needed at the price determined by the auctions results; and ComEd would make no profit
on the energy but would fully recover from its customers the cost of procurement. The ICC staff
would oversee the entire process to assure a fair bidding process, and an auction manager would
manage the process. The ICC held hearings on the Procurement Rider Case, which concluded on
September 20, 2005.
On December 5, 2005, the ICCs Administrative Law Judge assigned to the Procurement Rider Case
issued a Proposed Order that recommended that the ICC approve a competitive procurement process
similar to the process that ComEd proposed. A copy of the Proposed Order is attached to this Report
on Form 8-K as Exhibit 99.1. The Proposed Order reaffirms earlier rulings by the Administrative Law
Judge and the ICC that the ICC has legal authority under the Public Utilities Act to approve the
auction and the resulting rates. The Proposed Order also increases regulatory oversight of the
process.
The parties to the Procurement Case must file exceptions to the Proposed Order by December 19,
2005, and replies to the exceptions must be filed by December 27, 2005. The ICCs final order is
expected in January 2006, although the timing of that order may depend on the outcome of pending
litigation (described in the Report on Form 8-K filed on October 14, 2005) challenging the ICCs
authority to act on ComEds proposal.
* * * * *
This combined Form 8-K is being furnished separately by Exelon, ComEd, and Exelon Generation
Company, LLC (Exelon Generation) (Registrants). Information contained herein relating to any
individual Registrant has been furnished by such Registrant on its own behalf. No Registrant makes
any representation as to information relating to any other Registrant.
Forward-Looking Statements
Except for the historical information contained herein, certain of the matters discussed in this
Report are forward-looking statements, within the meaning of the Private Securities Litigation
Reform Act of 1995, which are subject to risks and uncertainties. The factors that could cause
actual results to differ materially from the forward-looking statements made by a Registrant
include those factors discussed herein, as well as the items discussed in (a) Exelons 2004 Annual
Report on Form 10-KITEM 7. Managements Discussion and Analysis of Financial Condition and Results
of OperationsBusiness Outlook and the Challenges in Managing Our Business for each of Exelon,
ComEd and Exelon Generation, (b) Exelons 2004 Annual Report on Form 10-KITEM 8. Financial
Statements and Supplementary Data: ExelonNote 20, ComEdNote 15 and GenerationNote 16, (c)
Exelons Current Reports on Form 8-K filed on February 4, 2005 and May 13, 2005, including those
discussed in Exhibit 99.2 Managements Discussion and Analysis of Financial Condition and Results
of Operations Exelon Business Outlook and the Challenges in Managing the Business and
Exhibit 99.3 Financial Statements and Supplementary Data
Exelon Corporation, (d) Generations Current Report on Form 8-K filed on May 13, 2005, including
those discussed in Exhibit 99.5 Managements Discussion and Analysis of Financial Condition and
Results of Operation and Exhibit 99.6 Financial Statements and Supplementary Data and (e) other
factors discussed in filings with the SEC by Exelon, ComEd and Exelon Generation. Readers are
cautioned not to place undue reliance on these forward-looking statements, which apply only as of
the date of this Report. None of Exelon, ComEd, or Exelon Generation undertakes any obligation to
publicly release any revision to its forward-looking statements to reflect events or circumstances
after the date of this Report.
Item 9.01. Financial Statements and Exhibits.
(c) Exhibits.
|
|
|
Exhibit No. |
|
Description |
|
|
|
99.1
|
|
Proposed Order of ICC Administrative Law Judge, dated December 5, 2005 |
SIGNATURES
Pursuant to the requirements of the Securities Exchange Act of 1934, the registrant has duly caused
this report to be signed on its behalf by the undersigned hereunto duly authorized.
|
|
|
|
|
|
EXELON CORPORATION
EXELON GENERATION COMPANY, LLC
|
|
|
/s/ John F. Young
|
|
|
John F. Young |
|
|
Executive Vice President, Finance and Markets and
Chief Financial Officer |
|
|
|
COMMONWEALTH EDISON COMPANY
|
|
|
/s/ Robert K. McDonald
|
|
|
Robert K. McDonald |
|
|
Senior Vice President and Chief Financial Officer |
|
|
December 12, 2005
EXHIBIT INDEX
|
|
|
Exhibit No. |
|
Description |
|
|
|
99.1
|
|
Proposed Order of ICC Administrative Law Judge, dated December 5, 2005 |
exv99w1
STATE OF ILLINOIS
ILLINOIS COMMERCE COMMISSION
|
|
|
|
|
Commonwealth Edison Company
|
|
: |
|
|
|
|
: |
|
|
Proposal to implement a competitive procurement
|
|
:
|
|
05-0159 |
process by establishing Rider CPP, Rider PPO-MVM,
|
|
: |
|
|
Rider TR-CPP and revising Rider PPO-MI. (Tariffs
|
|
: |
|
|
filed February 25, 2005)
|
|
: |
|
|
|
|
: |
|
|
|
|
: |
|
|
PROPOSED ORDER
DATED: December 5, 2005
05-0159
Proposed Order
TABLE OF CONTENTS
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
1 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
1 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
4 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
9 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
9 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
9 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
9 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
10 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
11 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
12 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
12 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
13 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
14 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
15 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
15 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
16 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
16 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
23 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
26 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
28 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
30 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
34 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
36 |
|
i
05-0159
Proposed Order
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
36 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
36 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
39 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
42 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
45 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
47 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
48 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
48 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
50 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
50 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
53 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
55 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
56 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
56 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
56 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
56 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
56 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
57 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
57 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
57 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
57 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
58 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
58 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
58 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
58 |
|
ii
05-0159
Proposed Order
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
58 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
59 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
59 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
59 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
59 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
59 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
60 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
60 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
60 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
60 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
60 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
60 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
61 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
62 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
62 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
62 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
62 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
62 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
63 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
63 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
64 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
64 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
64 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
64 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
65 |
|
iii
05-0159
Proposed Order
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
65 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
65 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
66 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
66 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
66 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
68 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
69 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
69 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
69 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
70 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
71 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
71 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
71 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
71 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
72 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
72 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
73 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
73 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
74 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
74 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
74 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
74 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
75 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
75 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
76 |
|
iv
05-0159
Proposed Order
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
76 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
76 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
77 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
77 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
77 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
78 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
78 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
79 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
79 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
79 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
79 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
79 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
80 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
81 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
81 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
81 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
81 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
81 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
82 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
82 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
83 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
83 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
83 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
83 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
83 |
|
v
05-0159
Proposed Order
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
84 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
85 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
85 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
85 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
85 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
86 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
87 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
87 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
87 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
87 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
88 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
88 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
88 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
88 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
89 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
89 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
89 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
90 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
90 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
90 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
91 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
92 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
92 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
92 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
92 |
|
vi
05-0159
Proposed Order
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
92 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
93 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
93 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
93 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
93 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
93 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
94 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
94 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
94 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
94 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
95 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
95 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
95 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
95 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
95 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
95 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
95 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
96 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
96 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
97 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
97 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
100 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
100 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
100 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
100 |
|
vii
05-0159
Proposed Order
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
100 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
101 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
102 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
102 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
102 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
102 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
102 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
102 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
103 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
103 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
103 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
103 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
104 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
104 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
104 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
104 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
104 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
104 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
105 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
105 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
106 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
106 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
107 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
107 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
107 |
|
viii
05-0159
Proposed Order
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
107 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
108 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
108 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
108 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
108 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
108 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
109 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
109 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
109 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
109 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
109 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
110 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
110 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
111 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
111 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
111 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
112 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
112 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
112 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
112 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
113 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
113 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
114 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
114 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
114 |
|
ix
05-0159
Proposed Order
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
114 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
115 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
115 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
115 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
115 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
115 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
115 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
115 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
116 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
116 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
116 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
116 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
116 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
116 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
116 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
117 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
117 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
117 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
117 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
117 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
117 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
118 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
118 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
118 |
|
x
05-0159
Proposed Order
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
119 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
119 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
119 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
119 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
120 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
120 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
120 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
121 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
122 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
122 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
125 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
125 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
125 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
125 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
126 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
126 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
127 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
127 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
127 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
127 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
128 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
128 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
128 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
128 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
128 |
|
xi
05-0159
Proposed Order
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
128 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
129 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
129 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
129 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
129 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
129 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
129 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
129 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
131 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
133 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
135 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
135 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
136 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
136 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
137 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
139 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
139 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
139 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
139 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
140 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
140 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
141 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
141 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
142 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
143 |
|
xii
05-0159
Proposed Order
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
144 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
144 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
144 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
145 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
145 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
146 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
147 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
147 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
148 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
148 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
148 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
149 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
149 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
149 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
149 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
150 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
151 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
151 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
151 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
152 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
153 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
153 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
153 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
154 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
154 |
|
xiii
05-0159
Proposed Order
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
154 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
154 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
155 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
155 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
155 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
155 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
155 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
156 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
156 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
156 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
156 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
156 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
156 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
156 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
156 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
158 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
159 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
160 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
162 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
162 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
162 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
162 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
163 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
163 |
|
xiv
05-0159
Proposed Order
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
163 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
164 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
164 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
165 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
165 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
165 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
165 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
165 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
165 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
166 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
166 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
166 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
167 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
167 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
167 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
168 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
168 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
168 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
169 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
170 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
171 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
173 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
173 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
175 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
175 |
|
xv
05-0159
Proposed Order
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
175 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
176 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
177 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
177 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
179 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
180 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
181 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
182 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
183 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
183 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
183 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
184 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
185 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
186 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
187 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
187 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
188 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
188 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
193 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
199 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
202 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
202 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
204 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
205 |
|
xvi
05-0159
Proposed Order
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
205 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
205 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
207 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
208 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
209 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
209 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
209 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
209 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
210 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
211 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
212 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
212 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
212 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
213 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
215 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
216 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
218 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
218 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
218 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
221 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
222 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
222 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
223 |
|
xvii
05-0159
Proposed Order
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
224 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
225 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
225 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
225 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
227 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
227 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
227 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
228 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
228 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
228 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
229 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
229 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
229 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
230 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
230 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
230 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
230 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
231 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
231 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
232 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
232 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
232 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
233 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
233 |
|
xviii
05-0159
Proposed Order
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
233 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
233 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
234 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
234 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
235 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
235 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
235 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
236 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
236 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
236 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
236 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
236 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
236 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
237 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
237 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
238 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
238 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
239 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
239 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
239 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
239 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
239 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
239 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
239 |
|
xix
05-0159
Proposed Order
xx
STATE OF ILLINOIS
ILLINOIS COMMERCE COMMISSION
|
|
|
|
|
Commonwealth Edison Company
|
|
: |
|
|
|
|
: |
|
|
Proposal to implement a
|
|
:
|
|
05-0159 |
competitive procurement process
|
|
: |
|
|
by establishing Rider CPP, Rider
|
|
: |
|
|
PPO-MVM, Rider TR-CPP and
|
|
: |
|
|
revising Rider PPO-MI. (Tariffs filed
|
|
: |
|
|
February 25, 2005)
|
|
: |
|
|
PROPOSED ORDER
By the Commission:
I. EXECUTIVE SUMMARY
A. Procedural History
On February 25, 2005, Commonwealth Edison Company (ComEd) filed its Ill. C. C. No. 4,
Original Sheet Nos. 244 through 303; 6th Revised Sheet No. 151.1; 8th Revised Sheet No. 151.13; and
7th Revised Sheet No. 151.14, (collectively, the Procurement Tariffs or the Procurement Tariff
Sheets). This tariff filing embodied a proposal to implement, and use in setting retail rates
under the Commissions jurisdiction, the results of a wholesale competitive power procurement
process by establishing Rider CPP, Competitive Procurement Process (Rider CPP), Rider PPO-MVM
Power Purchase Option (Market Value Methodology (Rider PPO-MVM), and Rider TS-CPP -Transmission
Services (Competitive Procurement Process) (Rider TS-CPP), and by revising Rider PPO-MI Power
Purchase Option (Market Index) (Rider PPO-MI). The tariff filing was accompanied by direct
testimony and other exhibits.
Notice of the proposed tariff changes was posted in ComEds business offices and published in
a secular newspaper of general circulation in ComEds service area, as evidenced by publishers
certificates, in accordance with the requirements of Section 9-201(a) of the Public Utilities Act
(the Act or PUA), 220 ILCS 5/9-201(a), and the provisions of 83 Ill. Adm. Code Part 255.
The Illinois Commerce Commission (the Commission or ICC) issued a Suspension Order on
March 9, 2005, suspending the Procurement Tariff Sheets to and including July 24, 2005, and
thereafter, issued a Resuspension Order on July 13, 2005, suspending the proposed tariffs to and
including January 24, 2006.
Pursuant to notice duly given in accordance with the law and the rules and regulations of the
Commission, a pre-hearing conference was held in this matter before the duly authorized
Administrative Law Judge (the ALJ) of the Commission, at its
05-0159
Proposed Order
offices in Springfield, Illinois, on April 18, 2005. Ten days prior, notice of the prehearing
conference had been provided by the Chief Clerk of the Commission to municipalities in ComEds
service area in accordance with the requirements of Section 10-108 of the Act, 220 ILCS 5/10-108.
An additional pre-hearing conference was held before the ALJ at the Commissions Springfield office
on August 24, 2005.
Petitions to Intervene were filed on behalf of the Attorney General of the State of Illinois
(the Attorney General or the AG); Central Illinois Light Company d/b/a AmerenCILCO, Central
Illinois Public Services Company d/b/a Ameren CIPS, and Illinois Power Company d/b/a AmerenIP,
(styled collectively as Ameren Companies); Ameren Energy Marketing Company (AEM); BlueStar
Energy Services, Inc. (BlueStar); Building Owners and Managers Association of Chicago (BOMA);
the Citizens Utility Board (CUB); City of Chicago (the City); Constellation Energy Commodities
Group, Inc. (CCG); Constellation NewEnergy, Inc. (New Energy); the Cook County States
Attorneys Office (CCSAO) (collectively, CUB and CCSAO are CUB-CCSAO); Direct Energy Services,
LLC (DES); United States Department of Energy (DOE); Dynegy, Inc. (Dynegy); the Environmental
Law & Policy Center (ELPC); Electric Power Supply Association (EPSA); Illinois Energy
Association (IEA); Abbott Laboratories, Inc., Caterpillar Inc., Daimler Chrysler Corporation,
Cognix Corporation, Enbridge Energy LLP, Ford Motor Company, and Motorola, Inc., styled
collectively as the Illinois Industrial Energy Consumers (IIEC); J. Aron & Company (J. Aron);
MidAmerican Energy Company (MidAmerican); Midwest Generation EME, LLC (Midwest Gen or MWGen);
Morgan Stanley Capital Group, Inc. (MSCG); Midwest Independent Power Suppliers (MWIPS); Peoples
Energy Services Corporation (PES); Reliant Energy, Inc. (Reliant); Local Unions 15, 51, and
702, International Brotherhood of Electrical Workers, AFL-CIO (collectively, Locals 15, 51, 702,
IBEW); Sempra Energy Solutions (SES); U.S. Energy Savings Corporation (USESC) (collectively,
DES and USESC are DES-USESC) (collectively, New Energy, DES, MidAmerican, PES, and USESC are the
Coalition of Energy Suppliers or CES) (collectively, all of the foregoing parties are the
Intervenors).
Evidentiary hearings were held from August 29-September 2, September 6-9, 12, 14, and 20,
2005, at the offices of the Commission in Springfield, Illinois. At the evidentiary hearings,
ComEd, the Staff of the Commission (Staff), the AG, BOMA, CES, CNE, CUB-CCSAO, CCG, DES-USESC,
Dynegy, IIEC, Midwest Gen, PES, and the DOE entered appearances and presented testimony, either by
live witness(es) or by affidavit. Appearances were also entered for J. Aron, MSCG, the City, and
MWIPS, although they did not submit testimony. At the conclusion of the hearings, on September 20,
2005, the ALJ marked the record Heard and Taken.
The following witnesses testified on behalf of ComEd: Frank M. Clark, Jr., Executive Vice
President and Chief of Staff, Exelon Corporation (Exelon), and President, ComEd; Elizabeth A.
Moler, Executive Vice President for Government and Environmental Affairs & Public Policy, Exelon;
William P. McNeil, Director of Regulatory Strategy, ComEd; Chantale LaCasse, Ph.D., Vice President,
National Economic Research Associates, Inc. (NERA); Steven T. Naumann, P.E., Vice President of
Wholesale Market Development, Exelon; Michael M. Schnitzer, Director, NorthBridge
2
05-0159
Proposed Order
Group, Inc; Lawrence S. Alongi, Manager of Distribution Rate Design and Administration, ComEd,
and Paul R. Crumrine, Director of Regulatory Strategies & Services, ComEd (jointly); William W.
Hogan, Ph.D., Lucius N. Littauer Professor of Public Policy and Administration, the John F. Kennedy
School of Government of Harvard University, Research Director, Harvard Electricity Policy Group,
and Director, LECG, LLC; Arlene A. Juracek, P.E., Vice President of Energy Acquisition, ComEd and
Exelon Energy Delivery LLC; Andrew Parece, Managing Principal, Analysis Group, Inc.; William H.
Hieronymus, Vice President, CRA International; and Kevin J. Waden, C.P.A., Director of Financial
Reporting and Accounting Research, Exelon Energy Delivery Company.
The following witnesses testified on behalf of the Staff: David J. Salant, Principal, ERS
Group, Adjunct Senior Research Scholar, Columbia Business School, Research Professor, Clemson
University; David S. Sibley, John Michael Stuart Centennial Professor of Economics, the University
of Texas at Austin; Scott A. Struck, CPA, Supervisor, Accounting Department, Financial Analysis
Division; Richard J. Zuraski, Senior Economist, Policy Program, Energy Division; Serhan Ogur,
Economic Analyst, Federal Energy Program, Energy Division; Eric P. Schlaf, Senior Economic Analyst,
Energy Division; Peter Lazare, Senior Rate Analyst, Financial Analysis Division; Cheri L. Harden,
Rate Analyst, Rate Department, Financial Analysis Division; Mary E. Selvaggio, CPA, Manager,
Accounting Department, Financial Analysis Division; Steven R. Knepler, CPA, Supervisor, Accounting
Department, Financial Analysis Division; Rochelle Phipps, Senior Financial Analyst, Finance
Department, Financial Analysis Division.
The AGs witnesses were Kenneth Rose, Ph.D, consultant, lecturer, Institute of Public
Utilities, Michigan State University; Harvey Salgo, Esq., Principal Consultant, La Capra
Associates; David Effron, CPA, Regulatory Consultant, Berkshire Consulting Services; and Philip
Reny, Ph.D., Professor of Economics, the University of Chicago.
BOMAs witnesses were Arthur B. Laffer, Chairman, Laffer Associates; and T.J. Brookover,
Senior Vice President & Director of Property Management, The John Buck Company, and Kristav M.
Childress, Technical Director, GEV Corp. (jointly).
CCGs witness was Michael D. Smith, Vice President, Regulatory and Legislative Affairs.
CESs witnesses were Philip R. OConnor, Ph.D., Vice President, Illinois Market, NewEnergy;
Mario Bohorquez, Director of Supply, Illinois Market, NewEnergy, and Wayne Bollinger, Director of
Energy Supply, PES (jointly); and John L. Domagalski, NewEnergy, and Richard S. Spilky, Director of
Electric Products, MidAmerican (jointly).
CUB-CCSAOs witnesses were Robert M. Fagan, Senior Associate, Synapse Energy Economics, and
William Steinhurst, Senior Consultant, Synapse Energy Economics, Inc.
3
05-0159
Proposed Order
DES-USESCs witness was James Steffes, Vice President, US Government & Regulatory Affairs and
Chief Compliance Officer, DES.
Dynegys witness was Barry Huddleston, Senior Director, Governmental and Regulatory Affairs.
IIEC submitted testimony of Robert R. Stephens, Consultant, Brubaker & Associates, Inc.; James
R. Dauphinais, Consultant, Brubaker & Associates, Inc.; and Brian C. Collins, Consultant, Brubaker
& Associates, Inc.
Midwest Gen submitted testimony of Frank C. Graves, Principal, The Brattle Group.
PES submitted the testimony of Wayne Bollinger, which was separate from the joint testimony
for the same witness that CES submitted.
DOE submitted the testimony of Dale E. Swan, Senior Economist and Principal, Exeter
Associates, Inc., Mathew I. Kahal, Consultant, Exeter Associates, Inc.
B. Testimony, Motions and Rulings
On February 25, 2005, ComEd filed its direct testimony concurrently with its tariff filing.
It presented direct testimony for each of its witnesses listed above, except Ms. Juracek, Mr.
Parece, and Dr. Hieronymus (who each submitted only rebuttal and surrebuttal testimony) and Mr.
Waden (who submitted only surrebuttal testimony).
On March 23, 2005, ComEd filed a Motion for Entry of a Case Management Order (the Motion for
Case Management Order), requesting a pre-hearing conference and entry of a case management order.
Also on March 23, 2005, ComEd filed a Motion for a Protective Order (the Motion for
Protective Order), requesting a protective order be entered pursuant to 220 ILCS 5/4-404 and 83
Ill. Adm. Code 200.430(a).
On March 25, 2005, the Commission issued notice of an April 8, 2005 hearing.
On March 29, 2005, Staff filed a Motion to Consolidate Dockets 05-0128, 05-0159, 05-0160,
05-0161, and 05-0162, pursuant to 83 Ill. Adm. Code 200.600 (the Motion to Consolidate).
On April 6, 2005, ComEd filed a response to the Motion to Consolidate, opposing Staffs
Motion. ComEd urged coordination rather than consolidation.
Also on April 6, 2005, IIEC filed a response to the Motion to Consolidate in support of the
Motion, and the AG, the City, CUB, and ELPC filed a Motion to file their response Instanter, after
notice from the ALJ that filing an informal response not opposing the Motion to Consolidate in part
was insufficient.
4
05-0159
Proposed Order
On April 8, 2005, Staff filed a reply in support of the Motion to Consolidate. Also on April
8, 2005, the Ameren Companies filed a response to the same Motion, arguing that the Motion depended
on mere speculation that ComEd and the Ameren Companies would raise the same issues.
On April 12, 2005, the ALJ denied the Motion to Consolidate.
On April 15, 2005, IIEC, Staff, Midwest Gen, the AG, the City, CUB, and ELPC (collectively,
the Government, Consumer and Environmental Parties (or GCE Parties), and the AG filed their
responses to the Motion for Protective Order. IIEC did not object to the Motion, and Staff
recommended modifications to the language of the proposed protective order.
Also on April 15, 2005, IIEC, Staff, Midwest Gen, and CES filed responses to the Motion for
Case Management Order and Coordinated Schedule. IIEC, Staff, and CES argued for elongating the
period for discovery.
On April 18, 2005, CCSAO filed a response to the Motion for Protective Order, seeking language
to exempt enforcement actions from such Order.
Also on April 18, 2005, the GCE Parties filed a response to the Motion for Case Management
Order, objecting to the parameters for data requests and the length of the discovery period.
On April 19, 2005, Dynegy filed a response to Motion for CMO and Coordinated Schedule.
Also on April 19, 2005, ComEd filed its reply in support of the Motion for Protective Order
and the Motion for Case Management Order and Coordinated Schedule.
On April 22, 2005, the ALJ issued a ruling, granting the Motion for Case Management Order, and
enumerating procedures to govern the case. Concurrently, the ALJ set forth the Coordinated
Schedule.
On April 26, 2005, the ALJ issued a ruling, granting the Motion for Protective Order.
On May 17, 2005, the AG, CCSAO, CUB, and ELPC filed a Motion to Dismiss the portion of the
proceeding related to ComEds Rider CPP (the Motion to Dismiss), claiming that such Rider
violates the consumer protections provisions in the Act reserving cost-based service to those
commercial and industrial customers whose service has not been declared competitive, and asserting
that the Act did not grant the Commission authority to approve a competitive procurement process
for customers whose service has not been declared competitive.
5
05-0159
Proposed Order
On May 25, 2005, BOMA filed a reply to the Motion to Dismiss, supporting the AG, CCSAO, CUB,
and ELPCs assertion that the Commission lacked the authority to approve Rider CPP.
Also on May 25, 2005, Locals 15, 51, 702, IBEW filed a response supporting the Motion to
Dismiss.
Also on May 25, 2005, ComEd and IEA both filed Oppositions to the Motion to Dismiss. ComEd
noted that the movants mischaracterized market-based rates as being distinct from the utilitys
costs, failed to acknowledge that the Procurement Tariffs recovered ComEds actual costs, and
explained that the Commissions authority to approve the auction system embodied in Rider CCP is
within its clear authority to approve cost recovery mechanisms under Articles IX and XVI of the
Act.
Additionally on May 25, 2005, Staff filed a response opposing the Motion to Dismiss on the
grounds that ComEds filing provides sufficient information for the Commission to determine whether
rates determined by the procurement process are just and reasonable. Also on May 25, 2005, Midwest
Gen, Ameren Companies, EPSA, MWIPS, New Energy, MidAmerican, PES, and USESC filed responses to the
Motion to Dismiss, opposing the Motion.
On June 1, 2005, the AG, CCSAO, CUB, and ELPC filed a reply in support of the Motion to
Dismiss, arguing that ComEds proposal does not allow the Commission an opportunity to review the
costs for fairness and reasonability and forces market-based rates on customers whose service has
not been determined competitive.
Also on June 1, 2005, the ALJ issued a Ruling denying the Motion to Dismiss. In the Ruling,
the ALJ found that market-based prices like those proposed in the Procurement Tariffs are one
method of a utilitys determining costs, and are not a mutually-exclusive replacement for
cost-based rates.
On June 8, 2005, Staff and Intervenors (other than J. Aron, MSCG, MWIPS, and EPSA) filed
direct testimony for all of their respective witnesses listed above, except Mr. Effron, Mr. Reny,
and Ms. Phipps (each of whom submitted rebuttal testimony).
On June 22, 2005, the AG, CCSAO, CUB, and ELPC filed a Petition for Interlocutory Review of
the ALJs Ruling denying, the Motion to Dismiss (the Petition for Interlocutory Review), arguing
that the Ruling misinterpreted Section 16-103(c) of the Act and that market-based pricing is not
reflective of costs where they are set in a less than fully competitive market.
On June 28, 2005, the Commission, on its own motion, ordered that an oral argument on the
Petition for Interlocutory Review be held on July 5, 2005.
On June 29, 2005, ComEd and Midwest Gen filed their responses to the Petition for
Interlocutory Review. Also on June 29, 2005, BOMA filed a reply to the Petition for Interlocutory
Review. Also on June 29, 2005, Locals 15, 51, 702, IBEW filed their response in support of the
same Petition. Also on June 29, 2005, the AG filed a Motion
6
05-0159
Proposed Order
to Reschedule and Clarify Scope of Oral Argument, seeking a later date for the argument and to
confine the argument to the issue whether the Act grants the Commission authority to approve
market-based rates for customers whose service is not declared competitive.
On June 30, 2005, ComEd and Locals 15, 51, 702, IBEW filed their responses to the Motion to
Reschedule and Clarify Scope of Oral Argument.
On July 1, 2005 the Commission denied the Motion to Reschedule and Clarify Scope of Oral
Argument by the AG.
On July 5, 2005, the Commission held oral argument on the Petition for Interlocutory Review.
On July 6, 2005 ComEd filed rebuttal testimony for all of its witness listed above except Mr.
Clark, Ms. Moler, and Mr. Schnitzer, and Mr. Waden.
On July 13, 2005, the Commission denied the Petition for Interlocutory Review.
On July 27, 2005, the AG, CCSAO, and CUB filed a Motion to Clarify the Place of Hearing and
Request the Place of Hearing Be at the Commission in Chicago (the Motion to Clarify) for the
convenience of the parties and their counsel.
On August 3, 2005, the AG, BOMA, CCG, CES, CUB, DES-USESC, Dynegy, IIEC, Midwest Gen, PES, and
Staff filed rebuttal testimony of all of their witnesses listed above except Messrs. Swan and
Kahal.
On August 4, 2005, the Ameren Companies and Staff filed a response in opposition to the Motion
to Clarify. Also on August 4, 2005, ComEd filed a response to the Motion to Clarify, taking no
position, and the DOE filed a response in support of the Motion to Clarify.
On August 10, the AG, CCSAO, and CUB filed a reply to the Motion to Clarify.
On August 12, 2005, the ALJ issued a ruling denying the Motion to Clarify.
On August 16, 2005, the CCSAO and CUB filed a Motion in Limine to Bar Witnesses from being
Cross Examined Simultaneously in this Matter with any Other Matter of the Cook County States
Attorneys Office and the Citizens Utility Board (the Motion to Bar), which Motion CCSAO and CUB
based on the ALJs ruling denying consolidation.
On August 18, 2005, the AG and CCSAO filed a Petition for Interlocutory Review of Request that
Hearings Be Held in Chicago (the Chicago Petition for Interlocutory Review), arguing that the
location convenient for some of the parties is in the public interest.
7
05-0159
Proposed Order
Also on August 19, 2005, ComEd filed its surrebuttal testimony for all of its witnesses listed
above, except Mr. Clark, Ms. Moler, and Mr. Schnitzer.
On August 22, 2005, CCSAO and CUB filed their joint reply to the responses to Motion to Bar.
On August 22, 2005, Staff filed its reply to responses to Motion to Bar.
On August 23, 2005, the ALJ denied the Motion to Bar.
Also on August 23, 2005, the AG, CCSAO, CUB, and ELPC filed a Motion in Limine to Exclude
Testimony Regarding the Post 2006 Workshops (Motion to Exclude).
On August 24, 2005, Ameren Companies, ComEd, and Staff filed responses to the Chicago Petition
for Interlocutory Review.
On August 25, 2005, the Commission issued a notice denying the Chicago Petition for
Interlocutory Review.
On August 26, 2005, the Ameren Companies, ComEd, IIEC, CES, and Staff filed responses to the
Motion to Exclude.
Also on August 26, the ALJ issued a Ruling denying the Motion to Exclude.
On September 20, 2005, during a hearing, the ALJ issued a schedule for post-hearing briefs and
party-proposed draft orders. On September 21, 2005, ComEd filed an outline for the post-hearing
briefs, which the ALJ adopted on September 23, 2005. On September 27 and 28, 2005, IIEC and Staff
filed motions to amend the brief outline.
On October 3, and again on October 12, 2005, ComEd filed a Motion to Correct the Transcript of
Hearings.
On October 7, 2005, initial post-hearing briefs were submitted respectively by ComEd, Staff,
the AG, CUB, DOE, IIEC, MSCG, PES, CES, CCG, DES-USESC, Dynegy, Midwest Gen, CCSAO, and BOMA.
On October 14, 2005, ComEd, MWGen, BOMA and the AG filed their respective proposed orders. On
October 27, 2005, ComEd, DOE, CCSAO, Dynegy, MWIPS, IIEC, CES, DES/USESC, MWGen, MSCG, BOMA, the
AG, CUB and Staff filed their respective post-hearing reply briefs.
On November 23, 2005, the ALJ granted the various motions to correct the transcript.
On December 5, 2005, the ALJ served a proposed order on the parties.
8
05-0159
Proposed Order
II. NEED FOR COMMISSION ACTION
The parties devoted some thought to the need for Commission action concerning the filed
tariffs. ComEd insisted that because it owns no generating assets of its own, it must purchase the
power and energy necessary to serve its customers at wholesale. ComEd notes that it currently
handle this purchasing through a contract which will expire at the end of 2006 and ComEd will
thereafter need to purchase power and energy in the wholesale market.
ComEd, in additional to other parties such as the Coalition of Energy Suppliers and MidWest
Generation urge the Commission to approve tariffs embodying a procurement methodology that both
secures reliable supply and results in reasonable and stable retail prices in the post-transition
period in accordance with the intent of the Illinois Electric Service Customer Choice and Rate
Relief Law of 1997, 220 ILCS 5/16-101 et seq. (the 1997 Law or the 1997 Restructuring Law). To
meet that requirement, ComEd has filed tariffs embodying the competitive procurement auction.
The AG asserts that the only action that the Commission needs to take in connection with this
docket is to permanently suspend the tariffs ComEd has filed. According to the AG the Commission
does not need to approve ComEds proposal. Moreover, the AG argues that the Commission need not
and should not pre-approve any other method of procuring electricity for 2007 and beyond.
The AG argues that the Commission must also continue to regulate rates pursuant to 220 ILCS 5/
9-101 and 9-201, and continue to enforce the other consumer protection provisions in the PUA.
The Commission concludes that it has to act upon the tariffs filed by ComEd and that action is
set forth in the following sections of this order.
III. LEGAL ISSUES
|
A. |
|
Background: The Illinois Electric Service Customer Choice and Rate Relief Law
of 1997 |
For the most part, the Section III.A of the parties briefs is titled, Background: the
Illinois Electric Service Customer Choice and Rate Relief Law of 1997, 220 ILCS 5/16-101 et seq.
The parties comments are summarized below. Unless otherwise indicated, assertions contained in
these summaries represent the positions of the parties, not findings by the Commission.
ComEd states that in 1997, the General Assembly radically transformed the electric services
industry in Illinois through the 1997 Law. The 1997 Law brought about immediate and substantial
benefits for consumers, including the largest guaranteed
9
05-0159
Proposed Order
residential rate reductions in the country. ComEd was required to reduce its residential rates by
20%. In addition, tariffed electricity rates for traditional bundled customers have been frozen
for residential customers, at the reduced level for almost a decade, from 1997 through 2006.
This rate reduction and freeze have saved residential and other customers three billion dollars
statewide.
As part of the transition to competitive markets for electricity in Illinois, the 1997 Law
specifically authorized electric utilities to reorganize their businesses and to divest generation
assets (the plants that generate electricity) with defined, but limited, Commission oversight of
those transactions. Section 16-111(g) authorizes a utility to implement a reorganization and to
sell, assign, lease or otherwise transfer assets to an affiliated or unaffiliated entity. While
providing for Commission review, the General Assembly expressly chose to authorize Commission
disapproval of such asset divestiture only if the agency found that the transaction would render
the utility unable to provide safe and reliable service, or would result in a strong likelihood
that the utility could seek a base rate increase during the mandatory transition period.
With regard to the divestitures allowed by the statute, the 1997 Law further provides that
once the Commission approves a utilitys sale or transfer of its generation assets, [t]he
Commission shall not in any subsequent proceeding or otherwise, review such a reorganization or
other transaction authorized by this Section. Rather, Section 16-111(i) directs that, after the
mandatory transition period, the Commission, in any proceeding to establish rates and charges for
tariffed services offered by an electric utility, shall consider only . . . the then current or
projected revenues, costs, investments and cost of capital directly or indirectly associated with
the provision of such tariffed services . . . .
In accordance with the statutory grant of authority in Section 16-111(g), ComEd has fully
divested its generation assets, selling some, and transferring others to an affiliated entity. As
the Commission recognized in approving these divestitures, it was fully understood that as a result
of the divestitures, subsequent to 2006, [ComEd] would obtain all of its supply from market
forces. (In re Commonwealth Edison Co., Proceeding Pursuant to Section 16-111(g), 2000 Ill. PUC
LEXIS 667 at 6, Aug. 17, 2000) In sum, in order to meet its ongoing mandatory service obligations,
see 220 ILCS 5/16-103, ComEd now must purchase the electricity needed to serve its customers. It
has been understood since the time ComEd divested its generation assets that, beginning in 2007,
ComEd would purchase that electricity at prices determined by market forces.
The AG avers that the PUA is based on the premise that the health, welfare and prosperity of
all Illinois citizens require the provision of adequate, efficient, reliable, environmentally safe
and least-cost public utility services at prices which accurately reflect the long-term cost of
such services and which are equitable to all citizens. The public has a strong interest in
utility services that are affordable, efficient and reliable.
10
05-0159
Proposed Order
The AG continues stating that the Act establishes a comprehensive regulatory scheme to review the
costs incurred by utilities and to set rates paid by consumers so that consumers of essential,
monopoly utility services are protected from unfair pricing.
The AG maintains that the 1997 Amendments reiterated and confirmed these goals. In section
16-101A, the General Assembly found that [w]ith the advent of increasing competition in this
industry, the State has a continued interest in assuring that the safety, reliability, and
affordability of electrical power is not sacrificed to competitive pressures, and to that end,
intends to implement safeguards to assure that the industry continues to operate the electrical
system in a manner that will serve the publics interest. (220 ILCS 5/16-101A(c)) While noting
that the ICC should act to promote effectively competitive electricity markets, the General
Assembly also concluded, Consumer protections must be in place to ensure that all customers
continue to receive safe, reliable, affordable, and environmentally safe electric service.
CCSAO asserts that the Choice Act did not initially amend Section 9-101, Section 9-102,
Section 9-103, Section 9-104, and Section 9-201 of the Act. These sections ultimately provide
consumers with a variety of protections, including: i) that all rates be just and reasonable, ii)
requirements on filing with the Commission and making publicly available schedules showing all
rates, iii) the filing at the Commission of contracts related to any service, and iv) the ability
to suspend a rate filing for a period of up to 11 months. CCSAO maintains that in determining the
current law, care needs to be taken to determine whether a particular provision of the customer
choice law has superseded any of the other provisions of the Public Utilities Act.
CCSAO believes that what is clear is that the while the General Assembly provided the electric
utilities with certain opportunities in the Act it did not remove the traditional ratemaking
provisions available to residential and small commercial customers in Article IX. According to
CCSAO, rates and supporting materials need to be provided to the Commission and the Commission
needs to determine whether rates are just and reasonable. CCSAO notes that the Commission has in
this case utilized one of the tools of Article 9 and suspended ComEds filing in order to have a
hearing on the filing. The Commission needs to demand compliance with Article IX.
CCSAO is not seeking review of the reorganization, but rather is asking the Commission to look
at the consequences of the divestiture when setting rates. CCSAO asserts that rates need to be
just and reasonable and that ComEd is not entitled under the law for ratepayers to pay whatever it
spends to acquire power as a result of that decision unless the rates are just and reasonable and
in compliance with Illinois law.
CCSAO argues that ComEds tariff fails to show precisely what those costs will actually be.
CCSAO concludes that ComEds proposal ultimately requires the Commission to take on faith that the
auction will result in a just and reasonable rate.
11
05-0159
Proposed Order
Staff notes that the Electric Service Customer Choice and Rate Relief Law of 1997 (referred to
by Staff as the Restructuring Law) implemented an unprecedented restructuring of the States
electric utility industry. Among other things, the Restructuring Law established a transition
period during which the pre-existing bundled rates for non-residential customers would remain
frozen at pre-1997 rates, and pre-existing bundled rates for residential customers would remain
frozen at pre-1997 rates less a percentage reduction (a 20% reduction in ComEds case) through the
end of 2006.
Staff further notes that with ComEds divesting itself of its generating assets as permitted
under the Restructuring Law, the question becomes with the transition period and ComEds purchase
power arrangements ending December 31, 2006, ComEd and similarly situated utilities will still have
to satisfy its obligation to provide power and energy to its customers.
IIEC maintains that under the Customer Choice Law, utilities are required to offer delivery
service, so that end-use customers could choose suppliers, other than the electric utility, for
their electric power and energy requirements.
IIEC notes that base rates were frozen for all customers and rates were reduced by 20% for
residential customers in the ComEd service territory. Also, utilities were given the option to
avoid the rate decrease and rate freeze but if they did they were required to file biennial rate
case proceedings without regard to whether the filing would produce a rate increase or decrease.
IIEC further notes that utilities were given the option to reorganize and restructure their
businesses and the right to collect transition charges to allow them to collect the cost of
investments they believed would be stranded or otherwise unrecoverable, if customers were allowed
to choose a supplier other than an electric utility.
To allow utilities to respond to compete with third party suppliers, the General Assembly
granted the utilities the right to request that the Commission declare a tariffed service or
services competitive. Utilities on the other hand, were required to . . . continue offering to
retail customers each tariff service that it offered as a distinct and identifiable service on the
effective date of the Amendatory Act of 1997 until the service . . . was declared competitive or
abandoned.
In adopting of the Customer Choice Law, the General Assembly expressed the intention that all
customers benefit, in an equitable and timely fashion, from lower costs of electricity that would
result from retail and wholesale competition. The
12
05-0159
Proposed Order
General Assembly intended that the . . . competitive wholesale and retail market . . . benefit
all Illinois citizens.
IIEC argues that the retail market in the ComEd service territory has not developed in a
manner that ensures all citizens in the ComEd service territory will receive the benefits of
effectively competitive wholesale and retail markets. IIEC asserts that the ComEd proposal does
not allow all of its customers to benefit from the wholesale and retail markets. Nor does it
permit all customers to benefit from the lower cost of electricity derived from retail and
wholesale competition. IIEC notes that ComEd specifically proposes to deny its largest customers
(3 MW and over) access to the lowest discoverable wholesale price, which it claims will be produced
by its recommended auction process.
CES states that the enactment of the Customer Choice Law in 1997 signaled the beginning of a
complex, multi-faceted transformation of the electric industry in Illinois. The scope of this
ongoing transformation has affected all stakeholders, including consumers, utilities, alternative
retail electric suppliers, governmental agencies, and other interested parties.
CES ran through a summarization of the Customer Choice Law in the following paragraphs.
Through the Customer Choice Law, the General Assembly provided a clear policy directive to the
Commission: The Illinois Commerce Commission should act to promote the development of an
effectively competitive market that operates efficiently and is equitable to all consumers. Thus,
the General Assembly has endorsed the concept that the Commission, in establishing just and
reasonable rates, must take affirmative action to ensure the development of an effectively
competitive market for retail electricity in Illinois.
The Customer Choice Law reflects the General Assemblys belief that Illinois retail electric
customers will benefit from competition because competition will lower rates more effectively than
regulation. The goal of restructuring the electric industry is to introduce competition to a
formerly noncompetitive, monopolistic market so that consumers will experience the benefits of
competition. Only if the Commission continues to foster a competition-enabling environment will
consumers have meaningful choices and reasonable opportunities to achieve savings over the rates
derived through a traditional rate of return regulatory process.
The Customer Choice Law provides that, in the event that utilities do not own generation and
must acquire supply in the wholesale market, the price of the wholesale supply should have a
reasonable relationship to the costs indicated by the Commission approved market value energy
charge (MVEC) methodology. (220 ILCS 5/16-111(i)); The Choice Law further provides that the MVEC
methodology can rely on a variety of inputs, including contracts applicable to the utilitys
service areas. (220 ILCS 5/16-112(a)) The auction proposed by ComEd would yield such energy
contracts.
13
05-0159
Proposed Order
CES maintains that one of the important features of the Customer Choice Law is the section
providing that utilities may request that certain rates be declared competitive. (220 ILCS
5/16-113; CES Ex. 4.0 at lines 743-53) The Commission utilized the competitive declaration
provision of the Act in ICC Docket No. 02-0479, in which the Commission issued an Order finding
that ComEd no longer would have an obligation to provide a bundled service supply product to
certain classes of customers, because the competitive market had developed to the point that such
customers could reliably expect to find comparable and alternative energy service products in the
markets.
CES asserts that the Commission should reject any proposals (whether explicit or not) to
rescind the competitive declaration for the above 3 MW class of customers as being a retreat from
the principle of Market Reliance, directly contrary to the Commissions Order in ICC Docket No.
02-0479, not in keeping with the goals of the Choice Law, and contrary to the facts of the existing
Illinois retail electric market.
CES maintains that the Customer Choice Law envisions the development of a competitive market
for electricity in Illinois, in which each consumer will have choices to determine the most
advantageous way to obtain electricity to service the customers own needs. The instant proceeding
represents a critical step toward achieving the General Assemblys goals.
DES-USESC comment that the Customer Choice Law requires the Commission to promote an
effectively competitive electricity market that operates efficiently and is equitable to all
consumers. (220 ILCS 5/16 101A(d)) The Customer Choice Law also states that Competitive forces
are affecting the market for electricity such that Competition in the electric services market
may create opportunities for new products and services for customers.
DES-USESC notes that the Customer Choice Law requires that all consumers must benefit in an
equitable and timely fashion from the lower costs for electricity that result from retail and
wholesale competition and receive sufficient information to make informed choices among suppliers
and services. (Id.) Thus, the General Assembly has endorsed the concept that the Commission, in
establishing just and reasonable rates, must take affirmative action to ensure the development of
an effectively competitive market for retail electricity in Illinois.
The Customer Choice Law reflects the General Assemblys belief that Illinois retail electric
customers will benefit from competition because competition will lower rates more effectively than
regulation. (See 220 ILCS 5/16-101(e)) The goal of restructuring the electric industry is to
introduce competition to a formerly noncompetitive, monopolistic market so that consumers will
experience the benefits of competition. DES-USESC argues that only if the Commission continues to
foster a
14
05-0159
Proposed Order
competition-enabling environment will consumers have meaningful choices and reasonable
opportunities to achieve savings over the rates derived through a traditional rate of return
regulatory process. DES-USESC further argues that the instant proceeding represents a critical step
toward achieving the General Assemblys goals.
CCG notes that the Restructuring Law created a new regulatory structure that would promote a
competitive wholesale and retail electric market in Illinois. (220 ILCS 5/16-101 et seq.)
Recognizing that [c]ompetitive forces are affecting the market for electricity as a result of
recent federal regulatory and statutory changes and the activities of other states and that [a]
competitive...market must benefit all Illinois citizens (220 ILCS 5/16-101A(b) and (d)), the
Restructuring Law stated that the Commission should act to promote the development of an
effectively competitive electricity market that operates efficiently and is equitable to all
consumers.
CCG further notes that in order to bring about the new regulatory structure, alternative
electric retail suppliers (ARES) were permitted to compete with utilities, a mandatory transition
period was established, residential rates were reduced by 20%, all rates were frozen for the
duration of the mandatory transition period, and utilities were permitted to restructure their
businesses and divest assets, including generating assets. The new structure also promoted the
development of wholesale electric markets. CCG argues that while the restructuring continues to
evolve, several issues will need to be resolved, including the issue of how utilities that no
longer own generation will procure power and energy so that they can meet their obligations for
tariffed service. CCG claims that the proposed tariffs, if approved, would address this issue.
Dynegy offers certain background comments with respect to the 1997 Customer Choice Law.
The Mandatory Transition Period (MTP) provided for in the Customer Choice Law, Section
16-102, ends on January 1, 2007. Without action by the Commission or the General Assembly, at that
time many changes will occur within the rules governing electric utilities in Illinois by operation
of law. Key among these is the end of the rate freeze. (See 16-111(a)) Although the precise
contours are not definitively set forth in the PUA, the General Assembly has laid out certain
policy goals and provided utilities and the Commission with certain options if nothing more were to
occur. The Customer Choice Law includes certain policy goals in Sections 16-101A(b), (d) and (e).
To help implement these goals, the PUA permits utilities to file general rate cases for rates
that will be effective after the expiration of the MTP. In examining such requests, the Commission
has been provided some guidance in such sections as Section 16-111(i), which provides for a
comparison between the market value for power and energy and the rate component for such services
in a utilitys proposed rates.
15
05-0159
Proposed Order
Dynegy notes that parties have raised the issue of whether the Commission has the authority to
approve ComEds proposal for any customer class that has not been declared competitive pursuant to
Section 16-113 and parties have also raised the issue of whether the proposal should nonetheless be
approved as a matter of policy. On these two threshold issues, Dynegy currently takes no position.
While generally supportive of an auction format as a means to accomplish the General Assemblys
goals set forth above, Dynegys basic concern is on ways to improve that process, and not on the
more fundamental issues raised by other parties.
|
B. |
|
ICC Authority under Articles IX and XVI to Approve the Filed
Tariffs1 |
For the most part, ICC authority under Articles IX and XVI to approve the filed tariffs was
addressed in Section III.B of the parties briefs. Discussion is also contained in Section VIII of
the briefs. Relationship of Illinois and federal law and jurisdiction was discussed in Section
III.C and is summarized elsewhere in this order. The parties arguments on these issues are
summarized below. Unless otherwise indicated, assertions contained in these summaries represent the
positions of the parties, not findings by the Commission.
ComEd states that despite the significant transformation of the electric services industry in
Illinois brought about by the 1997 Law, ComEd remains subject to ongoing mandatory service
requirements. Along with this ComEd notes that pursuant to long-settled statutory authority, an
electric utility is entitled to recover its prudently incurred costs. The General Assembly
expressed its intent in the PUA that utility service prices accurately reflect the long-term cost
of such services and that tariff rates for the sale of various public utility services . . .
accurately reflect the cost of delivering those services and allow utilities to recover the total
costs prudently and reasonably incurred. (220 ILCS 5/1-102)
Consistent with this expression of legislative intent, Article IX of the Act requires that
utility rates be just and reasonable. (220 ILCS 5/9-101) This requirement means that rates
should be sufficient to provide for operating expenses, depreciation, reserves . . . and a
reasonable return to the investor. (Illinois Bell Tel. Co. v. ICC, 414 Ill. 275, 286-88 (1953))
Rates must allow the utility to recover costs prudently and reasonably incurred. (ComEd brief at
10, citing Citizens Util. Bd. v. ICC, 166 Ill. 2d 111, 121 (1995)) Further, The state has no power
to compel a corporation engaged in operating a public utility to serve the public without a
reasonable compensation. (ComEd Brief at 10-11, citing City of Edwardsville v. Ill. Bell Tel. Co.,
310 Ill. 618, 621 (1924))
ComEd asserts that under long-standing regulatory principles, the Commission has authority to
approve the mechanism by which ComEd will incur, and recover, the
|
|
|
1 |
|
Discussion of the issues set forth in the
outline at VIII are included because of the inter-relationship of those issues. |
16
05-0159
Proposed Order
actual costs it must incur to fulfill its mandatory service obligations. There is nothing in
the Act that prohibits the Commission from establishing that mechanism in advance, as it previously
has done in analogous situations. ComEd maintains that the Act requires the Commission to ensure
that rates are just and reasonable. (220 ILCS 5/9-101) ComEd asserts that the statute does not
dictate how the Commission should make this determination and, indeed, it is firmly established
that Commission has wide latitude in establishing preferable techniques in utility regulation.
(City of Chicago v. Ill. Commerce Commn, 13 Ill. 2d 607, 618 (1958))
ComEd argues that both the Commission and Illinois courts also have held that the Commission
has the authority to approve formula-type rates, particularly for costs that fluctuate. ComEd
notes that in 1958, the Illinois Supreme Court upheld the Commissions authority to permit a
utility to automatically increase its rates to recover the costs of wholesale power purchases
pursuant to an approved mathematical formula. (City of Chicago, 13 Ill. 2d at 611-613)
More recently, the Supreme Court agreed with the Commission that, in the case of unexpected,
volatile or fluctuating expenses, an adjustment mechanism provides a more accurate and efficient
means than a general rate case for tracking costs and matching them with rates. (ComEd brief at 12,
citing Citizens Util. Bd. v. Ill. Commerce Commn, 166 Ill. 2d 111, 139 (1995)) Such mechanisms
simply and fairly provide for cost recovery and do not affect the utilitys fair rate of
return. (See City of Chicago v. Ill. Commerce Commn, 281 Ill. App. 3d 617, 628 (1st Dist. 1996))
What is critical is that the measure of costs, and the utilitys rates, must be outside the control
of the utility. (See Citizens Util. Bd. v. Ill. Commerce Commn, 275 Ill. App. 3d 329, 340, 1st
Dist. 1995) (the Commission may not approve a tariff which permits a utility to set its own
rates).
ComEd claims that Rider CPP establishes a competitive auction procurement mechanism by which
ComEd prudently may incur the costs associated with its wholesale power purchases and allows ComEd
to recover those costs without any markup to consumers. ComEd explains that the proposed
procurement mechanism is beyond the control of the utility and fully monitored by the Commission.
Once the auction is completed, an independent auction manager must submit a formal report to the
Commission summarizing what occurred at the auction. The Commissions Staff also must submit a
report to the Commission regarding the auction. The Commission then has the opportunity to review
the auction and, if it determines necessary, reject the auction results by initiating an
investigation or other formal proceeding.
ComEd continues stating that retail rates will be set by a pre-determined formula based on the
auction results. The Commission also retains its authority to initiate an investigation into the
rate at any time and any aggrieved party may file a complaint if the rate is unjust and
unreasonable. (220 ILCS 5/9-250) For all these reasons, ComEd urges that the cost recovery
mechanism in Rider CPP is fully consistent with the principles set forth by the Illinois Supreme
Court in City of Chicago and related cases, and is within the Commissions authority to approve
under Article IX of the Act.
17
05-0159
Proposed Order
ComEd asserts that authority to approve Rider CPP is also provided by Section 16-111(i) of the
Act. That provision addresses how the Commission must evaluate rates in the context presented
here, i.e., after the mandatory transition period but before a tariffed service is declared
competitive. Section 16-111(i) directs:
In determining the justness and reasonableness of the electric power and energy
component of an electric utilitys rates for tariffed services subsequent to the
mandatory transition period and prior to the time that the provision of the tariffed
service is declared competitive, the Commission shall consider the extent to which
the electric utilitys tariffed rates for such component for each customer class
exceed the market value determined pursuant to Section 16-112.
In addition, Section 16-111(i) permits the Commission to establish such electric power and
energy component at a rate equal to the market value plus 10%. In other words, the Act explicitly
recognizes that, prior to the time a service is declared competitive, charges for the electric
power and energy component of the service may be measured by that components market value.
Thus, Section 16-111(i) implements the longstanding Article IX just and reasonable rates
requirement, 220 ILCS 5/9-101, in the context of the electricity services restructuring envisioned
by the 1997 Law, by expressly allowing the Commission to make market value a reference point for
the justness and reasonableness of charges for the electric power and energy component of tariffed
services.
ComEd maintains that Rider CPP comports with the authorization provided by Sections 16 111(i)
and 16-112(a) to base rates for the electric power and energy component of tariffed service on the
market value of that energy. Market value as used in Section 16-111(i) is defined in Section
16-112. Significantly, Section 16-112 broadly establishes that the Commission may determine
market value pursuant to a tariff that . . . provides for a determination of the market value
for electric power and energy as a function of an exchange traded or other market traded index,
options or futures contract or contracts applicable to the market in which the utility sells, and
the customers in its service area buy, electric power and energy. (220 ILCS 5/16-112(a)) A
competitive auction process fits squarely within the statutory criteria for establishing the
market value for electric power and energy under Section 16-112(a).
ComEd argues that Rider CPP is not prohibited by Section 16-103(c). (ComEd brief at 16-24) In
Section III.B.4.a, ComEd says the AGs Section 16-103(c) argument has already been correctly
rejected.
ComEd argues that the parties argument confuses retail and wholesale markets. The auction
proposal is a wholesale auction, whereby ComEd will purchase electric energy at wholesale from
third party suppliers to serve its retail load. It is not a retail auction. ComEd will be
charging its retail customers its actual costs of procuring power at wholesale. ComEd will not be
charging its retail customers market-based rates.
18
05-0159
Proposed Order
Thus, these parties would read Section 16-103(c) to mean that a utility like ComEd that owns no
generation facilities of its own could not charge customers, prior to a competitive declaration,
the costs of wholesale electricity acquired through a competitive process.
ComEd asserts that this proposition is surprising in light of the consensus conclusion reached
in the Commissions Post 2006 Initiative, a collaborative process that addressed issues regarding
the Acts post-transition period commencing January 1, 2007. Interested stakeholders, including
each of the parties now advancing the Section 16-103(c) argument, participated in that process
through several open working groups, including one focused specifically on procurement. The
declared consensus of all stakeholders in the Procurement Working Group was that the ideal
procurement method for utilities that had divested their generation assets should, among other
criteria, allow for a competitive procurement approach, provide for the opportunity for full
cost recovery to the utilities if they follow the Commission approved procurement approach and
result in market-based rates for customers.
ComEd also cites to the ALJ ruling that from a simple reading of Section 16-103(c), and its
numerous references to cost, it is clear that market-based prices and cost-based rates are not
mutually exclusive concepts. (05-0159 ALJ Ruling of June 1, 2005 at 6) Rather, use of
market-based prices is recognized as a mechanism for or subset of, not an exception to or
replacement of, establishing rate components based on cost. That is, use of market-based pricing
is identified as one method for determining such costs, not an alternative thereto. According to
ComEd, the ruling emphasized that what is at issue in this proceeding is ComEds costs: In the
instant case, ComEds proposal is intended to recover only such costs as are actually incurred in
procuring power and energy through the auction process. Given that use of market-based prices
is not inherently inconsistent with the principle of setting rate components at cost, the ruling
explained that the question is whether Section 16-103(c) prohibits the use of an auction or other
market-based process in determining the costs of power and energy in setting rates for
non-competitive customers.
ComEd further cites that the ruling properly concluded there is no such prohibition in the
statute. Rather, the statute requires that rate components for competitive services may only be
set, not surprisingly, by using market-based prices to establish cost. (Id.) But just because
that particular method is statutorily mandated for establishing certain cost components for
competitive services does not somehow mean it is statutorily prohibited for other services or
customers, particularly where, as in the instant case, use of market-based prices is expressly
recognized as one means of establishing costs in Section 16-103(c).
ComEd argues that the AGs construction of Section 16-103(c) is contrary to the language and
main purpose of the statute.
ComEd provides a summarization of Section 16-103. Section 16-103 is captioned, and defines,
the [s]ervice obligations of electric utilities. Subsection
19
05-0159
Proposed Order
16-103(a) provides that until a tariffed service is declared competitive pursuant to Section
16-113 meaning that until the Commission determines that a customer segment or group can obtain
equivalent electric service from one or more providers other than the electric utility, 220 ILCS
5/16-113 an electric utility remains obligated to provide tariffed retail services to that
customer segment or group. However, once a tariffed service is declared competitive, a utility
generally can choose not to provide service at all or can provide unregulated service, priced any
way it wants. (220 ILCS 5/16-113(b), 16-119) That is the point of bringing competition to formerly
regulated retail markets.
Subsection 16-103(c) sets forth a limited exception to this rule for smaller customers. The
section declares that [n]otwithstanding any other provision of this Article meaning
notwithstanding the provisions of Sections 16-103(a) and 16-113 described above each electric
utility shall continue offering to all residential customers and to all small commercial retail
customers bundled electric service indefinitely, even if the service is declared competitive.
Section 16-103(c) continues by defining how, when service to these smaller customers becomes
competitive, the still-ongoing mandatory service obligation shall be priced, providing that
pricing shall be at at rates which reflect recovery of all cost components for providing the
service. Finally, Section 16-103(c) concludes by defining cost in this setting, stating that
[f]or those components of the service which have been declared competitive, cost shall be the
market based prices. Market based prices as referred to in Section 16-103(c) means either as
provided for in Section 16-112, or the utilitys cost of obtaining the electric power and energy
at wholesale through a competitive bidding or other arms-length acquisition process.
ComEd asserts that the import of Section 16-103(c) is that residential and small commercial
retail customers are entitled to remain with their existing public utility, even after their
service is declared competitive. ComEd notes that these small customers would never be forced into
the market and could continue to receive their electric service from their existing public utility
as they had done before the 1997 Law. However, the General Assembly made sure that the utility
could not take advantage of small customers who chose to remain with their existing utility. ComEd
states that the General Assembly provided that, once a service is declared competitive, these small
customers who remain with the utility are entitled to rates based on costs determined by market
forces. Even if the utilitys actual costs prove to be higher, the utility is limited to charging
these small customers rates based on costs determined by market forces.
Thus, according to ComEd, Section 16-103(c) is an exception that applies for limited customer
groups when a service is declared competitive, and it defines how a utility shall obtain recovery
of all cost components at and after that time. Section 16-103(c) says nothing about the situation
here, where the relevant customer classes have not yet been declared competitive. Critically, the
fact that cost must be based on market prices when a service for certain small customer groups is
declared competitive does not mean that cost cannot ever be based on market prices at any other
time.
20
05-0159
Proposed Order
ComEd argues that the Attorney General effectively rewrites the statute as if it read that cost
shall be the market based prices only for any service that has been declared competitive. But,
ComEd asserts the word only nowhere appears in, and cannot be glossed onto, the provision.
ComEd maintains that absent an ambiguity, a statute must be interpreted in accordance with the
words used by the legislature, and provisions that do not appear may not be added. (See, e.g.,
People v. Glisson, 202 Ill. 2d 499, 504 (2002) (where a statute is clear and unambiguous, courts
cannot read into the statute limitations, exceptions, or other conditions not expressed by the
legislature); Donahoo v. Bd. of Educ. of School Dist. No. 303, 413 Ill. 422, 426 (1953)) Section
16-103(c) is inapposite: it addresses pricing for residential and small commercial customer classes
that have been declared competitive. ComEds tariff does not purport to apply to such a situation.
ComEd argues that the Attorney Generals interpretation of Section 16-103(c) would lead to
absurd results and would render other provisions of the Act superfluous.
ComEd notes that many costs from poles to wires are prudently incurred precisely because
they are incurred at market prices. It would be illogical to read into the statute a prohibition
that until a service is declared competitive, a utilitys recoverable costs cannot be based on
competitive, arms-length transactions or market prices that define the utilitys actual costs.
Because ComEd no longer owns generation assets, it necessarily must acquire wholesale electricity
in the market, at prices subject to FERC regulation. That is why it is correct that market-based
prices and cost based rates are not mutually exclusive concepts.
Contrary to the implication in the Attorney Generals argument, ComEd does not propose to
charge a retail market-based rate for its utility services based on the potential competitive
offerings of other retail suppliers. That would be inappropriate for any customer class before a
service is declared competitive under Section 16-113. Rather, ComEd seeks to recover its actual
costs, which happen here as often is the case to be incurred at market-based prices in the
various wholesale markets in which ComEd must purchase electricity.
Second, the Attorney Generals view contravenes another principle of statutory interpretation,
namely, that a statute should be evaluated as a whole and that each provision should be
construed in connection with every other section. (Abrahamson v. Ill. Dept of Prof. Reg., 153
Ill.2d 76, 91 (1992)) [I]f possible, no term [should be] rendered superfluous or meaningless.
(Texas-Cities Serv. Pipeline Co. v. McGaw, 182 Ill.2d 262, 270 (1998)) The Attorney General
contends that, before a service is declared competitive, rates cannot be based on the market value
of electric power and energy. However, Section 16-111(i) explicitly provides that, before a
service is declared competitive, the Commission must consider the market value of electricity in
setting rates. To ignore Section 16 111(i) would render that provision meaningless.
21
05-0159
Proposed Order
ComEd states that more recently, the Supreme Court agreed with the Commission that, in the
case of unexpected, volatile or fluctuating expenses, an adjustment mechanism provides a more
accurate and efficient means than a general rate case for tracking costs and matching them with
rates. (Citizens Util. Bd. v. Illinois Commerce Commn, 166 Ill. 2d 111, 138 (1995)) What is
critical is that the measure of costs, and the utilitys rates, must be outside of the utilitys
unilateral control. (See Citizens Util. Bd. v. Illinois Commerce Commn, 275 Ill. App. 3d 329, 340
(1st Dist. 1995) (the Commission may not approve a tariff which permits a utility to set its own
rates))
ComEd continues that such formula rate mechanisms have not been limited to fuel purchases.
(See Citizens Util. Bd., 166 Ill. 2d at 133 (upholding recovery of coal-tar cleanup expenditures
through a flexible rider mechanism); City of Chicago, 281 Ill. App. 3d at 627-28 (upholding rider
recovery of utility municipal franchise fees)) ComEd notes that it already employs a formula rate
in many other tariffs.
ComEd contends that its proposed auction review process fully protects all the consumer
protections of the Act.
ComEd asserts that the issue before the Commission is not whether ComEds wholesale
electricity costs may increase, but simply whether those costs are prudently incurred, and whether
ComEds Rider CPP allows the Commission sufficient opportunity to review whether those costs are
prudently incurred.
ComEd contends that the Commissions review of the prudence of ComEds proposed wholesale
acquisitions occurs in two forms, which together allow the Commission ample opportunity to review
the prudence of ComEds incurrence of these costs. First, through this proceeding, ComEd provides
an opportunity to the Commission and interested parties to review the method by which ComEd will
make its wholesale acquisitions. ComEd proposes for review and approval the very mechanism by which
it will make these wholesale acquisitions. Many of the precise issues of discretionary conduct
raised by CUB such as how the qualifications of bidders will be established, how much of ComEds
retail power requirements will be offered for bid, how much of ComEds requirements can be captured
by one bidder all are available for review and approval by the Commission in this proceeding.
ComEd maintains that its proposal provides for extensive review of the auction itself by the
Commission. Within one business day of the auctions completion date, both the Auction Manager and
the Auction Advisor must submit reports to the Commission. The Auction Managers report will
provide a factual summary of the activities and events that occurred during the course of the CPP
Auction and the CPP-H Auction and an assessment of whether the auctions were conducted fairly and
appropriately in accordance with the CPP rules and procedures. The Auction Advisors report
provides an independent assessment . . . as to whether or not the CPP Auction and the CPP-H
Auction were conducted fairly and appropriately and all necessary actions to ensure the
competitiveness and integrity of such auctions were followed.
22
05-0159
Proposed Order
The Commission can reject the auction results by initiating a formal investigation or other formal
proceeding by the end of the third business day following the auctions completion date. Also,
the tariff does not in any way limit the Commissions ability to review all the information it has
available to it.
ComEd asserts that if an objective process beyond the control of the utility is approved and
followed, the utility adds no markup or profit to the resulting costs, and the Commission
contemporaneously reviews and accepts the auction results, there necessarily is no basis for a
detailed review of the acquisition after the fact.
|
2. |
|
Attorney Generals Position |
The AG argues that the PUA does not authorize market-based rates for electric service that
has not been declared competitive under Section 16-113.
The AG argues that the 1997 Amendments authorize the Commission to use market based prices
to set utility rates only for services that consumers have the option of purchasing from their
utilitys unregulated competitors and that have been declared competitive pursuant to Section
16-113 of the PUA. (AG brief at 8-12)
The AG further argues that there is no language in the 1997 Amendments or other Articles of
the PUA that authorizes market-based rates for customers who do not have access to electric service
that has been declared competitive.
It is the position of the AG that the Commission can declare electric service competitive
only when comparable service is available from at least one non-utility supplier.
The AG notes that the 1997 Law contains express criteria to determine whether there is
sufficient competition to declare electric service competitive and the Commission can approve
market-based rates only for services that meet these criteria. By structuring the transition to
competition in this manner, the General Assembly allowed the self-generating regulatory force of
the market to set rates only where there is sufficient competition but retained regulated rates
for those services that do not yet meet the criteria to be declared competitive. According to the
AG, in the absence of competition, rates must continue to be determined by the Commission through a
process of regulatory review defined by the PUA, rather than by passing through prices from
wholesale markets.
The AG asserts that in the regulatory review process, the Commission is required to determine
whether rates proposed by electric utilities are just and reasonable. The AG further asserts
that the Commission must also ensure that electric rates for a utilitys captive customers are
based on the actual cost of providing service.
The AG believes that captive customers, who do not have access to service that has been
declared competitive, have a right to the continued consumer protections
23
05-0159
Proposed Order
afforded by the procedural and substantive standards that the General Assembly, the Courts and the
Commission have articulated as essential elements of rate of return/cost-based regulation in
Illinois. The AG summarizes these standards as follows: rates based on a review of the prudence
of management decisions; rates based on a direct review of profits; rates determined through public
proceedings with procedural safeguards that ensure the right of the citizens to participate,
investigate, present evidence, and cross-examine witnesses; rates determined to be just and
reasonable through a deliberative decision-making process based on the evidence in the record and
applicable law; and rates determined by an independent Commission whose ratemaking decisions are
subject to scrutiny by the Courts and can be reversed or voided for violations of the PUA and
ethics laws.
The AG asserts that unlike the Commission, markets are not required to consider the prudence
of management decisions, excess profits, citizens right to be heard, the justness and
reasonableness of rates, the credibility and weight of evidence, or ethical problems. The AG
continues stating that markets are not required to ensure that the People of Illinois have access
to adequate, efficient, reliable, environmentally safe and least-cost public utility services at
prices which accurately reflect the long-term cost of such services and which are equitable to all
citizens.
The AG argues that the Commission has a duty to review rates for electricity to determine
whether the costs were prudently incurred.
The AG maintains that the mandatory transition period does not mean an end to regulated rates,
or an end to the obligation of the Commission under the PUA to ensure that utilities charge
consumers rates that are just and reasonable, and based on costs that are prudent and reasonable.
The AG asserts that the 1997 Amendments specify that electric utilities service obligations remain
unchanged until there is a competitive declaration pursuant to Section 16-113 of the Act.
The AG is of the opinion that ComEds proposal seeks to radically shift risks to consumers and
to insulate the Company from any financial responsibility for power procurement decisions. The AG
argues that the 1997 Amendments do not contemplate or authorize this change in regulatory, consumer
protections. Such a change is inconsistent with the longstanding consumer protections contained in
the PUA and retained by the 1997 Amendments.
The AG stresses that the Commission cannot approve a blank rate. The AG argues that the 1997
Amendments do not authorize utilities to file tariffs with rates that do not exist. These
Amendments preserve existing consumer protections, which include Commission review of rate changes
in docketed public proceedings, and rates that are just and reasonable and that reflect the cost of
service. Commonwealth Edisons request to pre-approve unknown rate increases must be reviewed
within this statutory framework.
24
05-0159
Proposed Order
The AG argues that some parties wrongly suggest that Section 16-111(i) authorizes the
Commission to approve the use of market value as the rate for service that has not been declared
competitive.
The AG states that Section 16-111(i) directs the Commission to compare cost-based rates with
the market value calculated using one of the methods listed in Section 16-112 to provide a check
on utility cost-based rates so that the assumed benefits of competition would not be lost to
consumers who lack competitive options. This consideration of market value is simply one step in
the process of determining the justness and reasonableness of the regulated rates charged to
captive customers. The AG argues that it is not authority to abandon cost-based ratemaking or to
increase rates above what is fair, just and reasonable.
The AG argues that when read consistently with Section 16-103(c), Section 16-111(i) is clearly
a protection for non-competitive consumers, ensuring that they will not pay rates that are more
than 10% higher than market rates. The AG asserts that it is clear that Section 16-111(i) does not
authorize the pass-through of market-based rates for service that has not been declared
competitive, it only authorizes the Commission to add a market value calculation to the various
analytical screens used to determine the justness and reasonableness of the regulated rates charged
to captive customers and to impose a cap (market value plus 10 percent) on rates charged to captive
customers.
The AG notes that the General Assembly responded to City of Chicago by passing section 9-220
of the PUA, which specifically addresses rate changes based on fuel, gas and purchased power costs
and mandates an annual review, with public hearings, to determine whether such purchases were
prudent.
The AG lists a second factor distinguishing City of Chicago from ComEds proposal in this
docket is that the Court in City of Chicago did not believe that the Commission or the utility had
any discretion but to purchase the gas and pay the price for natural gas set by the Federal Power
Commission.
The AG notes that a utility can choose to either recover retail purchased power costs (and
other specified costs) pursuant to a variable monthly charge subject to an annual prudence review
and reconciliation, or choose to include that charge in base rates. (220 ILCS 5/9-220) The AG
offers that if the utility has given up its fuel adjustment rate during the mandatory transition
period, it is free to reinstate it after January 1, 2007 when the mandatory transition period ends.
The AG asserts that ComEds effort to abdicate its responsibility to prudently purchase
electricity on behalf of consumers should be rejected as harmful to consumers interests. According
to the AG, the cost of electricity purchased to serve consumers is not and should not be something
outside ComEds control.
25
05-0159
Proposed Order
The AG asserts that retail consumers would pay these rates, which would be based on an auction
process that ComEd was intended to obtain electricity at market prices. (ComEd Ex.3.0 at 13) It is
disingenuous to suggest that the auction is really just a method to recover costs to be incurred
at market-based prices in the various wholesale markets in which ComEd must purchase electricity,
unrelated to retail rates.
The AG argues that Rider CPP violates the PUA by imposing market rates on consumers and by
allowing the utility to charge rates that have not been subject to regulatory review.
The AG states that ComEd does not need ICC approval to purchase its full requirements electric
supply at market-based prices. The AG continues stating that ComEd cannot obtain ICC approval for
the market-based rates in Rider CPP because the Commission does not have authority to approve
market-based rates for electric service that has not been declared competitive pursuant to PUA
Section 16-113.
The AG argues that the 1997 Amendments authorized the Commission to use market based prices
to set utility rates only for services that consumers have the option of purchasing from their
utilitys unregulated competitors and that have been declared competitive pursuant to
Section16-113 of the PUA. According to the AG, more than three million ComEd customers receive
service for which there are no competitive options. The AG insists that for those customers, the
Commission must set fair, just and reasonable rates based on the cost of service standards that
have been established to protect monopoly consumers.
The AG contends that the Commission cannot lawfully approve Rider CPP because it does not
contain rates and contains an unlawful blank authorization to change rates.
The AG asserts that ComEds attempt to avoid regulatory review by seeking pre-approval of the
auction process is also illegal under the PUA and the 1997 Amendments. Nowhere does the law
authorize the Commission to waive the consumer protections afforded by rate case or prudence
reviews.
The AG argues that the only lawful course for the Commission is to permanently reject Rider
CPP. ComEd is still free to seek a change in its delivery and power rate if costs justify such a
move. The Commission would review such a request under Article IX of the PUA.
CUB argues that the ICC lacks authority under the Act to approve the filed tariffs. CUB notes
that the Act provides for the general supervision of all public utilities by the Commission. The
Commissions power and authority come strictly from the Act, and the ICC cannot, by its own
actions, extend its jurisdiction beyond the law. CUB contends that the Act does not confer the ICC
with jurisdiction to approve ComEds proposals.
26
05-0159
Proposed Order
CUB asserts that market-based rates cannot apply here. The condition precedent for the
charging of such rates to ComEds residential customers and other customers below 3 KW has not been
met. CUB further asserts that is because the Commission has not declared tariff services for these
customers competitive, as required under 220 ILCS 5/16-113.
CUB urges the Commission to scrutinize ComEds proposals under its traditional ratemaking
rules. CUB maintains that the Commission must determine whether ComEd acted prudently in procuring
power and incurring the costs of it, regardless of the procurement method used.
CUB notes that under applicable law, if all the cost of acquiring the power is prudently
incurred, then those costs can be passed on to customers through rates. But if any cost is deemed
imprudent, it cannot be included in the rates. In addition, the Act mandates that the ICC establish
rates that are just and reasonable. CUB states that ComEd would have the burden of proving the
justness and reasonableness of its proposed rates and charges and the prudence of its conduct.
CUB observes that ComEd has not filed a schedule of actual rates, charges, or executed
contracts. According to CUB, the Commission has no actual rates, charges or executed contracts to
review for reasonableness or justness. ComEds filings merely propose a descending clock auction
procurement process that is replete with enormous non-reviewable discretion to be exercised by
ComEd and its auction manager. Then, ComEd is asking the ICC, and equally important, its customers,
to accept on blind faith that the resulting clearing prices will automatically be just and
reasonable. CUB claims that ComEd is proposing that the ICC forgo any meaningful after-the-fact
prudence review of the actual, resulting auction prices.
CUB contends that ComEd has fashioned its proposal so that it is completely risk free. In
particular, ComEd proposes that the auction prices and all of the enormous costs of running the
auction be passed on dollar-for-dollar to its customers. The auction product being procured is full
requirements electric supply, making for a back-to-back transaction whereby ComEd sells the same
commodity product at retail as it procures at wholesale with adjustments for line losses and other
costs, but without any margin added. Thus, even if the resulting prices are in fact unjust or
unreasonable, ComEd bears no risk of not recouping all of its costs of paying for the power from
its customers.
CUB stresses that the Commission cannot approve proposed tariffs that contain no actual rates
or charges and that grant a utility the prospective right to establish rates in the future.
(Citizens Utility Board v. The Illinois Commerce Commission, 275 Ill. App. 3d 329, 655 N.E.2d 961
(1st Dist. 1995)) CUB believes that the question of whether the ICC has the jurisdiction to
pre-approve the open-ended, type of proposals at issue here was answered in the negative in the
Citizens Utility Board case.
27
05-0159
Proposed Order
CUB asserts that the Commission can not approve a tariff that permitted a utility to establish
rates in the future, subject only to the condition that the rates contribute to the utilitys fixed
costs. Such a condition is implied in every just and reasonable rate and, standing alone, does
not properly constitute a rate under the Act, as further explained by the court. Thus, according
to CUB, the ICC has no jurisdiction to approve proposals that grant a utility a prospective right
to set rates into the future, which is precisely what ComEd is proposing here.
CUB insists that the ComEd proposal does not involve a process that merely and mathematically
adjusts existing rate schedules. According to CUB, the issue here is ComEds request for
pre-approval of an auction process never used or tested in Illinois before for ComEds retail full
requirements electric supply at unknown, unconstrained, uncapped and unspecified rates. CUB notes
that New Jersey is the only state using an auction but with supply products different than
Illinois. Ohio ran an auction but never used the auction prices because they were higher than the
regulated rates.
CUB is adamant that the proposals here are rife with discretionary conduct by ComEd. CUB lists
the following as examples of such discretion: ComEd decides who can bid by establishing the
qualifications for bidders. ComEd decides how much of its retail power requirements are being
offered for bid. ComEd decides how much of that requirement can be captured by one bidder by
setting a load cap. ComEd decides the maximum and minimum prices for the auction. ComEd designs and
creates the full requirements product being offered for bid, and creates and designs different
customer groups within the bidding system. ComEd establishes the duration of the supplier
contracts, which differs for each customer group.
CCSAO addresses the Commissions authority under Articles IX and XVI to approve the filed
tariffs. CCSAO argues that the Commission lacks authority to approve an auction for customers
whose service has not been declared competitive.
CCSAO maintains that the Commissions authority is limited to that provided by Illinois law.
As the Illinois Supreme Court noted, . . . the sole power of the Commission stems from the
statute, and it has the power and jurisdiction only to determine facts and make orders concerning
the matters specified in the statute.
CCSAO asserts that the auction, if properly designed, may at best determine a market price for
electric power. According to CCSAO, it is for the Illinois General Assembly to decide when
customers whose service has not been declared competitive like residential and small commercial
customers are to be subject to a market price.
CCSAO further asserts that competitive bidding is mentioned in the Act in the context of
market prices for such customers after a competitive declaration. Absent legislation, customers
whose service has not been declared competitive (residential and small commercial retail customers)
should not be exposed to a market price. CCSAO
28
05-0159
Proposed Order
notes that is no Commission-approved competitive suppliers for residential and small customers to
switch to, and therefore it would be unjust and unreasonable to expose them to a market price
without adequate consumer protections.
CCSAO asserts that the universe that the legislature sought in the transition and described in
its findings does not exist as originally envisioned. CCSAO states that this failure in the
marketplace is not something that the Commission can repair in the context of this docket. It is a
matter for the legislature.
CCSAO addresses ComEds sale and divestiture of generation assets. CCSAO notes that one of
the provisions of Article XVI, Section 16-111(g), allowed Illinois Public Utilities to transfer or
sell their electric generation assets subject to limited Illinois Commerce Commission review.
CCSAO notes that ComEd chose to avail itself of this opportunity and transferred its nuclear assets
to an affiliate in Exelon and sold its fossil fuel assets to another company. ComEds need to
obtain generation is the result of its choice to transfer and sell its generation assets under this
opportunity provided by the Customer Choice law.
CCSAO acknowledges that this case is ComEds proposal on how to procure power, as it no longer
has power generation assets. CCSAO maintains that the proper question: Was ComEds decision to
avail itself to this opportunity without negotiating any options for obtaining generation post 2006
a just and reasonable thing to do and was it prudent?
CCSAO states that during the transition ComEd took steps to ensure that residential customers
continued to receive reasonable rates. ComEd had purchase power agreements with Midwest Gen, ExGen
and other suppliers throughout the country.
CCSAO asserts that ComEd should have taken additional steps to ensure that it was able to meet
its obligations to residential and small commercial customers post-2006 before completing these
transactions. CCSAO seeks that the Commission should conclude that ComEd failed to act prudently
on behalf of residential ratepayers.
CCSAO further assert that the tariffs filed by ComEd fail to provide the Commission with
enough information to determine the exact rate that will be paid by ratepayers under the tariffs.
CCSAO argues that this is not what Article IX requires under the various requirements for rates in
Illinois.
CCSAO claims that the lack of price certainty and the various tasks that the tariffs delegate
to individuals like the auction manager and advisor, the tariffs do not provide the level of
specificity as required by Illinois law. CCSAO asserts that Illinois consumers may ultimately have
to pay the price set by the auction for the power without the benefit of a comprehensive 11-month
Commission review of the justness and reasonableness of the costs and the supporting data and an
opportunity for a later prudence review.
29
05-0159
Proposed Order
CCSAO argues that consumers are entitled to have the Commission actively review the dollars
that they are being asked to spend on electricity. To have the Commission pre-approve the current
tariff without actual numbers would be like handing the utilities a blank check .
CCSAO contends that the focus here is on the pre-approval of an unknown rate for customers
whose service has not been declared competitive. CCSAO maintains that ComEd can use a variety of
tools to procure power and then file a rate case before the Commission to recover its lawful costs
including those from the wholesale market.
CCSAO recommends that the Commission (a) reject the Companys proposal; (b) open a new docket
to consider the full range of procurement options; and (c) affirm that, regardless of which
procurement method is employed, retail rates remain subject to traditional regulatory standards of
justness and reasonableness, which entail a prudence review of the companys decisions.
CCSAO further recommends that the Commission should recognize that the Company retains
responsibility for making and managing the decisions and actions necessary to serve default service
customers and should clarify that the Commission will ensure, as part of its oversight
responsibility, that the Company has done so in a manner that best serves default service
customers.
Staff notes that prior to 1997, electric utilities such as ComEd generally owned their own
generating assets that produced the power and energy needs of their customers. As a result, the
tariffs filed by these utilities pursuant to Section 9-201 of the Act would seek to recover the
costs incurred relating to the generating assets that were used to provide service to customers.
Staff further notes that in 1997, Choice Law was a massive overhaul of the States policy
toward electric utility service. It began a transition toward delivery service unbundling and
greater reliance on market forces to determine how electric power and energy would be provided to
retail customers. The Choice Law was codified in Article XVI of the Act. (220 ILCS 5/16-101)
Staff contends that pursuant to Section 16-111(i), it is within the Commissions authority to
review a competitive procurement process-driven tariff such as the ComEd-filed tariffs. Staff
asserts that such tariffs must clear at least two hurdles: (1) FERC regulation, including
strictures governing wholesale electric transactions between sellers of electricity and affiliated
wholesale purchasers, and (2) the provisions of the Public Utilities Act relevant to the setting of
rates after 2006 including Article IX, and Section 16-111(i) of the Act, with its directive that
the Commission consider the extent to which the power and energy component or rates exceeds the
market value determined pursuant to Section 16-112 of the Act.
30
05-0159
Proposed Order
Staff asserts that the Commission can retain jurisdiction and that Section 16-111(i) of the
Act requires the Commission to consider the extent to which the electric utilitys tariffed rates
for such component for each customer class exceed the market value determined pursuant to Section
16-112. (220 ILCS 5/16-111(i)) The Commission is also authorized to impose a rate ceiling in the
event the rates for that electric power and energy component exceed the market value by more than
10%.
Staff argues that in order for post-transition period rates to comply with Section 16-111(i)
of the Act, the utility must provide or propose some method to compare its proposed rates to the
market value determined pursuant to Section 16-112 of the Act. ComEds proposal was intended to
provide such a method.
Staff avers that the fact that ComEd Rider CPPs uses formulae to establish rates does not
diminish Commission authority. Formulae have been used on prior occasion by utilities in Illinois
and approved by Illinois courts. (See City of Chicago v. Illinois Commerce Commn, 13 Ill.2d 607,
150 NE.2d 776 (1958)) Staff insists that the Commission has the authority to approve formula-based
rates.
Staff continues that despite the fact that residential and small business services have not
been ruled competitive, the Commission has authority to rule on ComEds tariffs.
Staff contends that subject to limitations stated elsewhere in the Choice Law, an electric
utility is relieved of its obligation to provide retail services offered at the time of enactment
of the Choice Law when the service is . . . declared competitive pursuant to Section 16-113 . . .
. Once so relieved of its provider of last resort (POLR) obligations, an electric utility is
free to charge market rates subject to any limitations stated elsewhere in the Act.
Staff notes that one such limitation is set forth in Section 16-103(c) of the Act, which
places limits on the rates that a utility may charge competitive residential and small business
services by requiring the continued offering of tariffed services for such customers at rates
which reflect recovery of all cost components for providing the service . . . . Staff further
notes that while Section 16-103(c) of the Act refers to market-based prices, this phrase is used
in defining costs and it is clear from the statutory language of Section 16-103(c) that the
Legislature did not consider market-based prices and cost-based rates to be mutually exclusive
concepts.
Staff argues that Section 16-103(c) indicates that the rates for certain competitive services
must reflect recovery of all costs components for providing the service and that costs shall be
the market based prices . . . which are specifically defined as either (i) those prices for
electric power and energy determined as provided in Section 16-112, or (ii) the electric utilitys
cost of obtaining the electric power and energy at wholesale through a competitive bidding or other
arms-length acquisition process. (220 ILCS 5/16-103(c)) Staff argues that the language of Section
16-103(c) implies that market-
31
05-0159
Proposed Order
based prices as used in Section 16-103(c) may be determined based on the utilities actual cost of
obtaining such power and energy through any arms-length acquisition process including a
competitive bidding process.
Staff argues that Section 16-103(c) of the Act imposes a limitation on market rates that
allows either a market-value rate under Section 16-112 of the Act or a cost-based rate. Since ComEd
no longer possesses its own generation assets, the only means for ComEd to acquire the electric
supply it needs to serve its customers is through third party suppliers. Staff maintains that
based on Section 16-103(c), the Commission may set rates based on the costs incurred through the
only means available to ComEd to obtain such supply.
Staff further notes that the explicit language contained in Section 16-103(a) provides that
[n]othing in this subsection shall be construed as limiting an electric utilitys right to
propose, or the Commissions power to approve, allow or order modifications in the rates, terms and
conditions for such services pursuant to Article IX or Section 16-111 of this Act. (220 ILCS
5/16-103(a)) Section 16-103(c) is a limitation on the Legislatures decision to generally relieve
electric utilities of their obligation to provide services that are declared competitive. The
Legislature has specifically directed that nothing with respect to its decision to remove
competitive services from traditional regulatory oversight shall be interpreted or construed to
limit the Commissions authority or power pursuant to Article IX or Section 16-111.
Finally, according to Staff, the declaration of findings contained in the Choice Law makes
clear that the Legislature acknowledged that [c]ompetitive forces are affecting the market for
electricity and that it intended for the Commission to promote the development of an effectively
competitive electricity market that operates efficiently and is equitable to all consumers. (220
ILCS 5/16-101A(b)) Staff agrees that the proposed Rider CPP clearly acknowledges competitive
developments and is consistent with the development of competitive markets and proposes protections
for consumers and others.
Staff asserts that the ability to charge market rates for retail services declared competitive
under the Restructuring Law is the ability under Section 16-116(b) to charge whatever rate a
willing buyer will pay, free from Commission scrutiny with respect to prices, terms and conditions.
Staff notes that Section 16-103(c) of the Act is an exception to the general ability of an
electric utility to (i) refuse to offer or (ii) charge a market rate for certain retail services
declared competitive.
According to Staff, Section 16-103(c) of the Act requires electric utilities to continue to
offer traditional bundled electric service on a tariffed basis for residential and small commercial
retail customers, notwithstanding the declaration of such services as competitive. Further,
Section 16-103(c) restricts the general ability of electric utilities to charge market rates for
competitive retail services, and instead requires that rates for competitive residential and small
commercial retail services reflect recovery of all cost components for providing the service.
32
05-0159
Proposed Order
Staff takes issue with the AGs assertion that setting cost-based retail rates for services
not declared competitive based on market-based wholesale costs is inconsistent with Section
16-103(c) and beyond the Commissions authority. Staff asserts that Section 16-103(c) of the Act
imposes a limitation on an electric utilitys ability to charge market rates for residential and
small commercial customer competitive services, requiring instead cost-based rates specifically
defined to include an electric utilitys cost of obtaining the electric power and energy at
wholesale through a competitive bidding or other arms-length acquisition process. Staff asserts
that the AGs argument that Section 16-103(c) prohibits the Commission from setting rates according
to the cost-based methodologies set forth therein is based on a flawed reading of Section 16-103(c)
that fails to recognize (1) that the reference to market based prices is in the context of
cost-based rates and (2) that Section 16-103(c) is a limitation on the ability to charge market
retail rates rather than a grant a specific rate authority.
Staff does not agree that the ratemaking principles are inconsistent with auction based
procurement. To the contrary, Staff maintains that the auction-based procurement proposal as
modified by Staff is consistent with applicable ratemaking principles.
Staff disagrees with the AGs statement in that it implies that there is some means of
acquiring wholesale energy other than through the wholesale market. As explained above, any such
assertion ignores the fact that the Restructuring Law authorized ComEd to divest itself of its
generation assets and that it owns no generation assets at this time. As a result, any possible
procurement method will necessarily rely on the wholesale market.
Staff agrees that the Commission may establish a utilitys charges for the electric power and
energy component of tariffed services at a rate equal to the market value plus 10%. Staffs
position is that Section 16-111(i) of the Act creates a ceiling on the rates that can be set and
in the event that a utilitys cost for electric power and energy is less than market plus 10%, the
Commission cannot authorize rates to exceed the utilitys actual cost. Staffs interpretation of
Section 16-111(i) is consistent with Section 16-111(i)(1) which provides that the Commission
should only consider the then current or projected revenues, [and] costs . . . directly associated
with the provision of such tariffed services . . . and Sections 9-101 and 9-201 which provide
that rates must be just and reasonable. Staff argues that to allow a utility to recover more than
its cost would result in a rate that is unjust and unreasonable.
Staff notes that the Commission has broad authority to make appropriate prudence findings
based on the evidence presented, and to incorporate those findings into tariffs providing for
recovery through a rider mechanism. Staff states that ComEds auction-based procurement proposal
fully articulates the criteria and method by which ComEd will enter into contracts for wholesale
power and energy to serve its retail customers removing its discretion in all material respects,
incorporating the resulting
33
05-0159
Proposed Order
wholesale costs, with no mark up, into a formula based translation mechanism to determine retail
rates. Staff contends that this proposal is not properly characterized as an attempt to avoid
regulatory scrutiny or nefariously avoid or transfer risk. Staff asserts that with certain
modifications to ComEds auction proposal, the record supports the prudence finding that ComEd
seeks with respect to its auction-based procurement proposal.
Staff further addresses the legality of Rider CPP, arguing that it is clearly within the
Commissions authority to approve Rider CPP. As articulated by Staff throughout its brief, the
Commission should find that the process for establishing rates under Rider CPP is indeed based on
sound business judgment and would result in just and reasonable rates.
CCG comments on Article XVI post-transition rate-setting authority. (CCG brief at 5-6) The
Restructuring Law notes that [l]ong standing regulatory relationships need to be altered to
accommodate the competition that could fundamentally alter the structure of the electric services
market. (220 ILCS 5/16-101A(b)) The two key provisions under the Restructuring Law that address
the approval of rates after the mandatory transition period are Sections 16-112(a) and 16-111(i).
First, Section 16-112(a) instructs the Commission on how to determine market rates. This, among
other things, includes a determination in accordance with a tariff that has been filed by the
electric utility with the Commission pursuant to Article IX . . . and that provides for a
determination of the market value for electric power and energy. (220 ILCS 5/16-112(a))
Second, Section 16-111(i) mandates that the Commission, in establishing tariffed rates and
charges, is to consider the then current or projected revenues, costs, investments and cost of
capital directly or indirectly associated with the provision of such tariffed services. (220 ILCS
5/16-111(i)) This Section also mandates that [i]n determining the justness and reasonableness of
the electric power and energy component of an electric utilitys rates for tariffed services . . .
the Commission shall consider the extent to the which the electric utilitys tariffed rates. . .
exceed the market value determined under Section 16-112 . . . . (220 ILCS 5/16-111(i))
CCG maintains that Article XVI authorizes the Commission to establish market value through
various means, and it mandates that the Commission take into account the market value in
considering the justness and reasonableness of the charges for the power and energy component of
the tariffed service. ComEd filed its tariffs pursuant to Article XVI and Article IX (discussed
below) for the provision of tariffed services. Those tariffs establish a process for procuring
power and energy in the wholesale market through an auction. The auction, by definition and
design, is a competitive process where various suppliers will bid to provide wholesale full
requirements electricity service to ComEd. The results of the bidding process will establish the
market value for providing electricity service at wholesale under Section 16-112(a) and would also
be the
34
05-0159
Proposed Order
prudently incurred costs to ComEd. Clearly, Sections 16-112(a) and 16-111(i) authorize the
Commission to establish market value.
Section 16-103 requires ComEd to continue to offer bundled electric service to its customers
consistent with the bundled service it provided in 1997. (220 ILCS 16-103(c)) ComEd filed its
tariffs in order to recover its costs so that it can meet its obligation to continue to provide
tariffed service as mandated by the PUA. In addition to Sections 16-112(a) and 16-111(i),
discussed above, the tariffs filed by ComEd are subject to all of the Commissions general
ratemaking authority in Article IX of the PUA. (220 ILCS 5/9-101 et seq.)
For example, according to CCG the procedure for the filing of tariffs, as set forth in Section
9-201(b), provides that the Commission is authorized to suspend tariffs and upon reasonable
notice, to enter upon a hearing concerning the propriety of such rate or other charge,
classification, contract, practice, rule or regulation. The tariffs that were filed by ComEd were
suspended by the Commission. The case was set for hearing and the Commission has an 11-month
statutory deadline within which to make a final determination on the tariffs.
The Commission, under Article IX, shall establish the rates or other charges,
classifications, contracts, practices, rules or regulations proposed . . . which it shall find to
be just and reasonable. (220 ILCS 5/9-201(c)) Accordingly, in setting rates the Commission must
determine that the rates accurately reflect the cost of service delivery and must allow the utility
to recover costs prudently and reasonably incurred. (Citizens Utility Board v. Illinois Commerce
Commission, 166 Ill. 2d 111 (1995)) In this case, ComEds tariffs set forth a mechanism whereby it
will purchase power and energy through a competitive process in the wholesale market through an
auction. As discussed above, the actual cost of service, in this case, is the market value that
will be established through the auction process.
Under Article IX, the Commission has discretion in setting rates. Generally, rates are set
through base rates that attempt to recover a utilitys costs by estimating the total revenues
necessary to recover its operating costs plus a cost of investor capital. (Citizens Utility Board
v. Illinois Commerce Commission, 124 Ill. 2d 195, 200-201 (1988)) In addition, the Commission has
the authority to set rates through automatic cost recovery mechanisms. (See, e.g., City of Chicago
v. Illinois Commerce Commission, 13 Ill. 2d 607, 618 (1958), affirming the Commissions
discretionary authority under Article IX to allow rate recovery of utilitys costs through a
purchase gas adjustment clause, later codified at 220 ILCS 5/9-220; Citizens Utility Board, 166
Ill.2d at 139, affirming recovery of expenditures related to coal tar clean up through a rider
mechanism.)
Taken together, the provisions under Article XVI and under Article IX authorize the Commission
to approve the tariffs filed in the instant proceeding. (CCG Brief at 8)
35
05-0159
Proposed Order
CCG asserts that there is no prohibition in Section 16-103(c) on how the Commission is to set
rates for bundled tariffed services. The purpose of Section 16-103(c) is to ensure that electric
utilities continue to offer to all residential customers and to all small commercial retail
customers in its service area, as a tariffed service, bundled electric power and energy delivered
to the customers premises . . . . (220 ILCS 5/16-103(c))
Section 16-103(c) does require that [f]or those components of the service which have been
declared competitive, cost shall be the market based prices. It does not prohibit the opposite,
namely that if a service is not declared competitive, market based rates cannot be utilized. As
correctly stated in the ALJs ruling, from a simple reading of Section 16-103(c), and its numerous
references to cost, it is clear that market-based prices and cost-based rates are not mutually
exclusive concepts...use of market-based pricing is identified as one method for determining such
costs, not an alternative thereto. (05-0159 ALJ Ruling, June 1, 2005 at 6)
As discussed in CCGs Initial Brief, the Commissions authority for setting rates during the
post transition period rests in Sections 16-111(i), 16-112(a) and Article IX. Furthermore, nothing
in Section 16-103 or any other section of the Public Utilities Act (PUA) limits the Commissions
long-standing plenary authority to determine how tariffed rates are to be set under Article IX
which includes the setting of rates through cost recovery mechanisms based on formulas.
CES asserts that by enacting the Choice Law, the General Assembly formalized its belief that
Illinois retail electric customers will benefit from competition because competitive pressures
lower rates more effectively than regulation. (See ILCS 5/16-101(e)) As the steward of the
competitive retail electric market in Illinois, the Commission, guided by the provisions of the
Customer Choice Law, has been given the authority to approve a market-based structure for all
customers served by ComEds default rates.
|
C. |
|
Relationship of Illinois and Federal Law and Jurisdiction |
ComEd avers that the reasonableness of the price of wholesale power transactions is governed
exclusively by federal law and the FERC and may not be reevaluated by the Illinois Commerce
Commission.
ComEd asserts that the Commission has no jurisdiction over wholesale electricity costs or
rates because they occur in interstate commerce. It is well established that under the Federal
Power Act and the Supremacy Clause of the United States Constitution, wholesale power transactions
are subject to FERCs exclusive regulatory
36
05-0159
Proposed Order
authority including the authority to determine the reasonableness of wholesale energy prices.
ComEd further asserts that it is firmly established that FERCs authority preempts state
regulation of wholesale energy prices. Thus, according to ComEd, a wholesale rate accepted for
filing by FERC binds not only the entities involved but also state authorities. ComEd argues that
where FERC has determined that wholesale prices are just and reasonable, a state may not conclude
otherwise, including by preventing the utility from passing those costs to retail customers.
ComEd next addresses the purpose of Rider CPP. Although the Supremacy Clause precludes ICC
review of the reasonableness of the price of ComEds wholesale power transactions, ComEd filed
Rider CPP to enable the Commission and all interested parties to review the method by which ComEd
would make its wholesale power acquisitions, recover the resulting costs, and allocate those costs
among ComEds different customer classes.
According to ComEd, the AG, relying on Pike County Light & Power Co. v. Pennsylvania PUC, 465
A.2d 735 (Pa. Commw. Ct. 1983), argues that federal law does not preempt the Commissions detailed
review of wholesale electricity transactions and disallowance of utility costs incurred in such
transactions. But Pike County stands only for the proposition that a utility is required to make
prudent choices among available wholesale alternatives, and provides no support whatsoever for the
Attorney Generals attack here on the wholesale market itself.
ComEd argues that the Attorney General, CUB, and CCSAO fundamentally mischaracterize the
nature of federal and state regulatory jurisdiction over wholesale electricity markets.
ComEd argues that the reasonableness of rates and agreements regulated by FERC may not be
collaterally attacked in state or federal courts and the only appropriate forum for such a
challenge is before FERC or a court reviewing the Commissions order. ComEd notes that this
exclusive federal jurisdiction over wholesale electricity transactions stems from their uniquely
interstate character.
ComEd notes that FERC actively regulates the precise issues raised by the AG in its brief:
whether a wholesale market is competitive, and whether a wholesale supplier may charge rates based
on market prices, rather than costs.
ComEd asserts that the ICC has no power to determine, based upon its assessment of the
competitiveness of the wholesale market, whether wholesale transactions should be based upon
market prices or the costs of particular wholesale suppliers. ComEd further asserts that those
are matters exclusively for FERC to decide. ComEd maintains that if parties are dissatisfied with
FERCs regulation of the wholesale market, or with FERCs grant of market-based rate authority to
any particular wholesale supplier, it must raise those objections with FERC, not with this
Commission.
37
05-0159
Proposed Order
ComEd avers that Pike County stands for the narrow proposition that when a utility chooses
among various wholesale providers, it must choose prudently and may not unreasonably favor its own
high-cost affiliate. ComEd states that nothing in Pike County remotely suggests that a state
commission has the authority to declare that the lowest cost wholesale providers rates as
determined in an open auction are too high and may not be recovered through retail rates.
ComEd continues stating that the Pike County courts affirmance of the PUCs disallowance of
costs does not support the proposition that a state commission may review the competitiveness of
wholesale markets or whether a wholesale providers prices are too high. ComEd argues that Pike
County hardly supports rejection of ComEds competitive auction proposal here, in which all
potential suppliers, affiliated and unaffiliated, have an open and fair opportunity to compete to
supply electricity to ComEd. ComEd argues that a State must rather give effect to Congress
desire to give FERC plenary authority over interstate wholesale rates, and to ensure that the
States do not interfere with this authority.
ComEd asserts that it has not impermissibly failed to consider purchasing electricity at
below-market prices from its affiliate. ComEd concedes that if Exelon Generation offers the
lowest available market price at the auction, it will be selected under ComEds proposal.
According to ComEd, low-cost in this context can only mean one thing: at below-market wholesale
prices.
ComEd asserts that the Commission simply cannot compel such a below-market transaction.
ComEd notes that wholesale electricity contracts between affiliated companies are directly
controlled by explicit federal standards, and those standards require FERC review of wholesale
transactions between a utility and an affiliate at market-based rates to ensure that such insider
transactions do not unduly favor affiliates or harm the competitive wholesale market. ComEd
further notes that market-based rates for sales involving affiliates will be found to violate
section 205(a) of the FPA unless there is a clear showing of lack of potential affiliate abuse
According to ComEd, requiring a sweetheart deal between affiliates at below-market rates
would assuredly invite complaints at FERC from wholesale competitors who were foreclosed from
selling in northern Illinois, and private investment in generation could be discouraged as well.
ComEd states that FERC held that for a utility to establish that an affiliate transaction is
reasonable, it must show that the rate is comparable to the price of an arms-length transaction
between non-affiliates. ComEd notes that FERC identified three showings a utility could make to
establish the reasonableness of an affiliate transaction (1) evidence of direct head-to-head
competition between the affiliate and competing unaffiliated suppliers in a formal solicitation or
informal negotiation process; (2) evidence of the prices which non-affiliated buyers were
willing to pay for similar services from the affiliate; or (3) benchmark evidence that shows the
prices, terms and
38
05-0159
Proposed Order
conditions of sales made by non-affiliated sellers. ComEd asserts that none of those criteria
are met in the Attorney Generals proposal.
The AG argues that Illinois retains jurisdiction over retail rates and costs notwithstanding
Federal jurisdiction over wholesale sales. According to the AG, the ICC has exclusive
jurisdiction over retail electricity sales by Illinois public utilities. The AG asserts that FERC
has exclusive jurisdiction over wholesale electricity sales in interstate commerce and the
transmission of electricity in interstate commerce. The AG further asserts that both commissions
are required by their enabling statutes to ensure that the rates over which they have jurisdiction
are just and reasonable.
The AG argues that FERCs jurisdiction extends only to those matters that are not subject to
regulation by the States. The AG further argues that FERCs wholesale ratemaking authority and
the states retail ratemaking authority do not overlap, and there is nothing in the federal
legislation which preempts a state commissions authority to determine the reasonableness of a
utility companys claimed expenses.
The AG asserts that FERC has a duty to ensure that wholesale rates are just and reasonable.
The Federal Power Act (FPA), 16 U.S.C. 791a et seq., declares that . . . the business of
transmitting and selling electric energy for ultimate distribution to the public is affected with
the public interest, and that Federal regulation of . . . the sale of such energy at wholesale in
interstate commerce is necessary in the public interest. (16 U.S.C. 824(a)) The FPA requires
FERC to ensure that wholesale electric rates are just and reasonable. (16 U.S.C. 824e) FERC must
strike a fair balance between the financial interests of the regulated company and the relevant
public interest, both existing and foreseeable. (Farmers Union Cent. Exch. v. FERC, 734 F.2d
1486, 1502 (D.C. Cir. 1984))
The AG asserts that FERC traditionally used cost-of-service rate regulation to set wholesale
electric rates but, over the past decade, has increasingly allowed electricity wholesalers to
charge market-based rates. (Louisiana Energy and Power Authority v. FERC, 329 U.S. App. D.C. 401,
141 F.3d 364, 365 (D.C. Cir. 1998); Elizabethtown Gas Co. v. FERC, 10 F.3d 866, 870 (D.C. Cir.
1993)) FERC may rely on market-based rates in lieu of cost-of-service regulation to ensure that
rates satisfy this [just and reasonable] requirement only where there is a competitive market.
Regarding the rationale for market-based rate authority, The principle justifying this
approach as just and reasonable was that in a competitive market, where neither buyer nor
seller has significant market power, it is rational to assume that the terms of their voluntary
exchange are reasonable, and specifically to infer that the price is close to marginal cost, such
that the seller makes only a normal return on its investment. (California ex rel. Lockyer v.
FERC, 383 F.3d 1006, 1012 13 (9th Cir. Sept. 9, 2004))
39
05-0159
Proposed Order
The AG states that applicants for market-based rate authority are required to demonstrate, on
a continuing basis, that the seller and its affiliates do not have market power and cannot erect
other barriers to entry by potential competitors. . . . FERCs system consists of a finding that
the applicant lacks market power (or has taken sufficient steps to mitigate market power), coupled
with strict reporting requirements to ensure that the rate is just and reasonable and that
markets are not subject to manipulation. (Id. at 1013, quoting Tejas Power Corp. v. FERC, 908
F.2d 998, 1004 (D.C. Cir 1990))
The AG notes that FERC recently revoked Duke Powers market-based rate authority based on
historical data and results of the Commissions pivotal supplier test, market share test, and
market concentration test (using the HHI).
The AG maintains that the FPA contains provisions to protect electric utilities and their
customers from exploitation by affiliates that generate and sell electricity, and these provisions
were expressly preserved in the Energy Policy Act of 2005 stating, Nothing in this subtitle shall
limit the authority of the Commission under the Federal Power Act (16 U.S.C. 791a et seq.) to
require that jurisdictional rates are just and reasonable, including the ability to deny or
approve the pass through of costs, the prevention of cross-subsidization, and the issuance of such
rules and regulations as are necessary or appropriate for the protection of utility consumers.
(P.L. 109-58 Sec. 1267)
The AG notes that FERC assesses the reasonableness of affiliate electric contracts using
criteria set forth in Boston Edison Company Re: Edgar Electric Co., 55 F.E.R.C 61,382 (1991) and
Ameren Energy Generating Co., Union Electric Co., d/b/a AmerenUE, 108 F.E.R.C. 61,081, at n.14
(2004). (AG brief at 16-17) Edgar held that where a seller seeks to sell wholesale power to a
utility affiliate, it must make one of three showings:
|
|
|
evidence of direct head to head competition between the affiliate and competing
unaffiliated suppliers in a formal solicitation or informal negotiation process; |
|
|
|
|
evidence of the prices which non affiliated buyers were willing to pay for similar
services from the affiliate; or |
|
|
|
|
benchmark evidence that shows the prices, terms and conditions of sales made by non
affiliated sellers. |
Last year, FERC held that these three options for demonstrating the reasonableness of an
affiliate sale were not an all inclusive list; the individual facts of a case could bring forth
other examples not expressed in Edgar to show that a transaction is without affiliate abuse.
(Ameren Energy Generating Co., Union Electric Co., d/b/a AmerenUE, 108 F.E.R.C. ¶ 61,081, at n.14
(2004))
40
05-0159
Proposed Order
According to the AG, the ICC can use its retail ratemaking authority to determine whether the
cost of wholesale electricity purchased by an Illinois utility, at FERC-approved rates, was
prudently and reasonably incurred.
The AG states that the Act grants the ICC broad authority to supervise the manner and method
in which the business is conducted by electric utilities in Illinois. (220 ILCS 5/4 101) The AG
notes that the ICC regulates the rates which public utilities charge to retail customers to ensure
that they are just and reasonable. (220 ILCS 5/9-101) The Act specifies that retail rates
charged by public utilities must accurately reflect the cost of delivering those services and
allow utilities to recover the total costs prudently and reasonably incurred. (220 ILCS 5/1
102(a)(iv))
The AG further notes that the ICC has supervised electric utilities, set just and reasonable
rates, conducted prudence reviews and discharged other duties under the PUA for almost a century.
The 1997 Amendments left these regulatory safeguards in place to protect utility customers who do
not have access to electric service that has been declared competitive pursuant to Section 16-113
of the PUA. Hence, according to the AG the ICC will continue to perform all of these regulatory
functions until Illinois completes the transition to fully competitive retail electric markets.
Although the mandatory transition period ends on January 1, 2007, the transition period is far
from over.
The AG asserts that when setting retail rates, the ICC has authority to determine whether the
cost of wholesale electricity purchased at FERC-approved wholesale rates was prudently and
reasonably incurred. (Pike County, 465 A.2d 735 (PA 1983)) In Pike County, the court upheld a
state utility commissions decision to disallow recovery, through retail rates, of a portion of a
utilitys expense of purchasing power from an affiliate at FERC-approved wholesale rates.
The AG maintains that the Court concluded that the state commissions action was regulation
only of Pikes retail rates, and as such proceeded, not from an analysis of [the generation
affiliates] cost of service data, analysis within the exclusive jurisdiction of the FERC, but
rather from analysis of Pikes cost of service and comparison with alternative costs of purchased
power. (Pike County at 737-738) The Court held that FERC approval of the [generation
affiliates] tariffs means only that, as a matter of law, it is reasonable for [the generation
affiliate] to charge such rates; FERC approval does not mean that it is reasonable for Pike to
incur such costs.
The AG asserts that the ICC has broad authority, under Illinois law, to obtain information
from electric utilities to compare alternative costs of purchased power from electric utilities.
(220 ILCS 5/5-101 et seq.) The Federal Power Act further authorizes the ICC to obtain books,
accounts, memoranda, contracts and records of electric utilities regulated by the ICC, generators
that sell electricity to those utilities, and affiliates (including holding companies) of
generators that sell electricity to electric utilities regulated by the ICC.
41
05-0159
Proposed Order
According to the AG, the ICCs authority to review costs incurred by electric utilities, to
determine whether they are just, reasonable and prudently incurred, extends to review of the cost
of electricity procured under wholesale rates established by FERC. (See, generally, Pike County)
The AG asserts that the Commission has extensive powers under state and federal law to obtain
information regarding generation costs and other data needed to determine whether costs are
reasonable and prudent. (220 ILCS 5/5-101 et seq. and 16 U.S.C. 824) The AG argues that neither
Illinois electric utilities, nor their parent companies and generation affiliates, can hide behind
claims that FERC jurisdiction precludes a thorough prudence review by the ICC.
The AG states that according to the Illinois Supreme Court, States retain the authority to
review the prudence of a distributors actions in incurring FERC-approved supply charges when the
distributor had a choice whether to incur the charge. (General Motors Corporation v. Illinois
Com.Commn, 143 Ill 2d 407, 421-22; 574 NE2d 650, 658 (1991))
The AG contends that ComEd incorrectly claims Mississippi Power, Nantahala and General Motors
provide support for its view that where FERC has determined that wholesale prices are just and
reasonable, a state may not conclude otherwise, including by preventing the utility from passing
those costs to retail customers. In General Motors, the Illinois Supreme Court explains, A
State regulatory agency could find that purchase of a particular quantity of power from a
particular source was unreasonable if lower cost power was available elsewhere, even if the cost
of the purchased power had been approved by FERC, and therefore deemed unreasonable. Mississippi
Power, 487 U.S. at 373, 108 S.Ct. at 2440, 101 L.Ed.2d at 340; Nantahala, 476 U.S. at 972, 106
S.Ct. at 2360, 90 L.Ed.2d at 958. (General Motors, 143 Ill 2d at 422; 574 NE2d at 658)
In response to arguments by CCG, the AG asserts that CCG wrongly claims a state commission
is preempted by federal law from reviewing the prudence of power purchases . . . and to permit
such a review would interfere with ... [FERCs] plenary authority over interstate wholesale rates.
Central Vermont Public Service Corporation, 84 FERC 61,194, 1998 WL 765497 (1998)) CCG
mischaracterizes the holding in Central Vermont. There, FERC expressly held that FERCs approval
of a rate schedule does not preclude the Public Utilities Commission . . . from determining
whether [the utility] acted imprudently by not terminating the rate schedule under its terms where
lower-priced power was available to the [the utility]. (84 FERC 61,194, 1998 WL 765497)
Staff notes that in relying on Pike County Light & Power Co. v. Pennsylvania Public Utility
Commn, 77 Pa. Commw. 268, 465 A.2d 735 (1983), the AG seeks to establish that states retain
jurisdiction to examine the prudence of utility purchases of wholesale energy at FERC approved
rates. Staff agrees that state utility commissions are not prohibited from reviewing the prudence
of a utilitys purchases of wholesale power at FERC-approved rates. However, as explained in more
detail below, the ability
42
05-0159
Proposed Order
of the Commission to review the prudence of wholesale power purchases subject to FERC jurisdiction
is limited.
Staff asserts that the auction proposal tends to maximize the Commissions authority and
jurisdiction to impact wholesale procurement decisions for inclusion in retail rates. Staff notes
that this proceeding provides the Commission an extensive opportunity to have binding input into
the rules, practices and procedures that will be utilized to procure wholesale power and energy
for the provision of retail services. As these decisions will be made prior to the wholesale
purchases, they necessarily avoid any conflict with the federal filed rate doctrine explained
below. Staff asserts that these rules, practices and procedures identify the criteria ComEds
management will utilize to procure wholesale electric supply, and allow the Commission to engage
in an upfront prudence determination.
Conversely, Staff argues that the rejection of the auction-based procurement process in favor
of some other process that involves after-the-fact prudence reviews raises the issue of whether
there has been a violation of the filed rate doctrine whenever the Commission finds a wholesale
purchase to be imprudent. Staff notes that while the Commission has authority to make such
prudence determinations, those determinations must fit within the allowable parameters of the Pike
County exception to the filed rate doctrine. Staff submits that the Commissions ability to
exercise its regulatory authority is likely to be more constrained and limited in the
after-the-fact review and rejection process than under the upfront development and approval
process proposed here.
Staff notes that the federal filed rate doctrine is a rule of preemption that requires
state utility commissions to give binding effect to wholesale rates filed with or approved by
FERC. (See Nantahala Power & Light Co. General Motors Corp. Under the filed rate doctrine,
states are required to give effect to determinations made by FERC. Thus, state utility commissions
may not question or alter a FERC-approved wholesale rate or deny recovery of FERC-mandated costs
that the utility cannot avoid.
Staff offers that in setting intrastate rates, state commissions must therefore permit
regulated companies to recover costs and expenses that FERC has already established or approved.
Staff asserts that the court in Pike County recognized an important limitation on this aspect of
the filed-rate doctrine, however, and determined that a state regulatory commission, in setting
local rates, was not automatically required to use the cost of acquiring energy under a
FERC-approved power purchase contract if the company had other supply options available to it.
Staff argues that cases applying what has been termed the Pike County exception have thus
permitted state regulatory commissions to consider the prudence of utility companies decisions to
enter into the underlying contracts and agreements, including transactions with affiliates.
Staff cites Nantahala Power and Light Company, wherein the United States Supreme Court held
that under the filed rate doctrine, the North Carolina Utility Commission (NCUC) could not
reexamine, in a retail rate proceeding, the
43
05-0159
Proposed Order
reasonableness of a FERC-mandated allocation to two affiliated companies of low-cost entitlement
power from the Tennessee Valley Authority (TVA). Staff notes that the Supreme Court concluded
that the filed rate doctrine applied to state action by virtue of the Supremacy Clause; and that
once FERC sets a rate or makes a decision affecting such a rate, a State cannot conclude that the
FERC-approved wholesale rate is unreasonable or interfere with FERCs plenary authority over
interstate wholesale rates. (Nantahala, 476 U.S. at 963, 966-967)
Staff further cites the Pike County decision, wherein the Court noted that a utilitys
purchase of a particular quantity or power at FERC-approved rates could be deemed unreasonable if
lower cost power were available from another source. (Id., 476 U.S. at 972) However, because
Nantahalas calculation of costs for retail rates already included all the low-cost power that
FERC determined it was entitled to receive from the TVA, the determination that Nantahala had
purchased an unreasonably large quantity of high-cost power from TVA conflicted with FERCs order
no differently than a refusal to recognize a FERC-approved rate as reasonable. (Id. at 973)
Staff notes that the Supreme Court reaffirmed its view of the filed rate doctrine and the
plenary authority granted FERC in Mississippi Power & Light. Staff further notes that the Supreme
Court reversed the decision of the Mississippi Supreme Court and found that there was no room
under the filed rate doctrine for the MPSC to make its own determination of reasonable costs after
a mandatory allocation of those costs had been established by FERC.
Staff states that the Illinois Supreme Court has also endorsed the Pike County exception, but
recognizes its limitation. In General Motors Corporation, the Court upheld the Commissions
determination that it had no authority under the filed rate doctrine to conduct a prudence review
of unavoidable FERC-mandated take-or-pay costs. The Court acknowledged, however, the ability of
the Commission to conduct prudence reviews and deny recovery of gas costs incurred pursuant to
FERC-approved rates in certain circumstances.
Staff notes that the Illinois Supreme Court subsequently considered the filed rate doctrine
in United Cities Gas Co. v. Illinois Commerce Commn, 163 Ill. 2d 1 (1994), where the Commission
had denied recovery of certain FERC-approved gas costs based on its finding that the utilitys
allocation of demand charges between its Illinois and Tennessee service areas was imprudent.
After reviewing its holding in General Motors, the Court rejected the argument that the
Commissions decision violated the filed rate doctrine by trapping FERC-approved cost.
According to Staff, the U.S. Supreme Courts decisions in Nantahala and Mississippi and the
Illinois Supreme Courts decisions in General Motors and United Cities establish that state
utility commissions have a limited ability to review the prudence of a utilitys decision to
purchase power at a FERC-approved rate. Federal courts have also held that the filed rate
doctrine applies to market-based rates
44
05-0159
Proposed Order
authorized by FERC. (See Town of Norwood v. New England Power Co., 202 F.3d 408, 419 (1st Cir.
2000))
While the AG is correct that the Commission is not prohibited by federal law from reviewing
the prudence of ComEds purchases of FERC-approved wholesale costs, it is incorrect to suggest
that the Commissions power to conduct such a prudence review is basically unfettered. To the
extent the AG is suggesting that the Commission should look at the costs of wholesale suppliers
(including ComEds affiliates) in determining whether wholesale supply costs were prudently
incurred by ComEd, it is suggesting the very type of review (questioning the reasonableness of the
FERC-approved rate itself) that is prohibited by the filed rate doctrine and not encompassed
within the Pike County exception.
According to Staff, an after-the-fact prudence review of wholesale power purchases as
suggested by the AG would necessarily require some sort of proof that lower cost power was
available elsewhere in order for a denial of recovery of wholesale power costs to pass muster
under the filed rate doctrine. Staff submits that neither it nor any other governmental or
consumer party will be particularly well-situated to present such evidence given that neither
Staff nor any governmental or consumer party is likely to be directly involved in negotiating such
arrangements or otherwise privy to such information. It would seem that such evidence would be
hard to come by even for parties with access to that type of information. Staff offers that the
auction process itself is designed to determine the lowest cost power available to ComEd in a
fair, open and transparent process.
Staff submits that the foregoing analysis of the federal law and jurisdictional considerations
submitted by the AG demonstrate that there are real concerns about the effectiveness of any process
that embodies an after-the-fact prudence review of FERC-approved costs, and that the auction-based
procurement process is better situated to effectuate effective Commission regulation of wholesale
supply procurement decisions.
CCG comments on FERC jurisdiction of wholesale power rates and costs. The FERC regulates the
sale of wholesale power in interstate commerce under Section 201 of the Federal Power Act, 16
U.S.C.S. § 824 et seq., and as a result, wholesale rates and costs are governed exclusively by the
FERC. (See, e.g., New York v. FERC, 535 U.S. 1, 19-20 (2002); Miss. Power & Light Co.; Nantahala
Power & Light Co.)
CCG states that since ComEd no longer has generating facilities, the power that it needs in
order to be able to supply electricity to its customers under tariffed service has to be purchased
at wholesale. The terms of those purchases, including the rates and costs, are reflected in
purchased power agreements that are subject to the FERCs jurisdiction. As FERC pointed out in
Central Vermont Public Service Corporation, 84 FERC ¶61,194 (1998), a state commission is
preempted by federal law from reviewing
45
05-0159
Proposed Order
the prudence of power purchases...and to permit such a review would interfere with the Commissions
[FERCs] plenary authority over interstate wholesale rates.
CCG notes that FERC regulates wholesale sales of power that includes transactions between
affiliates, and has established more stringent criteria in instances that involve affiliate
transactions. (See Boston Edison Co. Re: Edgar Electric Company, 55 FERC ¶61,382 (1991) (Edgar))
CCG cites that the Edgar standards set forth three methods for demonstrating lack of undue
preference to an affiliate: (1) evidence of direct head-to-head competition between the affiliate
and competing unaffiliated suppliers in a formal solicitation or informal negotiation process; (2)
evidence of the prices that non-affiliated buyers were willing to pay for similar services from the
affiliate; and, (3) benchmark evidence that shows the prices, terms, and conditions of sale made by
non-affiliated sellers. FERC expanded the standards in Allegheny Energy Supply Co., LLC, 108 FERC
¶61,082 (2004) (Allegheny).
CCG states that FERC found that the descending clock auction process approved by the New
Jersey Board of Public Utilities met the Edgar and Allegheny standards in Public Service Electric &
Gas Company and PSEG Energy Resources & Trade LLC, 111 FERC 61,152 (2005). In that case, FERC
noted:
[The] underlying principle when evaluating a competitive solicitation process under
the Edgar criteria is that no affiliate should receive undue preference during any
stage of the process. The Commission indicated the following four guidelines will
help the Commission determine if a competitive solicitation process satisfies that
underlying principle: transparency, definition, evaluation and oversight . . . .
[T]he Commission finds that the New Jersey statewide bidding process is an example
of a process that meets these guidelines.
CCG notes that the Illinois Auction Proposal is modeled after the New Jersey auction and, if
approved, would pass muster under FERCs Alleghany and Edgar standards for transactions with
affiliates.
CCG concludes that the auction proposed by ComEd is consistent with, and would meet the goals
of, both Illinois and federal law and policy.
CCG states both the AG and CCSA, among other parties, cited to the Pike County exception in
their Initial Brief for the proposition that states are not precluded from evaluating the prudency
of a utilitys decision to purchase power from a particular source. CCG asserts that in Pike
County, all of Pike Countys power supply was provided by its parent company through a Power Supply
Agreement that had been filed with FERC. The court determined that under the facts of that case,
the Pennsylvania Public Utility Commission could review the prudency of such purchases.
CCG argues that the facts in this case, however, are completely different. The proceedings in
this docket are for the purpose of determining the methodologies and
46
05-0159
Proposed Order
procedures for the purchase of power and energy through an auction which, if approved, would be a
prudent and reasonable way to procure power. Hence, power and energy would be procured through a
Commission-approved competitive process that the Commission would have determined is prudent and
reasonable where various suppliers will be bidding against each other for the opportunity to
provide power supply to ComEd. Under the facts of this case, the prudency review discussed in Pike
County would have taken place in this docket.
|
D. |
|
References to Post-2006 Initiative References and Results |
ComEd addresses references to post-2006 Initiative Reports and Results. As noted by ComEd, a
motion to strike certain such references was denied.
The AG takes issue with references by ComEd and other parties to post-2006 Initiative reports
and results. The AG believes such references are inappropriate and should be disregarded.
The AG argues that Initiative participants relied on the Commissions promise free and open
discussion would be fostered by explicitly protecting Post 2006 Initiative discussion materials and
reports from use in subsequent litigation. The AG asserts that preserving free and open discussion
without fear of later misrepresentation is essential to the workshop process as used by the
Commission.
The AG contends that ComEds use of the Post-2006 Initiative is repetitive, selective and
unnecessary. The AG argues that even if properly admitted, testimony referring to the Post-2006
initiative should be given little or no weight because of the nature of the workshop process and
assumptions made by participants.
Objections to certain references to or characterizations of the Post-2006 Initiative and
reports were ruled upon during the course of this proceeding and are not before the Commission in
this Order.
The Commission believes the Post-2006 Initiative was an innovative and inclusive process that
provided a valuable opportunity to explore and develop alternatives on the critical issues relating
to post-2006 electric supply acquisition.
Parties who disagreed with the thrust of or characterizations in the references to the
Post-2006 process or results thereof were given a full opportunity to express their views in this
docket, as they were in the Post-2006 Initiative itself, and their comments have been duly
considered.
47
05-0159
Proposed Order
|
E. |
|
Conclusions Relating to Commission Authority |
|
1. |
|
Market-Based Rates for Service not Declared Competitive |
One of the arguments made by AG, CUB and CCSAO is that the PUA does not authorize
market-based rates for electric service that has not been declared competitive under Section
16-113.
As indicated above, ComEd, Staff, CCG, CES and MWIPS contend that this argument should be
rejected, as it was in the ruling issued on June 1, 2005 denying a motion to dismiss jointly filed
by several parties including AG, CUB and CCSAO. After oral argument, an interlocutory appeal of
that ruling was denied by the Commission on July 13, 2005.
On this issue, one of the arguments made by AG, CUB and CCSAO is that, contrary to law, the
Proposed Riders replace cost-based rates with market-based rates set by an auction. Much of the
focus is on Section 16-103(c). It provides in part that . . . each electric utility shall continue
offering to all residential customers and to all small commercial retail customers in its service
area, as a tariffed service, bundled electric power and energy delivered to the customers premises
consistent with the bundled utility service provided by the electric utility on the effective date
of this amendatory Act of 1997.
Section 16-103(c) goes on to provide:
Upon declaration of the provision of electric power and energy as competitive, the
electric utility shall continue to offer to such customers, as a tariffed service,
bundled service options at rates which reflect recovery of all cost components for
providing the service. For those components of the service which have been declared
competitive, cost shall be the market based prices. Market based prices as
referred to herein shall mean, for electric power and energy, either (i) those
prices for electric power and energy determined as provided in Section 16-112, or
(ii) the electric utilitys cost of obtaining the electric power and energy at
wholesale through a competitive bidding or other arms-length acquisition process.
(Emphasis added)
Similarly, Section 16-111(i) provides for the consideration of costs in establishing rates for
tariffed services subsequent to the mandatory transition period.
As argued by Staff, ComEd and other parties, it is clear from a simple reading of Section
16-103(c), and its numerous references to cost, that market-based prices and cost-based rates are
not mutually exclusive concepts. To the contrary, use of market-based prices is recognized as a
mechanism for or subset of, not an exception to or replacement of, the development of rate
components based on cost. That is, use of market-based pricing is identified as one method for
determining such costs, not an
48
05-0159
Proposed Order
alternative thereto. In the instant case, ComEds proposal is intended to recover only such costs
as are actually incurred in procuring power and energy through the auction process. How well the
proposal is designed to work in that regard is a different question that is addressed elsewhere in
this order.
Thus, the issue is not whether use of market-based prices is inherently inconsistent with the
principle of setting rate components at cost. As indicated above, it is not.
The next question is whether Section 16-103(c) prohibits the use of an auction or other
market-based process in determining the costs of power and energy in setting rates for
non-competitive customers, as argued by AG, CUB and CCSAO. A close reading of Section 16-103(c)
reveals that no such prohibition exists. What Section 16-103(c) says is that [f]or those
components of the service which have been declared competitive, cost shall be the market based
prices. Hence, rate components for competitive services may only be set, not illogically, by using
market-based prices to establish cost.
Implicit in the position advocated by AG, CUB and CCSAO on this issue is the proposition that
because market-based prices must be used to establish the cost for components of competitive
services, it necessarily follows that market-based prices may not legally be used to establish
costs on which to base rate components for non-competitive services or customers. However, as
indicated by various parties on the other side of this issue, the Act contains no such language,
either in Section 16-103(c) or elsewhere. As those parties correctly observe, the presence of a
statutory mandate to use a particular method for establishing certain cost components for
competitive services does not somehow mean that method is statutorily prohibited for other services
or customers, particularly where, as in the instant case, use of market-based prices is expressly
recognized as one means of establishing costs in Section 16-103(c).
In addition, as several parties have commented, it is difficult to see by what means AG, CUB
and CCSAO envision the cost of procuring power and energy being determined for non-competitive
services in a manner consistent with their theory that market-based prices may not be used to
establish costs on which to base rate components for non-competitive services. As noted above,
Section 16-103(c) contains a broad definition of market-based prices. It provides that market
based prices as referred to herein shall mean, for electric power and energy, either (i) those
prices for electric power and energy determined as provided in Section 16-112, or (ii) the electric
utilitys cost of obtaining the electric power and energy at wholesale through a competitive
bidding or other arms-length acquisition process. (Emphasis added)
Since ComEd has divested itself of all generation assets pursuant to Section 16-111(g) of the
Act, it is unclear how the cost of procuring power and energy would be established for
non-competitive services, when existing contracts expire at the end of 2006, if all such
market-based mechanisms were prohibited as AG, CUB and CCSAO contend. In other words, prohibiting
procurement alternatives that use market-based
49
05-0159
Proposed Order
prices, as that term is defined in Section 16-103(c), would preclude the use of the very
alternatives suggested by AG, CUB and CCSAO, such as contracts with ComEds affiliated generating
company. Under that baby with the bathwater scenario, utilities without generation would be left
with no legal means of procuring supply. In the Commissions view, a theory that leads to such a
result is not a proper interpretation of the statute.
For the reasons set forth, the theory that the proposed auction is prohibited by Section
16-103(c) of the Act should not be adopted.
|
2. |
|
Transfer of Generation Plants |
As indicated above, CCSAO asserts that ComEds need to obtain generation is the result of its
choice to transfer and sell its generation assets pursuant to Section 16-111(g) of the Act.
According to CCSAO, ComEd should have taken additional steps to ensure that it was able to meet its
obligations to residential and small commercial customers post-2006 before completing these
transactions. In CCSAOs view, the Commission should conclude that ComEd failed to act prudently on
behalf of residential ratepayers.
As observed by ComEd, however, this argument is inconsistent with Section 16-111(g). The
transfers in question were authorized by the Commission pursuant to Section 16-111(g), which
provides, in part, that [t]he Commission shall not in any subsequent proceeding or otherwise,
review such a reorganization or other transaction authorized by this Section . . . . Thus, the
Commission declines to find that ComEd failed to act prudently when it transferred its generation
plants pursuant to Section 16-111(g).
As explained above, ComEd, Staff and CCG contend that a review of the prudence of the auction
process should take place in this docket, not in a post-auction prudency review proceeding. That
is, if the process approved in this proceeding is followed in the auction, and the auction results
are certified by the Commission at the conclusion of the three-day review period, then the
acquisitions of supply made pursuant to the auction are deemed prudent and no after-the-fact
prudency review is either necessary or appropriate.
AG, CUB and CCSAO disagree. Among other things, they argue that under Illinois law, the
Commission must assess actual rates, whether they are presented in a rate case under Part 285 and
set prospectively, or presented in the context of a retrospective prudency review under section
9-220 of the PUA and subject to refund. The PUA does not authorize the pre-approval of blank
rates by the Commission under the guise of approving a process. (AG brief at 62-63)
50
05-0159
Proposed Order
The Commission has reviewed the arguments made and authority cited by the parties. In
analyzing this issue, the Commission first observes, generally speaking, that retail rates in
Illinois are set through either (1) the Part 285 test year ratemaking process or (2) a
pass-through rider mechanism.
Some pass-through riders are specifically authorized by statute, such as the UFAC and PGA
mechanisms in Section 9-220 of the PUA. Others are not specifically identified by statute, but are
authorized by Commission order, such as the coal tar riders authorized in consolidated Dockets
01-0080 et al. As discussed above, the Commissions order authorizing coal tar riders was upheld
by the Illinois Supreme Court in the Citizens Utility Board case, 166 Ill.2d 111.
Unlike rates established in a test year ratemaking proceeding, rider mechanisms contain
formula rate methodologies designed to pass through costs as they are incurred. Thus, by their very
nature, they will not identify specific rates or charges because those charges will not be known
until the subject costs are incurred. Therefore, there is no outright prohibition on use of blank
rates or formula rates in pass-through riders. If there were, no such rider could ever be
approved. Such a result would be inconsistent with Section 9-220, which authorizes PGA and FAC
pass-through riders, and with caselaw, such as the decisions in Citizens Utility Board and City of
Chicago, 13 Ill. 2d 607, before that.
In the instant case, one of the key issues before the Commission is whether use of the auction
process to procure electric supply should be subject to annual reconciliation hearings to consider
whether the power acquisition costs being passed through to retail customers were prudently
incurred.
Based on the record in this proceeding, the Commission believes that the proposed vertical
tranche auction process, as modified herein, is reasonably designed to enable ComEd to procure
power supply in a competitive and least-cost manner. In that regard, no alternatives were presented
that represent a more viable approach for procuring power supply after December 31, 2006.
As indicated elsewhere in this order, ComEd has divested itself of its generating plant
pursuant to Section 16-111(g), and must obtain its power supply from others. The provisions of that
section do not appear to contemplate any post-transaction second-guessing of the prudency of those
transfers.
To the extent some parties are arguing ComEd should obtain power at below-market rates from
its generating affiliate, that option appears to run afoul of the Edgar standard discussed above.
As noted above, ComEd, Staff and CCG assert that if the auction process is followed, and the
auction results are approved by the Commission at the close of the three-day review period, then
the acquisitions of supply made pursuant to the auction should be deemed prudent. They claim any
further prudence review of the pass-through
51
05-0159
Proposed Order
of those costs to ratepayers, with no markup or profit, would be pointless and legally unnecessary.
Given the record in this proceeding and the findings above, the Commission believes that if
the auction results are approved by the Commission at the close of the three-day review period,
then ComEd should be entitled to a presumption that the supply obtained pursuant thereto was
prudently purchased.
With respect to any prudence reviews after the Commission certification of the auction
results, the Commission acknowledges that the recommendation of ComEd, Staff and others to preclude
any post-transaction prudence reviews of auction purchases has practical appeal. Based on the
provisions of Section 9-220 of the PUA, however, the Commission believes the better course is to
initiate annual reconciliation hearings to address whether the purchased power costs being passed
through to ratepayers were prudent.
The first sentence of Section 9-220(a) provides, Notwithstanding the provisions of Section
9-201, the Commission may authorize the increase or decrease of rates and charges based upon
changes in the cost of fuel used in the generation or production of electric power, changes in the
cost of purchased power, or changes in the cost of purchased gas through the application of fuel
adjustment clauses or purchased gas adjustment clauses.
Several sentences later, Section 9-220(a) further provides, in part, Annually, the Commission
shall initiate public hearings to determine whether the clauses reflect actual costs of fuel, gas,
power, or coal transportation purchased to determine whether such purchases were prudent, and to
reconcile any amounts collected with the actual costs of fuel, power, gas, or coal transportation
prudently purchased. In each such proceeding, the burden of proof shall be upon the utility to
establish the prudence of its cost of fuel, power, gas, or coal transportation purchases and
costs.
Since the instant proceeding was not filed pursuant to Section 9-220 and ComEd presently has
no fuel adjustment clause in effect, there may be some question as to whether Section 9-220 is
directly applicable to the instant proposal, although AG, CUB and CCSAO claim it is. What is clear
is that the section speaks directly to changes in the cost of purchased power, and where
applicable, it requires annual hearings to consider the prudency of power purchases being passed
through to ratepayers via FAC riders. In the instant case, it undisputed that the supply
acquisitions in question are in fact purchased power.
All things considered, the Commission believes that while the Commission is not precluded from
authorizing a pass-through of procurement costs without formal reinstatement of a FAC, Section
9-220 provides appropriate guidance with respect to the procedures that should be followed for
reviewing the pass-through of purchased power costs, including purchases made pursuant to the
auction. While the instant proceeding and the Commission review during the three-day post-auction
window are
52
05-0159
Proposed Order
important tools in terms of prudency, they do not constitute annual public hearings within the
meaning of 9-220. Furthermore, while the purported lack of discretionary conduct by ComEd in
making the auction-driven purchases may be relevant in the evaluation of the auction proposal and
in the review of auction purchases, there is no language in Section 9-220 exempting no discretion
purchases from the annual reconciliation process.
Accordingly, the Commission finds that power purchases made pursuant to the auction should be
subject to an annual reconciliation proceeding to determine prudency as outlined in Section 9-220.
As discussed below, the proceeding will also be used to reconcile amounts collected with actual
costs as described in Section 9-220.
As indicated above, if the auction results are approved by the Commission at the close of the
three-day review period, then ComEd should be entitled to a presumption that the supply obtained
pursuant thereto was prudently purchased. At the reconciliation proceedings, if ComEd shows that
power purchases were made in accordance with the auction process, ComEd will be deemed to have made
a prima facie showing of prudency within the meaning of Section 9-220.
Whether the Commission is pre-empted by federal law from conducting a post-transaction review
of auction purchases is addressed below.
|
4. |
|
State and Federal Authority; Federal Preemption |
The parties appear to agree that the supply contracts resulting from the auctions will require
FERC approval. There is disagreement, however, on whether or to what extent the Commission has
authority to conduct a post-transaction review of the prudency of federally-approved wholesale
power transactions.
ComEd cites the Supreme Courts Mississippi Power decision for the proposition that [t]he
reasonableness of rates and agreements regulated by FERC may not be collaterally attacked in state
or federal courts. The only appropriate forum for such a challenge is before [FERC] or a court
reviewing the Commissions order. (47 U.S.354, 375)
ComEd also cites Nantahala Power where the Supreme Court stated, Once FERC sets such a rate,
a State may not conclude in setting retail rates that the FERC-approved wholesale rates are
unreasonable. A State must rather give effect to Congress desire to give FERC plenary authority
over interstate wholesale rates, and to ensure that the States do not interfere with this
authority. (476 U.S. at 965, 966)
ComEd contends that the type of analysis and review of wholesale transactions urged by AG, CUB
and CCSAO is not permitted under federal law. Rather, where FERC has determined that wholesale
prices are just and reasonable, a state may not conclude otherwise, including by preventing the
utility from passing those costs to retail customers.
53
05-0159
Proposed Order
AG, CUB and CCSAO, on the other hand, cite Pike County for the argument that the ICCs
authority to review costs incurred by electric utilities, to determine whether they are just,
reasonable and prudently incurred, extends to review of the cost of electricity procured under
wholesale rates established by FERC. The Court held that FERC approval of the [generation
affiliates] tariffs means only that, as a matter of law, it is reasonable for [the generation
affiliate] to charge such rates; FERC approval does not mean that it is reasonable for Pike to
incur such costs. (465 A.2d 735, 739)
According to the Illinois Supreme Court, States retain the authority to review the prudence
of a distributors actions in incurring FERC-approved supply charges when the distributor had a
choice whether to incur the charge. (citing General Motors Corporation, 143 Ill 2d 407, 421-22
(1991)) (emphasis added) They also cite the Central Vermont decision where FERC held that its
approval of a rate schedule does not preclude the Public Utilities Commission . . . from
determining whether [the utility] acted imprudently by not terminating the rate schedule under its
terms where lower-priced power was available to the [the utility].
In response, ComEd says the Court in Nantahala explained, Without deciding this issue, we may
assume that a particular quantity of power procured by a utility from a particular source could be
deemed unreasonably excessive if lower cost power is available elsewhere, even though the
higher-cost power actually purchased is obtained at a FERC-approved, and therefore reasonable,
price. (Nantahala, 476 U.S. at 972, citing Pike County)
The key, however, in ComEds view, is whether lower cost power is available elsewhere.
(Nantahala, 476 U.S. at 972) Whereas the utility in Pike County made no effort even to consider
whether lower cost power was available from suppliers other than its parent, here ComEds
competitive procurement auction is expressly designed to identify the lowest cost power available
from any wholesale supplier.
Having reviewed the arguments and decisions cited, the Commission declines at this time to
find that it is pre-empted by federal law from conducting a post-transaction review of the prudence
of ComEds actions in incurring the FERC-approved supply charges in question.
It appears to the Commission that while jurisdiction over wholesale power supply transactions
does rest with FERC, as argued by ComEd and others, the caselaw also indicates that the states are
not pre-empted from reviewing a utilitys pass-through of such charges to retail customers in some
situations, such as where the utility had a choice whether to incur the charge or where
lower-priced power was available to it.
Furthermore, from a jurisdictional standpoint, it is ComEd who has brought the instant docket
before the Commission and seeks Commission findings relating to the auction procurement process.
Whatever the scope of Commissions jurisdiction over these transactions may be, it is difficult to
see how the Commission is being asked to
54
05-0159
Proposed Order
assert jurisdiction over these issues in this docket while simultaneously finding that it is
somehow pre-empted by federal law from considering the same issues at a later time. Under the
circumstances, to make the pre-emption finding at this time would be, at best, premature.
In any event, as noted above, the subject wholesale supply contracts are subject to FERC
approval. What specific actions FERC will take, including any determinations relating to whether
the utility had a choice in incurring the charge or whether lower-priced power was available to it,
are unknown at this time. To the extent ComEd or other parties believe any approvals actually
granted from by FERC are in fact dispositive of these issues in a manner that supports a
pre-emption argument, they are free to make such arguments at the outset of the reconciliation
proceedings. In the meantime, the Commission will assume that Illinois law still regards prudency
reviews of purchased power transactions as within the Commissions authority to conduct, as
contemplated in Section 9-220 of the PUA.
Such reviews will not, however, consider the relationship between the wholesale suppliers
underlying cost of service and the charges assessed by it to the utility under FERC-approved
wholesale supply contracts. Under the caselaw, that issue is outside the jurisdiction of this
Commission.
|
5. |
|
Prudency of Contingency Purchases |
As discussed elsewhere, ComEd may make contingency purchases as a result of a suppliers
default or for other reasons. Generally speaking, ComEd and Staff agree that no post-auction
prudency review is necessary in situations that ComEd and Staff believe will not involve
discretionary action by ComEd.
The AG disagrees, arguing, among things, that the situations in question, such as purchases
from PJM-administered markets, are not free of judgment and discretion by ComEd. AG also contends
that an annual review of contingency purchases is required by Section 9-220 of the Act.
As indicated above, Section 9-220, where applicable, requires annual hearings to consider the
prudency of power purchases if those costs are being passed through to ratepayers via FAC riders.
In the instant case, it is undisputed that the contingency acquisitions in question are purchased
power. The Commission believes Section 9-220 provides appropriate guidance with respect to the
procedures that should be followed for reviewing the pass-through of contingency power purchases.
In the Commissions opinion, if ComEd wants authorization in this docket to pass through, to
ratepayers, the costs of contingency purchases, such purchases should be subject to annual prudency
reviews as part of the annual reconciliation proceeding.
55
05-0159
Proposed Order
|
6. |
|
Accounting Reconciliation |
As more fully explained elsewhere in this order, Staff recommends that annual docketed
accounting reconciliation proceedings be conducted to reconcile the cost of full requirements
electric supply purchased under Rider CPP with such revenues recorded. Staff also recommends that
other pass-through costs billed under Rider PPO-MVM and Rider TS-CPP be reconciled with revenues
recorded in annual docketed proceedings. ComEd objects to these proposals as burdensome and
unnecessary.
The Commission agrees with Staff that the reporting favored by ComEd does not assure the level
of detail necessary to properly identify and compare procurement costs to revenues, especially by
class. Of the two recommendations before the Commission, the annual reconciliation proceeding
proposed by Staff appears to provide the better balance of accuracy, transparency and efficiency.
Furthermore, an annual accounting reconciliation would appear to be consistent with the
procedures outlined in Section 9-220 of the Act as noted above in the discussion of prudency
reviews. The Commission also observes, however, that even if annual prudency reviews were not
conducted, annual accounting reconciliation proceedings should still be held for the reasons
indicated above.
IV. SUFFICIENCY OF THE COMPETITIVE MARKET
|
A. |
|
Markets Relationship to Auction Process |
ComEd argues the Illinois Auction Proposal will bring the benefits of competitive procurement
to ComEds customers. ComEd asserts that the proposal brings the benefits of a competitive
wholesale market to Illinois customers as well.
Staff takes the position that any deficiency in the competitiveness of the retail electricity
markets add to the urgency and importance of approving viable and appropriate procurement methods
for electric utilities to implement, since consumers who cannot rely on a competitive retail market
should at least be able to rely upon their regulated public utilities to supply them with electric
power. Staff further asserts that deficiencies in the competitiveness of retail electricity
markets say absolutely nothing about which procurement methods are appropriate for electric
utilities to implement.
Staff continues stating that assessing the competitiveness of electricity markets is not
directly pertinent to the debate over how electric utilities in Illinois will acquire electric
power to sell to their customers starting in 2007. Staff argues that a real need exists to
approve a viable and appropriate procurement method for electric utilities to implement.
56
05-0159
Proposed Order
The AG argues that the wholesale electricity market in and around Illinois is not sufficiently
developed at this time, to ensure a level of competition among suppliers that yields competitive
prices. The AG further argues that there are insufficient safeguards in place to prevent the
exercise of market power and inadequate market monitoring mechanisms in place to warrant reliance
on the wholesale market to determine retail prices.
|
4. |
|
Constellation Energy Commodities Groups Position |
CECG states that if the auction process is approved, there will be substantial participation
by suppliers of electricity that will lead to a robust competitive process. CECG asserts that
potential bidders are interested in the product, know how to price it, and that competition brings
suppliers to the process. CECG further asserts that the auction process will ensure the ComEd
procures power and energy in the most cost-effective manner.
|
5. |
|
Midwest Generations Position |
MW Gen argues that opponents have not presented evidence that transmission constraints or
market power exists in northern Illinois. MW Gen further argues that the groundless concerns over
market power and lack of competitiveness in the wholesale market disappear when the weight of the
evidence is considered. (MW Gen Brief at 4) MW Gen states the evidence shows that there are
numerous sources of supply and PJM safeguards to ensure that generators do not engage in market
manipulation. (Ibid)
MW Gen asserts that the wholesale market underlying the auction proposed by ComEd is
sufficiently competitive and well-developed to allow retail customers in northern Illinois to
obtain the advantages of efficient pricing.
The Commission agrees with Staff that the Commission does not have the luxury or the time to
reassess or unravel the General Assemblys decision to enact the Restructuring Law. As the record
amply demonstrates, ComEd possesses no generation assets and the current contracts for supply
expire December 31, 2006. The Commission must ensure that Illinois utilities possess a viable
procurement process. The Commission is of the opinion that in the near term, the only viable
approach relies upon the wholesale market.
The Commission also notes that the FERC has concluded that the wholesale market is competitive
and allows the sellers in that market to sell at market-based rates. No party has offered any
legal or evidentiary justification for rejecting the FERCs findings in this regard.
57
05-0159
Proposed Order
|
B. |
|
Other Jurisdictions Experiences with Competitive Electricity Procurement |
ComEd notes that the Illinois Auction Proposal is patterned on the New Jersey Basic Generation
Services, (BGS) auctions. ComEd further notes that New Jersey has conducted auctions since 2002
to acquire electric supply for four New Jersey electric distribution companies. ComEd asserts that
the New Jersey auctions have been successful.
CECG points out the similar observation, that ComEds proposal is modeled after the New Jersey
auction process. CECG states that it has been providing wholesale full requirements electricity to
utilities in Maine, Massachusetts, New Jersey, and Maryland. CECG asserts that the experience in
other states should be considered by the Commission.
The AG notes that the state of restructuring in the US has taken a dramatic turn since 2000.
The AG states that only 16 states and the District of Columbia have fully implemented legislation
and commission orders that allow full retail access for all customer groups. Two other states
allow retail access only for larger customers. The AG notes that several states have rolled back
restructuring and 26 states are no longer considering restructuring.
The AG continues stating that states that have used bidding or auctions have experienced price
increases. The AG argues that the increases can not be explained simply by increased fuel costs.
The AG notes that other states have had either flat retail prices or nominal increases because of
long-term coal contracts. (AG Brief at 27)
The AG further argues that Maine, Maryland, and Massachusetts that rely on the wholesale
market to provide for retail customers have all seen an increase in rates for residential
customers.
Although views from other states may be helpful to the Commission, the Commission is not bound
by those decisions and will look to the record in this matter for what is most advantageous to
Illinois customers. Additionally, the Commission is required to follow Illinois law, not laws of
other states.
58
05-0159
Proposed Order
|
C. |
|
Retail Market Conditions |
ComEd argues that in its retail service territory, many large, and a number of smaller
commercial and industrial customers, have taken advantage of offerings by competitive retail
electric service providers and that these providers depend on the wholesale markets opened up by
federal policy. ComEd notes that no residential customers take service from a Retail Electric
Supplier (RES). ComEd asserts that residential customers have indirectly benefited from
restructuring including the 20 percent rate reduction.
CES states that the competitive conditions in Illinois have yielded something on the order of
$4 billion in savings for Illinois residential and non-residential consumers since passage of the
Restructuring Act. CES argues that the competitive market in Northern Illinois for commercial and
industrial customers has developed well, as is evidenced by the portion of load that has moved from
bundled service to delivery service. CES asserts that the number of business customers that have
switched and the size of the load served demonstrate a developed market. CES continues stating
that customers have saved in the neighborhood of $1 billion for business customers from the
commencement of open access in 1999 to 2004.
The AG comments that many retail markets have remained relatively inactive, particularly for
smaller residential customers. States that have utilized competitive market procurement have seen
significantly greater price increases for electric service increase than states that have retained
traditional regulatory processes. The failure of competition to constrain prices and provide
efficient and fair prices is shown in those states that have attempted to procure power exclusively
from competitive markets. Learning from the experiences of other states can save Illinois consumers
up to a billion dollars per year, while insuring safe, adequate and reliable electric service.
IIEC argues that Illinois customers are not currently getting the full benefit of a
competitive market and that is illustrated by the wide disparity between the number of RESs serving
customers in the Ameren territory and the number of potential wholesale suppliers who might
participate in the proposed auctions. IIEC notes that only 8 RESs operated in the Ameren territory
while more than 30 wholesale suppliers might participate in the proposed wholesale auctions.
IIEC asserts that in the segment of the retail supply market that many consider to be the one
in which retail suppliers are most likely to compete, the level of retail supplier
59
05-0159
Proposed Order
activity has been unimpressive. IIEC believes this is due in part to the Reciprocity Clause
which has stymied the development of a fully open competitive retail supply market.
IIEC argues that the competitive market is not as open as other parties would have the
Commission believe.
The Commission concludes that the auction process approved herein with safeguards adopted is
an appropriate method of procuring electricity. The record shows that the proposal will keep ComEd
costs of procuring energy and capacity at a minimum, which will benefit its customers. The
Commission finds the AGs discussion of potential problems to be somewhat speculative concerning
alleged market failures that have not occurred and that may not occur. Moreover, the AGs
suggestion that policy makers use care when determining policy is a reasonable proposal for the
Commission, however it is not a reason to reject a competitive procurement mechanism.
|
D. |
|
Relevant Product Market |
ComEd states that bidders will need to acquire a range of products to serve the
full-requirements load of ComEd. ComEd further states that in addition to base load, bidders will
need intermediate and peaking resources, certain ancillary services, and will likely acquire
hedging products. ComEd states that suppliers that bid into the auction can access this amount of
generation through the bilateral market and such bilateral contracts can supply both the energy and
the capacity markets.
|
2. |
|
Physical vs. Financial Markets |
ComEd argues that one of the features of the PJM energy and capacity markets that will ensure
a robust auction is that PJM automatically dispatches the generation connected to the system to
serve customer demands every day. ComEd states that the supplier is committed to sell at a fixed
price, but there is no risk of customers not being served if the supplier does not schedule
deliveries of power; the supplier will simply owe PJM for the power that PJM dispatches. ComEd
asserts that the financial arrangements for supplying power are independent of the actual physical
power that is delivered.
ComEd notes that most discussion focuses on the energy markets, because they are the
fundamental source of the supply needed to meet customer demands. ComEd
60
05-0159
Proposed Order
continues that without capacity to back up energy, however, the continuity of service to
customers cannot be assured. ComEd asserts that to assure the reliability of supply to end-use
customers, PJM requires that all load-serving entities back up their obligations to serve customers
with capacity. The capacity can be in the form of generation owned by or under contract to the
load-serving entity. In addition, however, PJM operates a capacity market in which any supplier
can secure the necessary capacity. ComEd further asserts that the PJM capacity market further
assures robust participation in the auction, including by parties that do not own generation.
ComEd asserts that Intervenors offer various speculative arguments that northern Illinois
could become isolated from PJM energy markets and thus should be considered a separate market.
ComEd argues that these speculations were refuted by hard evidence. ComEd states that Reliability
Pricing Model (RPM) is a new way of managing the capacity market that PJM has proposed to FERC.
ComEd asserts that under RPM there could be differences in locational capacity prices that differ
based on system congestion, just as there are differences in locational marginal prices in the
energy markets now. According to ComEd, PJMs RPM proposal would not result in separate prices for
load connected to the ComEd system, nor would it produce separate markets in which local generation
could exercise market power in capacity.
The AG states that the capacity credit market is relevant to the proposed auction process
because potential auction participants that do not have available capacity of their own will have
to either purchase capacity credits in the market or make bilateral arrangements with those that do
have capacity.
The AG states that under PJM rules, each load-serving entity (LSE) has the obligation to own
or acquire capacity resources equal to the peak load that it serves, plus a reserve margin. The AG
further states that LSEs can acquire capacity by buying or building units, by entering into
bilateral contracts for capacity, or by participating in the capacity credit markets operated by
PJM. The AG asserts that the PJM capacity credit markets are designed to balance the supply of and
demand for capacity not met through the bilateral market or through self-supply. Competitive LSEs
that need to acquire the capacity resources required to meet their capacity obligations, or to sell
capacity resources when no longer needed to serve load, participate in these markets.
The AG argues that the PJM Market Monitoring Units (MMU) structural analysis of the ComEd
area capacity credit market showed high levels of concentration in the monthly and multi-monthly
capacity credit markets. The HHIs for these markets averaged 6419, and ranged from 2804 to 10000.
The AG notes that the MMU noted that [o]ne entity owned or controlled nearly two-thirds of total
capacity in the ComEd Control Zone.
The AG states that the residual supply index (RSI), a measure of the percentage of load that
can be met without the largest supplier, for the ComEd Control
61
05-0159
Proposed Order
Area monthly and multi-monthly capacity credit market auctions averaged 2.58 and had a minimum of
zero, meaning that in at least one auction, only one capacity supplier participated. Of the 48
capacity auctions held, 26 had a RSI of less than one, meaning at least one supplier was pivotal in
over half the auctions.
The AG argues that given these conditions in the capacity markets, and the MMUs assessment
that the likelihood of the exercise of market power is high, suppliers that do not already have
capacity available could find it very difficult to participate in the proposed auction.
|
c. |
|
CUBs and CCSAOs Position |
CUB argues that the PJM wholesale energy and capacity markets in the northern Illinois region
are not fully competitive and the relative immaturity of the MISO spot energy markets and the
insufficient scope of capacity and ancillary service structures in MISO result in a high level of
uncertainty concerning the competitiveness of the MISO spot energy markets.
The Commission concludes that PJM operates a regional capacity market from which bidders can
acquire required capacity and that will promote participation in the auction. In particular, the
record shows that the PJM capacity market can meet the needs of suppliers who do not have either
their own capacity or pre-existing bilateral contracts for capacity. Moreover, that market extends
throughout the PJM region and contains numerous unaffiliated buyers and sellers and a volume many
times greater than that required to serve ComEds POLR load. The Commission does not agree with
the AGs comments on potential market power in the so-called ComEd capacity market. The Commission
also finds that the RPM will not create a separate capacity market in Illinois, but rather, the
record shows that RPM is instead a new way of managing the capacity market that PJM has proposed to
the FERC. It does not appear from the record that ComEd will be isolated from PJM energy markets.
|
E. |
|
Relevant Geographic Market |
|
1. |
|
Significance of Political Boundaries |
ComEd argues that the geographical markets for electricity are not determined by the political
boundaries of a state, but by the access of consumers to suppliers and the extent to which one
supplier can be substituted for another. ComEd notes that it now has access to the entire PJM
market and to the adjoining MISO market. ComEd further argues that northern Illinois is neither a
relevant market nor a separate market.
62
05-0159
Proposed Order
ComEd believes that the evidence in this proceeding demonstrates that northern Illinois is not
a separate market for which generation concentration statistics can meaningfully be calculated.
ComEd asserts that it is an integral part of the multi-state PJM market. ComEd disagrees with
certain Intervenors arguments that generators in northern Illinois may be able to exercise market
power that could adversely affect the auction.
The AG states that the terms relevant market or relevant geographic market are terms used
in antitrust regulation that have specific meanings. The AG argues that electricity happens to be
a product for which it is particularly difficult to determine the relevant market area because of
transmission constraints that change daily, by season, and over time as load changes. The AG urges
the Commission to conduct an analysis to study of market conditions prior to making decisions
regarding the auction. The AG continues stating that in the absence of such an analysis, however,
price and market concentration data from the PJM MMU and other industry sources can be used to
characterize and compare the ComEd area in Northern Illinois, PJM-east and the whole of PJM.
According to the AG, prices have been converging between the ComEd area in Northern Illinois
and PJM east of Illinois which means higher prices in Northern Illinois than before the formation
of the PJM market. The AG notes that ComEd prices are distinct and lower than the PJM prices in
early 2004 and that after May 1, 2004, the prices are a little closer, and closer still after AEP
and Dayton were integrated in PJM after October 1, 2004. The AG concludes that there is in fact
convergence, and the difference usually was positive, meaning the PJM price was greater that the
ComEd price.
The AG argues that there is excess capacity in Northern Illinois and generally higher prices
in the eastern part of PJM. As a result according to the AG, when the markets were integrated, the
northern Illinois price was expected to rise to the price in the larger PJM area. The AG argues
that this opportunity to access higher priced markets in PJM east was a major reason that
generators in Northern Illinois preferred to be integrated into PJM.
CCSAO argues that as a separate control zone within PJM, and formerly a separate control area,
the ComEd region in Northern Illinois is an appropriate area in which to measure market
concentration post-2006 because of the potential for transmission limitations to restrict the
ability of non-Northern Illinois generation to effectively compete with internal Northern Illinois
generation.
63
05-0159
Proposed Order
CUB asserts that Northern Illinois is the appropriate market to test for the presence of
market power because during times when transmission constraints bind, PJM suppliers not located in
northern Illinois and other competing suppliers in MISO cannot directly compete with northern
Illinois suppliers.
CUB further asserts that the existence of separate wholesale market structures in Illinois
(PJM in the north, MISO in the central and southern regions) characterizes the market in which the
propose auction will take place. CUB argues that the outcome of the proposed auctions for ComEd
will be influenced by the ability of participants in the MISO region to effectively compete with
PJM suppliers; however the MISO market remains immature and the price outcomes in that marketplace
are uncertain. Since MISO participants will rely on the MISO market to some extent in determining
the prices they offer into the proposed auction, the MISO market immaturity will be reflected in
the outcome of the proposed auction. CUB further argues that it is premature to assume that the
MISO market will produce competitive outcomes.
The Commission finds that the parties generally agree that political boundaries have no
significance to the market for electricity. The Commission notes the AGs contention that a
relevant market should be defined, according to antitrust principles, but also notes that the
scope of this proceeding and the Commissions authority does not include determining antitrust
issues. The Commission finds that the relevant market in these proceedings is PJM. The Commission
also notes that FERC must approve the auction.
|
2. |
|
PJM/MISO Seam & Joint Operation Agreement |
ComEd notes that there are two Regional Transmission Organizations, PJM and MISO, in Illinois,
in the northern and southern parts of the state, respectively. ComEd disputes the notion that the
seam between the RTOs poses impediments to transactions occurring between the two, and that this
would make markets in both RTOs less competitive. ComEd believes that even if these assertions
were true they would be irrelevant, since the PJM market is more than adequate to support the ComEd
auction even if the MISO market were totally inaccessible. ComEd argues that Intervenors ignore
the fact that PJM and MISO will implement a joint and common market under which they will
essentially operate as one entity and the two RTOs have already taken the essential steps towards
the joint and common market. ComEd asserts that day to day operations are now being handled under
the PJM/MISO Joint Operating Agreement (JOA). ComEd notes that the JOA has contributed to
operational integration between the two RTOs, assisted in the smooth inter-operation of their
markets and their cooperative management of system congestion, and is a major step toward a full
joint
64
05-0159
Proposed Order
and common market. ComEd asserts that the practical effect of the JOA is to substantially
blur the electrical boundaries between the two RTOs, so that the boundary seams are
disappearing.
ComEd argues that the coordination under the JOA facilitates the reliable and efficient
movement of power between the two RTOs and will result in the same power flows on the gridand thus
the same locational marginal prices as if ComEd and AEP were in the MISO. ComEd further notes
that, as of December 1, 2004, FERC eliminated the transmission barrier between the two RTOs, so
that a transaction passing between them pays only one transmission rate, not two, thus the cost of
transmission will be the same, whether the generator is located in MISO or PJM.
CUB argues that the existence of the PJM-MISO seam presents a barrier to trade across the
regions and limits the ability of non-PJM suppliers to reach the northern Illinois region and
compete in an integrated marketplace. CUB argues that progress towards minimizing the seams effect
is insufficient; and that the existence of the seam remains even in the presence of the joint
operating agreement between PJM and MISO. CUB asserts that the different market structures of PJM
and MISO e.g., PJM has integrated regulation and reserve markets, and a separate capacity market,
where MISO has none of those features; and PJM has a stricter market monitoring and mitigation
protocol limit the effectiveness of competition between the regions.
CUB asserts that the PJM market monitors ability to mitigate the exercise of market power in
the PJM energy markets is limited. CUB further states that the PJM MMUs authority to mitigate
market power may be further eroded pending current FERC actions.
CCSAO notes that the PJM-MISO seam consists of the physical transmission interconnections
between the two RTOs and that this seam spans over one hundred interconnection points with a
nominal non-simultaneous transfer capability on the order of at least 60,000 MW. CCSAO argues that
the seam between PJM and MISO presents a barrier to effective trade between the regions, running
directly across Illinois, separating the wholesale electric markets in Northern Illinois from those
in Southern Illinois, thereby denying Northern Illinois residents the benefits of a cohesive,
integrated wholesale marketplace for electricity purchase by prospective retail suppliers.
The Commission concludes that the seam between PJM and MISO will not affect the competitive
environment in either RTO. The record shows that such seam has diminished, and that the RTOs have
already moved towards creating a joint and common market. The RTOs are already operating together
under the JOA. The RTOs
65
05-0159
Proposed Order
have the same power flows on the grid and same locational marginal prices, and now have a
single transmission rate. The record indicates that even if there were some sort of impediment
from a seam, it would be irrelevant, as the PJM market is more than adequate to support the
ComEds auction, regardless of the accessibility of the MISO market.
|
F. |
|
Market Characteristics, Including Supplier Concentration |
ComEd states that the universally used measure of market concentration is the
Herfindahl-Hirschman Index (HHI) statistic adopted in the Merger Guidelines published by the U.S.
Department of Justice and the Federal Trade Commission. ComEd asserts that in accordance with
these Guidelines, these market concentration statistics are calculated only for a relevant
geographical market. ComEd takes issue with the Ags reliance on HHI calculations that purport to
show that northern Illinois is a concentrated market despite not claiming that it is a market at
all, and despite FERCs conclusion that the issue of generation market power within PJM should be
analyzed on a PJM-wide basis.
ComEd believes that it has demonstrated that even if one believed northern Illinois were a
relevant geographic market, a proper calculation of HHIs would show that this market was only
moderately concentrated, rather than highly concentrated. According to ComEd the evidence shows
that even a monopolist who owned all the generation in northern Illinois could not
profitably raise prices. ComEd notes that because HHIs are only meaningful in a relevant
geographic market, this makes the purported market concentration calculations wholly irrelevant.
ComEd argues that a fundamental feature of the Illinois Auction is that suppliers do not bid
to provide wholesale market products, but rather compete to supply a wide range of integrated risk
management services along with a portfolio of other products. ComEd further argues that the
distinction between the product in the auction, for which suppliers compete, and the wholesale
products in whatever relevant market might be are two entirely different things. According to
ComEd, even if there were concentration in the wholesale product market, it would not tell us
whether there is concentration in the market for the auction product.
The AG notes that a competitive market is usually defined as a market that has many buyers and
sellers, relatively easy entry to the market by sellers, readily available product information for
buyers, and a market price that no buyer or seller has the ability to significantly affect. Few
markets fit the textbook definition of a perfectly competitive market, however. Markets vary by
the degree of their competitiveness. A significantly imperfect market may have problems similar to
an imperfectly regulated one, such as,
66
05-0159
Proposed Order
prices significantly above competitive levels, an inefficient allocation of resources, and
relatively few choices for customers.
The AG asserts that in the ComEd control area, generation ownership is extremely concentrated.
Even though ComEd is now integrated into the PJM system, transmission limitations restrict import
capabilities. The AG argues that one or two suppliers could potentially have considerable
influence on the market price in the ComEd Control Area during most hours of the year. Therefore,
extra caution is called for in relying on this wholesale market to provide reasonably competitive
results.
The AG notes that with respect to energy markets, the MMU concludes that the ComEd Control
Area was highly concentrated overall and in each segment of the supply curve. The MMU uses the
HHI to measure market concentration. The AG states that the HHI is the sum of the squared market
shares of the suppliers in the market. To characterize market concentration using the HHI, the MMU
uses the U.S. Department of Justice merger guidelines , which have been also adopted by FERC. If
the HHI is less that 1000, the market is not considered concentrated. An HHI between 1000 and 1800
means that the market is moderately concentrated. If an HHI is above 1800, the market is highly
concentrated.
The AG states that in the 2004 State of the Market report, the MMU calculated HHIs for three
separate phases of PJM development and compared import capabilities as new control areas were
integrated. The HHIs for the PJM energy markets during 2004 ranged
from 811 to 1634, which
indicates that these markets were unconcentrated to moderately concentrated. The HHIs for the PJM
capacity markets ranged from 909 to 1058, reaching just into the moderately concentrated range.
The AG argues that there is a dramatic difference in the level of market concentration in the
ComEd Control area, compared with PJM overall. The MMU found that both the hourly energy market
and the capacity market are highly concentrated in the ComEd Control Area. The HHIs in the ComEd
control area ranged from 4005 to 7746 for the hourly energy market and ranged from 2670 to 4065 for
the capacity market. When examined in terms of supply curve segments (i.e., base, intermediate,
and peak plants), all the HHIs indicate high concentration in the ComEd control area. For the base
supply curve segment, all the HHIs were greater than 9000. The maximum peak HHI actually reaches
10,000 the maximum possible HHI value indicating that a single firm supplied the market during
those peak load conditions. The HHI for base load installed capacity was 9,304, also exceedingly
high. AG Exhibit 1.2 compares the ComEd HHIs with the PJM HHIs in the energy market. AG Exhibit
1.3 compares the ComEd HHIs with the PJM HHIs in terms of installed capacity.
The AG states that the MMU calculated the RSI on an hourly basis for each generation owner in
PJM. The MMU also calculated the RSI for the two largest PJM suppliers on a combined basis. For
PJM during 2004, the RSI was less than 1.00 for only eight hours of the calendar year, and the
average RSI was 1.64. When the top two suppliers were combined for this calculation, the number of
hours that the RSI was less
67
05-0159
Proposed Order
than 1.00 jumped to 182, but this represents just over two percent of the hours in a year.
This means that it was only occasionally that a supplier or the top two suppliers were pivotal and
perhaps could influence prices. These results do not guarantee that the market is competitive,
only that one or two suppliers are not dominant and critical to meeting customer load for most
hours.
|
3. |
|
CUB and CCSAOs Position |
CUB/CCSAO asserts that the market is not sufficiently competitive, and the foundation for a
successful procurement requires a well-functioning, fully competitive wholesale market. CUB/CCSAO
further asserts that generation capacity and energy supply concentration in the Northern Illinois
region in post-2006 coupled with the pending expiration of the existing ComEd-Exelon contracts for
BUS supply will result in the ability of Northern Illinois generation suppliers to exercise market
power at times, leading to wholesale market prices that do not reflect competitive market outcomes.
CUB/CCSAO states that a generation supplier has the ability to exercise generation market
power when its actions have the effect of raising prices above competitive levels for a significant
period of time. Concentration of generation ownership gives a supplier or a group of suppliers the
ability to either physically or economically withhold generation, resulting in clearing prices
higher than those expected in a competitive market. Physical withholding of generation is when a
supplier or suppliers reduce the availability of generation to sell or schedule into the physical
marketplace, or spot markets. Economic withholding is when a supplier or suppliers increase (above
marginal cost) the price at which they are willing to sell into the spot marketplace. In either of
these instances, the spot market clearing price will be above the clearing price that would have
resulted in a competitive market and the generation owner or owners and other spot market
suppliers will earn greater revenues than they would have earned in a competitive market. Exelon
and Midwest Generation together still account for more than 50% of the installed capacity in the
Northern Illinois region, even when taking simultaneous import capacity into account. In Northern
Illinois, both the spot market and the forward bilateral markets will be influenced by the exercise
of market power. For example, auction participants perceptions of higher spot market prices will
lead to higher bilateral market prices, including those negotiated in advance of the auction,
reflecting the expectation that spot prices would be high.
CUB/CCSAO further states that as long as Exelon is contracted to supply ComEds BUS needs
through December 2006, the high ownership concentration levels in the northern Illinois region are
less likely to lead to market power abuse in the PJM spot markets, since Exelons Northern Illinois
capacity is committed to serving the BUS load. However, once that capacity becomes uncommitted,
Exelon is free to either sell into the spot market or negotiate bilateral sales to market
participants, without any oversight of the ICC or FERC (if market-based rate authority is granted
and/or renewed by FERC). The current load obligation serves to mitigate the likely exercise of
market power; but once the load obligation terminates, effective mitigation ceases and the
68
05-0159
Proposed Order
pricing outcomes in both the spot and the proposed auction process will be subject to highly
concentrated market forces.
CUB/CCSAO asserts that Post-2006, when transmission constraints bind into the Northern
Illinois region, the ability of non-Northern Illinois generators to effectively compete with
Northern Illinois generators is eliminated or at least diminished (considerably so for many
generators in PJM who are electrically distant from the Northern Illinois region). Thus, the
relevant market will still be a subset of the broader PJM RTO market during these times, and it is
at these times that market power can be exercised in the region.
The Commission finds CUB-CCSAOs and the AGs assertions regarding the possible effects on the
auction of concentration of physical generation in northern Illinois to be unsubstantiated and
contrary to the evidence establishing that bidders will operate in the PJM regional market and will
not be limited by physical generation location. Their assertions depend in large part on HHI
calculations that are meaningful only in a relevant geographic market. The record shows that
northern Illinois does not constitute such a market. ComEd presented two studies showing that the
relevant geographic market is the interstate PJM market, of which northern Illinois is just one
part. Moreover, even CUB-CCSAO and the AG disclaimed the concept of a separate northern Illinois
market. Accordingly, the Commission rejects the AGs call for further analysis.
|
G. |
|
Transmission Constraints |
ComEd presented evidence from witnesses, including professional engineers and experienced
system operators that there are no transmission constraints that currently exist or that are likely
to exist in the future, that would prevent generation from outside northern Illinois from competing
with Illinois generation in the auction. ComEd presented two studies demonstrating this point.
The first study showed that prices in the ComEd zone are essentially identical to prices in a wide
interstate region, thereby demonstrating that transmission constraints are not separating northern
Illinois from the broader PJM market. The second study showed that a monopolist who owned all the
generation in northern Illinois could not profitably raise prices because so much replacement
generation would come in from outside Illinois. ComEd explained that because Northern Illinois
exports low cost energy for which there is no demand in northern Illinois, area generators would
first have to forego export sales (that create counter flows on the transmission system) before
even beginning to use up the substantial import capacity into northern Illinois. In addition,
ComEd presented data directly demonstrating that there were no significant transmission constraints
to importing power into northern Illinois. Moreover, ComEd presented testimony of actual operating
conditions that confirmed that there are no such constraints. In particular,
69
05-0159
Proposed Order
PJM data on limiting transmission elements in the area around northern Illinois show no
significant constraint into northern Illinois, and this is confirmed by transmission loading relief
data.
ComEd also showed that the PJM markets have efficient means of dealing with transmission
congestion that will not freeze bidders with generation out of the auction. PJM dispatches all
generation on an integrated basis consistent with system operation; this is called
security-constrained economic dispatch, meaning that PJM directs the generators to operate in the
very best (i.e., most economic) way possible consistent with serving all the load. ComEd explained
that any local transmission limits are internalized by the market, which adjusts the dispatch to
make sure that all the load is served while at the same time there is no violation of constraints
on the transmission system. In other words, the PJM computer model yields the most economic
dispatch of generation that will make maximum use of the transmission system in every hour. Unlike
the prior regime, where flows were transactions that were routinely limited as a means of
addressing congestion, PJM handles local congestion with market pricing and, moreover, allows a
variety of hedges (e.g., FTRs) to be used by sellers and buyers to avoid or minimize even those
costs.
The AG notes that in recent years, the electric transmission system has been required to
perform two critical functions. First, is the traditional and important task of maintaining system
reliability. To perform this function the system must be able to meet energy and demand
requirements at all times and to withstand sudden system disturbances. It appears, at this time,
that the Illinois regions ability to meet this reliability requirement is adequate in the near
term.
According to the AG, the electrical system is now also being required to provide a second
critical function: market support. The AG notes that in a 2003 report, the North American Electric
Reliability Council noted that the transmission system is being subjected to flows in magnitudes
and directions that were not contemplated when it was designed or for which there is minimal
operating experience.
The AG argues that if this trend of local transmission construction continues as expected, it
presents a serious challenge to the development of competitive wholesale markets. The AG notes
that while this problem is recognized and is being addressed by both PJM and the Midwest ISO (and
other ISOs and RTOs as well), it will, at best, take many years to remove transmission constraints
and to reach a point where the transmission system can provide the open access needed to support a
more developed competitive wholesale market.
The AG argues that ComEd erroneously asserts that PJM mitigation rules will ensure that the
wholesale electricity markets are competitive even where there are transmission constraints.
The AG states that ComEd apparently assumes that because PJM is operating the markets and
maintaining system reliability, and because these
70
05-0159
Proposed Order
markets are active and have forward markets present that this implies the market is competitive.
The AG argues that ComEd is confusing market activity with degree of competitiveness and that there
is not yet enough information on which to base a conclusion that regional wholesale electricity
markets are sufficiently competitive to support an auction.
CCSAO argues that there has been no relevant and detailed prospective analysis of post-2006
transmission constraints during summer periods (2007-2011) into the Northern Illinois region by the
auction proponents that demonstrates that transmission constraints into the region are not
problematic during summer peak periods. CCSAO states that its analysis is retrospective, and does
not include data from key summer months, July and August. CCSAO Brief at 25
CUB argues that market power may be present during 2007-2011 because of transmission
constraints.
The Commission is of the opinion that northern Illinois does not experience binding
transmission constraints that would cause it to separate from the rest of PJM and become a load
pocket or that would prevent competition in the auction by parties not owning local generation.
ComEd presented multiple studies and other data showing that no such constraints exist presently,
or are expected to exist in coming years. ComEd also presented evidence that the purpose of the
RTO planning process is to anticipate and respond to developing transmission needs, and that this
Commissions record of approving transmission construction projects is excellent. The Commission
observes that the assertions of the AG and CUB-CCSAO about potential transmission constraints are
not only speculative and contrary to the most recent data available, but also do not focus on the
fact that most constraints will impede neither the market nor competition in the auction. The
Commission therefore concludes that there is no reason to believe that transmission constraints
affecting Illinois or the PJM markets in general, will impede the Illinois Auction Proposal.
|
H. |
|
Limitations on Generator Entry |
ComEd notes that in the near term (i.e., before new generation can be built), entry is not
needed to discipline prices, as there is substantial excess capacity in the relevant market. ComEd
continues stating that considering the longer term, the existing transmission system and operating
rules permit efficient generator entry, and historically generator entry has occurred with a high
degree of rapidity. ComEd argues that because the PJM markets have visible locational prices, the
increase in prices for energy and capacity as supplies tighten signals the need for new generation.
ComEd
71
05-0159
Proposed Order
further argues that the standardized interconnection processes and terms in the PJM
transmission tariff also facilitate entry. ComEd notes that since 1999, in northern Illinois alone
over 8,000 MW of new generation, nearly all owned by independent generators, has been
interconnected to ComEds system.
The AG states that the easier it is for new suppliers to enter a market, the more difficult it
is for the existing supplier or suppliers to maintain a price above a competitive level and earn
economic rents through the exercise of market power. The AG notes that there are two primary means
by which new entrants can enter a market. They can either build new generation capacity within the
region or use the transmission system to import electricity from outside the area (either from
their own generating facilities or by purchasing power from another source). The AG asserts that
building new generation capacity and expanding transmission capacity to increase import
capabilities require long lead times to, for example, obtain site permissions, construct
facilities, and secure fuel supplies and transmission access. According to the AG, new entrants
face significant market risk and uncertainty.
The Commission concludes that there does not appear to be significant limitations on entry of
new generators in the PJM market, including northern Illinois. ComEd presented evidence that in
the short term, this issue is essentially irrelevant, given excess capacity. Likewise, the record
shows that in the long term, generator entry is largely unimpeded. The Commission notes that this
capacity for entry is clear from recent experience in particular, the entry of more than 8,000 MW
of new generation.
|
I. |
|
Relationship to Small Commercial and Residential Customers |
As discussed above, ComEd noted that to date that many non-residential customers have directly
benefited from competitive retail service. ComEd also noted, however, that all customers,
including residential customers, have received great benefits from the transition to competition,
including a 20 percent rate reduction for residential customers and nearly a decade of frozen
bundled rates. This is true regardless of the fact that residential customers have not yet
received direct offers from competitive providers, who, ComEd explained, have not seen a profit in
aggregating small accounts at the low prevailing prices. According to ComEd, this is a reason to
approve, not reject, competitive procurement.
ComEd demonstrated to this end that under the Illinois Auction Proposal, ComEd would in effect
aggregate the demands of small customers and offer them to wholesale suppliers through a
transparent auction process. ComEd observed that acquiring new supply through any means whatever
is unlikely to leave the resulting rates at their current artificial reduced and frozen level.
ComEd showed, moreover, that accessing the competitive market through the proposed auction format
is intended to result in ComEds incurring the lowest cost available to serve its customers needs,
and
72
05-0159
Proposed Order
in doing so it will bring the benefits of wholesale competitive markets to small customers.
ComEd also explained that aligning its rates with actual wholesale market prices will also make
small customers more attractive to competitive suppliers, giving these customers direct access to
retail competition. In addition, ComEd noted that the auction format is a straightforward, open
and transparent mechanism for establishing the market value required under Article XVI of the Act.
CCSAO argues that residential and small commercial customers have clearly not benefited from
having competitive choices in the retail electric market. According to Cook County, in terms of
what the General Assembly found when they adopted the choice law, one needs to look no further than
their words:
(d) A competitive wholesale and retail market must benefit all Illinois citizens.
The Illinois Commerce Commission should act to promote the development of an
effectively competitive electricity market that operates efficiently and is
equitable to all consumers. Consumer protections must be in place to ensure that all
customers continue to receive safe, reliable, affordable, and environmentally safe
electric service.
(e) All consumers must benefit in an equitable and timely fashion from the lower
costs for electricity that result from retail and wholesale competition and receive
sufficient information to make informed choices among suppliers and services. The
use of renewable resources and energy efficiency resources should be encouraged in
competitive markets. 220 ILCS 5/16-101A(d), (e)
CCSAO asserts that retail residential competition has failed so far. Cook County points to
the testimony of Mr. Frank Clark, executive vice president and chief of staff of Exelon and
president of ComEd who was asked if he was aware of any competitive supplier actually providing
service to residential or small commercial customers he indicated that there are none.
CCSAO asserts that while one might debate what a timely fashion might be as the transition
is almost over, we are beyond equitable and timely for residential retail competition. Clearly,
how to end up with retail competition for the residential customer is a challenging issue.
The AG states that ComEds proposed tariff uses an auction to facilitate . . . market-based
pricing for full requirements electric supply . . . [and] determines retail charges for full
requirements electric supply based upon the results of the auctions using formulae provided in the
Translation to Retail Charges portion of the tariff. Since wholesale market-based prices are used
to determine retail charges, wholesale market conditions directly impact retail rates. If an
auction were to be held before wholesale
73
05-0159
Proposed Order
markets are fully functioning and competitive, the auction would likely produce artificially
high wholesale prices for electricity which, in turn, would artificially increase retail rates.
The AG argues that small commercial and residential customers would be forced to pay these
increased rates because ComEd is the only electricity supplier available to these captive customers
and because demand for electricity is very inelastic, especially in the short run. The AG argues
that the reason for inelasticity in the demand for electricity is that there are few substitutes
that customers can switch to quickly. Customers can replace air conditioners, appliances, lights,
and other electrical devices with more efficient replacements but that takes time.
The Commission acknowledges that residential customers and small commercial customers have not
received the benefits of alternative electric supply to the extent that larger industrial customers
have. ARES have not deigned to serve residential and small commercial customers for whatever
reason. However, the amendments to the Act did afford customers a reduction in their rates and so
restructuring has been somewhat beneficial to residential and small commercial customers. The
movement to procurement by an auction process has the potential to place residential and small
commercial customers in a better position vis-à-vis larger customers.
|
J. |
|
Market Rules and Monitoring |
ComEd explains that increasing prices through the exercise of market power inherently involves
withholding supply, and that the profitability of the strategy, if any, arises from receiving such
high prices on the generation that is not withheld that they more than make up for not being paid
for the generation that is withheld. ComEd states, that several circumstances ensure that northern
Illinois generators cannot withhold their supply from the PJM market.
ComEd notes that the PJM market rules require that every generator that qualifies as a
capacity resource which includes nearly all generation in northern Illinois bid into the PJM
day-ahead market every day unless the generation is on an authorized scheduled outage or a
legitimate forced outage. ComEd also notes that the PJM Market Monitor may investigate whether a
forced outage was legitimate. Thus, according to ComEd, physically withholding generation violates
PJM market rules and is closely watched by the Market Monitor.
ComEd further notes that the must-bid rule is extremely important in the functioning of the
PJM market, in particular because mandatory bidding in the day-ahead market also disciplines
potential market power in the forward market. ComEd
74
05-0159
Proposed Order
states that a generator cannot demand an exorbitant price for a long-term bilateral contract,
because the customer always has the opportunity of passing up the offer and instead buying from the
generator in the spot market.
ComEd notes that if the circumstances that CUB-CCSAO and the AG hypothesize were to occur
that is, if transmission constraints were to temporarily isolate northern Illinois from the rest of
PJM and leave it with fewer than three pivotal suppliers then PJMs market mitigation rules would
be triggered automatically. ComEd explains that under such circumstances, the generators in the
constrained area would not be allowed to bid their generation at market rates but would be required
to reduce their bids to their marginal cost plus 10%. ComEd points out that the FERC has agreed
that PJMs current offer capping rules work effectively to mitigate market power in a manner that
is fair to most generating units.
CUB-CCSAO suggests that a generator could employ nimble strategies to take advantage of
temporary binding constraints at peak hours.
CUB-CCSAO asserts that a price of marginal cost plus 10% could still allow exercise of market
power because bids would exceed barebones short-run variable costs. CUB-CCSAO also argues that the
bid mitigation rule would not apply when transmission constraints were binding, but there is an
exception in place for those constraints. CUB-CCSAO claims that PJMs and MISOs mitigation rules
are insufficient to address potential use of market power and likely price increases. CUB-CCSAO
also asserts that the PJM 10% adder should be reduced so that values are closer to 100% of marginal
costs.
CUB-CCSAO further asserts that the MMUs mitigation authority is threatened by recent FERC
questioning of PJMs use of a no three pivotal suppliers test when deciding whether to implement
local market power mitigation when transmission constraints bind.
The AG asserts that there are insufficient safeguards in place to prevent the exercise of
market power and inadequate market monitoring mechanisms in place to warrant reliance on the
wholesale market to determine retail prices.
The AG claims that PJMs bid mitigation does not adequately protect customers because the
capped units receive the higher of the market price or their offer price cap. The AG also claimed
that mitigation cannot be protecting customers adequately because its use has been declining.
75
05-0159
Proposed Order
The Commission concludes that there is no evidence of any credible risk that supply will be
withheld, either physically or economically, from the PJM market. The record shows that PJMs
mandatory day-ahead bidding rules, along with monitoring and market forces (some of which are
specific to northern Illinois), effectively prevent such withholding.
Moreover, there is no evidence that the existence of withholding strategies, even were they to
be possible and were they to occur, is a reason to disapprove the auction; indeed, a well-designed
auction may be less susceptible to manipulation than other procurement mechanisms.
The Commission finds that PJMs bid mitigation rules effectively and fairly limit the possible
and profitable exercise of market power. The evidence, in particular, shows that CUB-CCSAOs and
the AGs concerns about these rules are without merit and that these rules will be applicable to
bidders. The record also shows that the exceptions to the transmission constraints are not an
issue. Nor is there any question that the bid mitigation rules help protect customers and will
restrain bid price increases.
|
2. |
|
PJM Market Monitoring Unit |
ComEd explains that PJM has a large, professional, and active Market Monitoring Unit (MMU)
that continually monitors the operation of the market for potential exercises of market power or
other attempts at manipulation or gaming. ComEd states that the MMU has a staff of more than 16
full-time professional employees, continuously monitors the functioning of the market, and makes
periodic reports on its operations. ComEd also notes that the MMU has tools to prevent physical or
economic withholding of generation to drive up prices. The MMU detects physical withholding by
reviewing forced outages or deratings and detects economic withholding by reviewing bids against
cost information. ComEd also notes that if the MMU identifies a problem it generally discusses the
issue informally with the market participants involved, which is itself effective in ending
behavior the MMU questions. If this does not yield results, ComEd further notes, the MMU issues a
Demand Letter requesting the market participant to desist and provides copies to FERC and relevant
state regulator(s). ComEd states that the FERC also has authority to monitor the PJM markets and
has established protocols to work with the MMU to ensure that the FERC can exercise its statutory
authority to ensure that rates are just and reasonable.
Additionally, ComEd notes that PJMs market design also helps prevent gaming behaviors and
that reliance on open markets is a means of reducing the risks of such behaviors. ComEd states
that open, bid-based centrally-dispatched market is inherently harder to game than many, if not
all, other market structures, and that many of the colorfully-named behaviors that worked, for
example, in California during its crisis, simply would not work in the PJM markets. ComEd also
notes that market manipulation
76
05-0159
Proposed Order
based on generation withholding, misreporting of data, phony sales, and like stratagems are not
permitted by PJM tariffs and market rules and, in many cases, are violations of federal and state
law.
The AG agrees that PJM has an MMU that periodically examines the PJM area, including the ComEd
subregion. The AG asserts that the MMUs analysis is not sufficiently detailed to determine the
extent to which relevant wholesale markets are competitive. The AG argues that conditions are such
that is it possible that market power could be or is being exercised. The AG states that an
independent analysis would help shed some light on this important issue.
The AG also states that the Commission should specify wholesale market conditions that must be
met before that market is used to procure electricity, manage risk, and set rates for Illinois
retail customers. Once those criteria are established, the ICC should conduct a comprehensive and
rigorous analysis of the Illinois regional wholesale market, to determine the likely outcome of
using that market to determine retail prices. The study should assess the potential for strategic
bidding, collusion or related anti-competitive activities to ensure that market participants
cant outwit the designers in Illinois. According to the AG these initial studies could serve as a
foundation for on-going analysis of the Illinois regional wholesale market.
CUB-CCSAO asserts that PJMs and MISOs market monitoring are insufficient to address
potential use of market power and likely price increases. They also assert that the PJM MMU could
not fully prevent the exercise of market power during periods of transmission constraints. In
addition, they assert that ComEd is relying on the PJM MMU as a first choice, not a last resort.
The Commission concludes that the record tends to show the effectiveness of PJMs MMU as the
last line of defense against market manipulation. Among other things, the MMU continuously
monitors the market, has multiple methods for preventing efforts to drive prices up artificially
through withholding, and has processes for addressing any issues that do arise. In addition, the
record demonstrates that the FERC performs additional monitoring and that the MMU and the FERC work
together in these regards. The Commission is not persuaded by the AGs assertion that the MMU is
not effective, as such assertion does not square with the evidence. Accordingly, the Commission
concludes that PJMs MMU will be a safeguard for the Illinois Auction Proposal.
77
05-0159
Proposed Order
|
3. |
|
Proposed Illinois Market Monitor |
CUB-CCSAO suggest that a separate Illinois Market Monitoring Unit (IMMU) be established that
would review the effectiveness and competitiveness of the PJM market structure and would have
access to confidential market data to monitor detect and potential market power and take action to
prevent or eliminate abuse. CUB-CCSAO asserts that potential remedies would include petitioning
RTOs, the FERC, or the U.S. Department of Justice to take action. They also assert this IMMU could
have authority beyond RTO-administered markets into broader investigations of energy industries.
ComEd states that in effect, CUB-CCSAO is proposing an Illinois entity to do a job the PJM MMU
was already tasked to do. ComEd notes multiple problems with this proposal. First, there is no
source of authority and CUB-CCSAO suggested none for an Illinois entity to monitor transactions
in wholesale power markets in interstate commerce, transactions that are by federal statute subject
to the exclusive jurisdiction of the FERC. In addition, ComEd notes that CUB-CCSAOs proposal adds
nothing to the scope of the markets being monitored, since under the Illinois Auction Proposal
ComEd and other restructured utilities will be purchasing resources on the monitored wholesale
market anyway. ComEd further notes that for reasons noted above, there is no need for the
proposal, as its purported function already is being performed adequately by the PJM MMU and the
FERC. In addition, ComEd notes, if there are criminal violations, the U.S. Department of Justice,
the various United States Attorneys offices, and state prosecutorial authorities have authority to
enforce the law.
The Commission does not see the need for another monitor at this time. If in the future, it
appears that the PJM MMU or FERC is not providing sufficient oversight the Commission may revisit
this issue. Additionally, the Commission will continue to exercise its authority as may be
appropriate to monitor the ongoing procurement processes.
|
K. |
|
Other Competitive Market Issues |
ComEd states that the pending merger is irrelevant to this docket. ComEd notes that no party
to that proceeding presented evidence that the merger would have competitive implications in
Illinois, as the focus of the proceeding was on combining generation fleets in New Jersey and
Pennsylvania. ComEd also notes that the PJM MMU concluded that Exelons and PSEGs proposed
mitigation (divestiture of 6,600 MW of generation) is sufficient to cure any competitive concerns,
and that the FERC had acted to approve the merger without hearing and without finding any
unmitigated market power issues. ComEd further states that operationally there is no link between
the proposed merger and any of bidding on generation in northern Illinois, planning or operations
of the transmission system, or marginal costs of generation. ComEd Brief at
The AG asserts that the pending Exelon/PSEG merger would likely have a material impact on the
development of wholesale markets across the country and that the FERC did not comprehensively
address these competitive impacts. The AG cites the MMUs 2004 State of the Market Report, which
noted that the merger raise[d]
78
05-0159
Proposed Order
concerns about potential adverse competitive effects, absent mitigation. In addition, the AG
maintains that neither the FERC nor the MMU had examined possible collusion with respect to the
merger.
The Commission concludes that there is no evidence that the pending Exelon-PSEG merger will
have any deleterious impact on the Illinois Auction Proposal and substantial evidence that it will
have none. The evidence demonstrated that the merger, as proposed, will not have competitive
implications for Illinois. The Commission also notes that the FERC already evaluated and rejected
use of a behavioral analysis, and the DOJ Antitrust Division is already considering possible
impacts of the merger on competition.
V. AUCTION DESIGN ISSUES
|
A. |
|
General Effectiveness and Suitability |
ComEd notes that the Commission, recognizing the need for a coordinated approach to post-2006
supply issues, established the Post 2006 Initiative to provide a framework for considering
available alternatives. ComEd actively participated in that effort, along with Staff and a variety
of stakeholders. ComEd states that, after considering a wide variety of procurement alternatives,
and assessing the advantages and disadvantages of each, the Post 2006 Initiative identified
eighteen characteristics of an ideal procurement process. The Final Staff Report on the Post 2006
Initiative recommended that a vertical tranche auction be utilized by large utilities without
significant generation assets. ComEd points out that its proposed tariffs follow the guidance and
direction provided in the Final Staff Report on the Post 2006 Initiative using a vertical tranche
auction, and that no other party has proposed a method that better meets the identified criteria.
Staff concludes that the basic SDCA auction concept, as proposed by ComEd is an appropriate
competitive procurement method for securing power supply commitments for serving ComEds retail
customers. Staff recommends that the Commission approve the basic SDCA approach.
The AG asserts the full requirements, vertical tranche, declining clock auction proposed by
ComEd is not well suited for supplying electricity to Amerens customers. The AG argues that the
auction would result in a uniform price that all suppliers receive, irrespective of their costs or
their ability to sell at a lower price.
The AG notes that electricity is generated by different methods, including the use of nuclear
fuel, various types of coal, natural gas, oil and renewable energies such as
79
05-0159
Proposed Order
wind and each of these processes has distinct costs. According to the AG, however, under the
auction proposed by ComEd, low cost producers of electricity which use nuclear energy or coal can
obtain prices based on the higher market prices for coal or natural gas.
The AG further argues that because ComEds proposal would allow PJM wholesale prices to
influence the clearing price, Illinois consumers rates could increase irrespective of suppliers
actual costs to produce power because PJMs prices would push the auction prices upward.
Additionally, the AG asserts that the auction format proposed by ComEd produces undue risks to
consumers by holding a single, annual auction for multi-year supply. A single auction for an 8,000
MW obligation is substantial, and obtaining it all at one time puts consumers at risk for all of
their supply. The AG argues that ComEds decision to terminate all of its existing contracts so
that all supply would be open at the same time exposes consumers to the risk that the time of the
auction might be inauspicious, and drive up prices due to short term concerns. Securing all supply
in a single auction would prevent the company from minimizing the effect of adverse circumstances
by spreading its purchases over a greater time frame.
The AG argues that the general structure of ComEds proposed auction will result in unjust and
unnecessary price increases, and rob Illinois consumers of the value of local, low cost generation,
which ComEd consumers have paid for over the years through rates that included return on investment
and depreciation expense. The annual auction structure, in particular the first auction, will
expose consumers to undue risk by exposing all of ComEd load to a single procurement. The
Commission should reject ComEds proposal as ill-suited to Illinois.
DES states that the Commission should direct ComEd to make two fundamental changes to its
competitive procurement proposal: First, DES asserts that ComEds proposal improperly relies upon
contracts longer than one year, and because of their long terms, such contracts are saddled with an
elevated risk premium. DES argues that consumers may pay higher default service prices than they
would under a model with shorter-term contracts and these long-term contracts also remove the
impact of changes in market price driven by supply and demand. DES asserts that such price
distortions can contribute to a lack of demand side reductions, and increased environmental harm
due to increased energy consumption. DES states that ComEds proposal segments the availability of
auction products to customers by demand level in a way that could hinder the further development of
competition. DES believes that if customers are to fully realize the benefits of a competitive
market, multiple products must be offered by multiple suppliers to a full range of customers.
80
05-0159
Proposed Order
CCSAO argues that ComEd focuses on the implementation details of an auction while glossing
over the fundamental question of whether other options would better serve the public interest.
CCSAO also urges the Commission reject the Companys proposal; open a new docket to consider the
full range of procurement options; and affirm that, regardless of which procurement method is
employed, retail rates remain subject to traditional regulatory standards of justness and
reasonableness, which entail a prudence review of the companys decisions.
CCSAO asserts that the Commission should recognize that the ComEd retains responsibility for
making and managing the decisions and actions necessary to serve default service customers and
should clarify that the Commission will ensure, as part of its oversight responsibility, that the
ComEd has done so in a manner that best serves default service customers.
CCSAO notes that ComEd has considered other options and indicated that through November of
2003 their goal had been to acquire Illinois power and in that process also gain approval for a
single source affiliate contract.
DES urges the Commission to modify ComEds position in two ways. DES argues that long term
contracts should be removed from the procurement process. Secondly, DES urges that the Commission
direct ComEd to offer multiple products by multiple suppliers to a full range of customers. DES
argues that ComEds proposal segments the availability of auction products in such a way that will
hinder further development of competition.
The Commission finds that the vertical tranche auction proposed by ComEd is an appropriate
competition procurement method for securing power supply for the needs of ComEd customers.
|
B. |
|
Full Requirements Product |
ComEd describes the principal benefit of a full requirements product, such as that proposed,
as shifting risks from customers to suppliers. ComEd explains that a utilitys load varies over
time based on a number of factors time of year, commercial operations evidenced during peak
periods, and hour-to-hour based on weather conditions and other variables. Under a full
requirements model, a supplier agrees to provide a set portion of the utilitys full requirements
throughout the term of the agreement, even though the amount of energy at some times will be
significantly
81
05-0159
Proposed Order
greater and more costly than at other times. ComEd indicates that suppliers must assemble a
portfolio that provides for adequate generation, and assume the associated risks of acquiring too
little or too much generation. In contrast, customers receive and pay only for the supply they
need when they need it, without additional financial obligation or exposure, and are therefore
insulated from risk.
Staff informs that Tranche is a French word meaning slice and defining the basic product
as a slice of the Companys full requirements essentially removes the burden of generation
portfolio decision making from the shoulders of the Company (and to some extent, the Commission)
and places it on the shoulders of suppliers, instead.
Staff notes that alternatives to procuring vertical tranches of the Companys full
requirements load would entail procuring an appropriate array of specific types of supply contracts
and/or generating assets (e.g., an appropriate assortment of contracts or assets designed to serve
base-load, intermediate-load, and peaking-load). Although some intervenors in this docket proposed
considering such active portfolio management alternatives, Staff opposes them.
Staff agrees that the full-requirements product directly contributes to fulfilling the goal of
having competitive entities take, manage and price BGS risks. The full-requirements product places
price-risk management responsibility in the hands of competitive entities that were best suited to
take, manage, and price these risks. Staff further agrees that the full-requirements product
contributes to the goal of maximizing participation. It expands the base of potential competitors,
including financial players and marketers and traders without an asset base in PJM. Those entities
are able to use specialized skills in price-risk management to assemble wholesale portfolios and
compete in the auction. Staff further agrees that a full-requirements product also contributes to
the goal of minimizing customer confusion and encouraging efficient retail markets. Staff further
agrees that the full-requirements product also contributes to the goal of encouraging efficient
retail markets.
Thus, Staff recommends that the Commission approve the basic full-requirements product concept
in this docket. In making this recommendation with respect to the basic full-requirements product
concept, Staff is not tacitly endorsing other aspects of the proposed auction process or other
aspects of the Companys proposal in this case.
The AG asserts that a full requirements contract puts the risk of volume fluctuation
exclusively on the supplier, and that each supplier therefore will build the risk of this
uncertainty into their bids by including a risk premium. The AG argues that consumers are
therefore left vulnerable to paying excessively high prices to cover risks
82
05-0159
Proposed Order
that could be more economically managed, a risk which is increased by what the AG called an
abbreviated post auction review.
The Commission concludes that a full requirements product is appropriate. Successfully
managing an energy portfolio requires that there be a sufficient amount of energy to serve
customers needs, while safeguarding against paying for energy that is not needed. In order to
adequately provide for energy supply that varies widely by month, by time of day, and in response
to particular events, a utility without substantial generation assets would be left vulnerable to
certain risks. ComEds proposal for a full requirements auction product ensures that customers in
ComEds service territory have adequate energy supply, and that they pay only for the energy that
they use. In shifting the risk from customers to suppliers, customers are guaranteed adequate
electric supply while at the same time gaining rate stability.
|
C. |
|
Multiple Round Descending Clock Format |
|
1. |
|
General Effectiveness and Suitability |
ComEd articulates that use of a multiple round, descending clock format for the auction is a
transparent process that enables bidders to compare the prices of the various products in the
auction and to continuously evaluate their bids with the benefit of information provided during the
progress of the auction, thereby extracting the market price. ComEd notes that use of this auction
format is supported by successful experience in New Jersey, as well as by academic and professional
literature supported by extensive research concerning auction design.
MW Gen supports the auction design as currently proposed by ComEd. The particular auction
design proposed by ComEd is an open-bid, simultaneous, descending-clock mechanism that allows ComEd
to take advantage of competition in procuring goods and services in an efficient manner and has
been previously used and refined in New Jersey to sell Basic Generation Service.
MW Gen argues that competitive procurements, such as the mechanism proposed in this Docket,
are more likely to foster efficient resource allocations and investment when compared to a
regulatory process, such as a traditional regulatory review aimed at developing or obtaining
least-cost resources to meet forecasted needs. MW Gen also argues that competitive procurement
mechanisms such as the instant auction protect against affiliate favoritism and other forms of
discriminatory behavior. Open competitive procurements in Illinois will help sustain effective
wholesale power markets in and around Illinois, by offering suppliers an attractive, recurring
contracting
83
05-0159
Proposed Order
opportunity under well-defined conditions. This in turn creates a virtuous circle that
assures customers will benefit from competitive market pricing and risk allocations in the future. |
MW Gen asserts that transparency is crucial to ensuring competitiveness and encouraging
participation by potential suppliers, particularly in a situation like that in Illinois where
utility affiliates own substantial generating assets from which they could provide power to their
affiliated utilities. Transparency means that the eligibility rules, the products being procured,
and the criteria for evaluating offers are well-defined and well-understood by all relevant
parties. Frequently, this means that the solicited services will be standardized, and that offers
must conform to certain specified terms and conditions. This allows objective selection of
suppliers, usually on the basis of price alone.
MW Gen further asserts that suppliers will be encouraged to participate in a process that is
not only transparent, but that is also commercially fair and reasonable in its terms, and is
non-discriminatory (in that no special eligibility clause or evaluation approaches can be applied
to favor a specific set of participants). According to MW Gen, it should not be possible to
directly or indirectly restrict participation so that only affiliates, or perhaps local producers,
would effectively be eligible.
MW Gen continues, stating that the proposed auction makes available the benefits of market
competition while also providing to retail customers reasonably stable rates. The proposed auction
achieves these twin objectives by procuring power in a competitive wholesale market over various
time horizons, averaging the prices of the winning bids together into the rates faced by retail
customers. MW Gen believes that allowing suppliers to compete for these staggered products
simultaneously also increases the efficiency of the process, since suppliers are able to shift bids
towards whichever products seem to be over-valued, thereby driving all products to prices that are
appropriately adjusted for risk and term.
MW Gen asserts that a reasonable auction design should allow the regulatory body to evaluate
procurement products from time to time to see if they need to be adjusted to better serve other
policy objectives, such as facilitating retail-access competition or creating long-run supply
adequacy incentives. (In particular, the auction design could be adjusted over time, if needed, to
increase rate stability.) Continued regulatory review can also encourage broad supplier
participation by assuring suppliers that the procurement process will remain competitive and open.
Regulatory review does this, in part, by protecting the procurement process from affiliate
favoritism and ensuring a non-discriminatory process.
The Commission concludes that use of a multiple round, descending clock format is appropriate
for use in ComEds service territory. Specific details of ComEds proposal are discussed below.
84
05-0159
Proposed Order
ComEd states that load caps act as a competitive safeguard, limiting the influence that any
one bidder can have on the results of the auction while at the same time limiting the utilitys
exposure to any one particular supplier, thereby shielding the utility and its customers from risk.
ComEd initially proposed that the load cap be set at a 50% level. However, ComEd notes that after
considering various suggestions from Staff and Intervenors, ComEd modified the load cap proposal in
its rebuttal testimony, decreasing the cap level from 50% to 35%.
Staff asserts that the weight of the evidence supports the Companys 35% load cap proposal.
Staff notes that it is within the range recommended by Staff and MidWest Gen and is supported by
all parties except IIEC.
MW Gen supports the currently proposed load cap of 35% as appropriate for the procurement
auction. MW Gen asserts that a load cap limits the number of tranches that any single auction
participant can obtain. MW Gen further states that a load cap has four related purposes: (1) to
increase supplier diversity; (2) to reduce the likelihood that a given share of load will be
subject to default; (3) to reduce the impact resulting from any single suppliers default; and (4)
to increase the supplies available on the wholesale market underlying the auction by limiting the
extent of direct auction participation by owners of physical generation assets, thereby promoting
more robust auction bidding by marketer/traders and other participants that do not own significant
physical generation assets.
MW Gen notes that IIECs opposition is based on the belief that a load cap might increase
costs to consumers by limiting the amount of load that low cost suppliers could serve. MW Gen
further notes that although that is certainly a legitimate concern, it is also true that the
objectives of a load cap identified above operate to decrease cost and risk for the utility and its
customers. Moreover, no evidence supports the conclusion that eliminating a load cap will, or is
even likely to, result in lower costs.
MW Gen argues that to the extent that a 35% load cap induces certain generation owners to
commit fewer generation resources directly into the auction, more generation resources potentially
will be available for sale in the underlying wholesale energy markets that backstop the auction.
If, in this fashion, a lower load cap facilitates a more liquid underlying wholesale market (e.g.,
for various forward and spot purchases), then the lower load cap potentially could encourage more
breadth of participation and bidding by pure marketer/traders and other potential auction
85
05-0159
Proposed Order
participants who do not have significant generation resources to cover their own load
interest. Thus, according to MW Gen, a 35% load cap will result in more auction participants with
increased initial interest in tranches, which is pro-competitive and likely to facilitate lower
auction prices.
MW Gen also argues that a 35% cap also prevents exaggerated statements by potential suppliers
of initial interest which might otherwise result in mis-sizing of the auction. MW Gen believes
that supplier participation in a ComEd auction will be strong enough that a load cap of 35% will
not overly constrain participation. MW Gen also notes that the proposed 35% load cap comports with
the New Jersey BGS auction, which limits participants to no more than 33% of available fixed-price
tranches in any single auction.
IIEC opposes imposition of this artificial barrier to open competition and supply at the
lowest prices. IIEC argues that the cap would prevent any single supplier from winning contracts
to supply more than 50% of the auctioned load (expressed in number of tranches) even if its bid
would result in substantially lower prices to ComEd and its retail bundled service customers. IIEC
notes that one consequence of restricting auction competition through the imposition of an auction
load cap would be that efficient suppliers, able and willing to provide large quantities of
electricity at prices lower than their competitors, would be artificially constrained in the amount
of low-cost power and energy they would be allowed to supply. IIEC argues that a predictable
consequence of such limitations would be a higher than necessary auction clearing price and thus a
higher price to consumers with load caps even if such suppliers sold their excess supplies to
other bidders, retail customers would not be supplied at the lower cost otherwise available. IIEC
further argues that those efficient, lower priced supplies could only be provided through a winning
middleman-bidder who would impose its own markup on the low-price supply.
IIEC supports participation by as many suppliers as can reliably and economically provide
supply. However, IIEC disagrees that a load cap is the way to promote robust competition in the
auction. The fact an auction may have more bidders does not mean there will be more low-cost or
low price suppliers competing in the auction. Even if a load cap encouraged a larger number of
suppliers to participate, elimination of low-price or low-cost bids via the load cap, nonetheless,
will reduce the competitiveness of the auction, and in turn increase the auction clearing price.
IIEC argues that marketers and traders with superior risk management capabilities, like generation
owners, may elect to skip Illinois auction if the number of tranches they are permitted to bid on
and win is too low to be profitable or efficient. IIEC believes that it should be beyond dispute
that the level of participation by efficient, low-cost or low-price suppliers should not be
curtailed for the sake of an appearance of competition.
IIEC notes that ComEds revised auction rules would impose a lower 35% load cap. Even that
IIEC feels would constrain the unfettered operation of market forces.
86
05-0159
Proposed Order
IIEC states that by establishing a load cap, ComEds proposal would limit the amount of supply
that a very efficient bidder could offer into the auction and compete with the supply of others.
IIEC further states that limiting this efficient bidders objective influence on the market forces
of the auction would be inappropriate and result in higher market prices. In other words, limiting
the number of competing supply tranches reduces the competitiveness of the auction and will likely
raise and certainly not lower, the prices resulting from the auction. |
IIEC argues that ComEd, Staff, and Midwest Generation the principal advocates for load caps
have not shown that any load cap is more beneficial than harmful to the results of the auction.
A 35% load cap would be more harmful to open competition (and potentially auction clearing prices)
than ComEds 50% load cap proposal. The Commission should reject the artificial barrier to full
competition represented by the proposed load cap.
The Commission concludes that ComEds proposed load cap, as modified in its rebuttal testimony
to be set at 35%, is appropriate. Load caps serve as a competitive safeguard, limiting the
influence that any one bidder can have on the results of the auction. At the same time, load caps
limit the utilitys exposure to any one particular supplier, thereby shielding the utility and its
customers from risk. Staff and the vast majority of stakeholders agree, with IIEC the lone
opponent of the proposed load cap. The Commission is not persuaded by the IIECs suggestions that
a load cap could, in certain hypothetical situations, increase auction clearing prices, and finds
that the benefits provided by a load cap outweigh any potential disadvantages.
ComEd states that the starting prices for products in the auction will be established by the
Auction Manager in consultation with the ICC Staff and ComEd. ComEd further states that the prices
will fall within the maximum and minimum starting prices provided to qualified bidders in
connection with submission of their Part 2 applications to participate in the auction. ComEd notes
that the Part 2 applications must include indicative offers from prospective bidders indicating the
number of tranches they would be willing to serve at the maximum and minimum prices. This
information is then taken into account in setting the starting prices.
Staff observes that no party objected to the above-specified description, purpose, and
mechanics. Staff recommends that the Commission approve the Companys proposal with respect to the
auctions starting prices.
87
05-0159
Proposed Order
The AG notes that the proposed auction structure starts at a given price, and the price is
reduced until all tranches are supplied and there are no suppliers left who are willing to provide
service at a lower price and the starting price effectively sets the maximum price consumers can be
asked to pay for supply. This is a key component of the auction process. However, the AG notes
that no prediction of starting prices appears in the record and the auction manual and rules fail
to provide any information about how the opening prices are set.
The AG argues that the failure of ComEd to include an estimate of starting bids or a method
for determining the maximum and minimum opening bids emphasizes how its proposal leaves consumers
vulnerable to the unknown rate increases. The Commission and the public do not even know how the
range of prices will be determined. The Commission cannot approve such an open-ended process
without violating the PUAs requirement that it only allow rates that are just and reasonable.
(See 220 ILCS 5/9-101) The essentially unknown range of possible starting prices (and final
prices) renders Rider CPP unlawful just as the Rider CS proposal, which would have allowed ComEd to
negotiate certain rates without stated standards or review, was found unlawful by the court in
Citizens Utility Board v. Illinois Commerce Commission, 275 Ill. App. 3d 329, 339 (1st Dist. 1995).
The Commission finds that ComEds proposal adopts the appropriate methodology for establishing
the starting prices. The Attorney Generals position that possible starting bids should be
revealed at this juncture is without merit, as the determination of starting bids must consider
recent market data, which can only be assessed near the time of the auction. The Commission
Staffs involvement in developing the starting price in conjunction with the Auction Manager and
ComEd adequately safeguards consumer interests.
ComEd proposes that the size of the reductions in price from round to round in the auction be
determined by a formula taking into account the amount of excess supply for the particular
product. Under ComEds proposal, products that attract more supplier interest and therefore have
more excess supply would experience larger price reductions. Those that have garnered less
interest would have smaller price reductions. ComEd notes that depriving bidders of any
information about the decrement formula would have certain drawbacks. However, based on Staff
concerns, ComEd devised an alternative to provide bidders with price decrement formulas, but to
make sure that these formulas do not allow bidders to make good inferences about the excess supply
on a product toward the end of the auction. ComEd asserts that the actual bid
88
05-0159
Proposed Order
decrement formulas would be developed as soon as possible by the Auction Manager, in
conjunction with ICC Staff and the Auction Advisor.
By way of background, Staff notes that the auction proceeds in biddings rounds, in which
suppliers bid quantities in response to the prevailing prices announced by the Auction Manager.
Staff continues, in the initial round, the price is set relatively high. Between rounds, the price
for each product either ticks down or remains the same. The price ticks down when there is excess
supply for that product (i.e., when the total number bids for tranches exceeds the target number of
tranches sought by the Company for that product). Otherwise (when there is no excess supply for a
product), the price remains the same. When there is no longer any excess supply for any of the
products, the auction ends. Among the auction rule details is the precise manner in which prices
would change between rounds.
Staff concludes that price decrements can and should reveal something (but not everything)
about the excess supply prevailing at the start of each auction round. Thus, Staff respectfully
recommends that the Commission accept this basic principle and reject BOMAs suggestion that
bidders should remain totally in the dark about excess supply throughout each auction.
Staff also concludes that ComEd has provided a good structure for setting bid decrements,
but that it is expected that decrement formulas would be finalized closer to the auction. Thus,
Staff recommends that the Commission direct the Companys Auction Manager to consult with Staff in
finalizing those formulas, which would be revealed to bidders prior to the auction in an Auction
Manual.
BOMA argues that the information ComEd proposes to divulge does not help the consumers one
iota. Divulging the number of bids after each round signals the amount of remaining interest in
the auction. BOMA argues that ComEds proposed auction gives bidders the opportunity to learn
about the bidding behavior of other bidders and thereby allows those bidders to adapt their bidding
strategies accordingly. BOMA asserts that bidders would use this information to keep the market
price of electricity well above their own marginal cost. According to BOMA, this information only
encourages bidders to implicitly collude on a high price.
The Commission concludes that the proposal by ComEd and Staff to provide price decrement
formulas in the Auction Manual in a way that precludes bidders from making inferences about excess
supply toward the end of the auction is prudent and reasonable. ComEd and Staff are attempting to
balance two conflicting consequences of providing excess supply feedback: providing too much
feedback may empower a
89
05-0159
Proposed Order
bidder to stop the auction prematurely at an elevated price, but providing too little feedback
may lead to more timid bidding. The Auction Manager should consult with Staff in finalizing these
formulas, which would be revealed to bidders prior to the auction in an Auction Manual.
|
5. |
|
Auction Volume Reductions |
ComEd states that the auction design provides for volume reductions by the Auction Manager in
the event that interest in the auction by suppliers is not as high as expected. If interest is not
sufficient, the auction volume is reduced to ensure competitive prices at the auction, and the
remainder of the volume is procured on PJM-administered markets. ComEd states that provision is
made for volume reductions as a safety net to ensure that prices resulting from the auction are
competitive.
Staff notes that an additional competitive safeguard advanced by the Company is a provision
of the Competitive Procurement Process Auction Manual filed in this proceeding that the Auction
Manager can cut back the volume purchased through the auction if this is necessary to ensure a
competitive bidding environment.
Staff states that in principle, an auction volume adjustment can completely offset the effect
on price due to the exercise of market power by a bidder. A bidder with market power could attempt
to stop the clock in the auction by reducing the number of tranches bid such that supply equals
or falls below demand. The anticipated benefit from this strategy is to preserve a high margin on
the tranches still bid for. However, a volume adjustment can, by reducing the number of tranches
available in the auction, decrease or even eliminate the benefit to a bidder from withholding
supply.
Thus, Staff recommends that the Commission accept ComEds position with respect to limitations
in the use of volume cutbacks. Staff states that the Commission (rather than the Auction Manager
or Staff) would retain a remedy should it find reason, based on the Auction Managers Report and/or
the Staff Report, to question the competitive integrity of the auction process. Staff further
states that the Commission can refuse to certify the results of any auction for any reason,
including but not limited to evidence of collusion or improper coordination among bidders or a
breakdown in competition.
Staff agrees that strict confidentiality should be maintained over the detailed volume
reduction guidelines that are yet to be developed. Staff believes that it is important that
bidders not be made privy to these detailed guidelines. Staff agrees that the Auction Manager and
the Staff (with the assistance of any expert auction advisors that Staff may engage) should and
will work together to develop those detailed
90
05-0159
Proposed Order
guidelines in compliance with whatever order the Commission should hand down in this docket.
Dynegy states that there is little disagreement that the Auction Manager must have the ability
to reduce the volumes for any given product either before the auction starts (if there has been
insufficient interest expressed by the potential Suppliers to make the auction workably
competitive) or after the first round of the auction (if the bids in the first round demonstrate
insufficient interest by the potential Suppliers to make the auction workably competitive), with
the remainder of the volume in such a case being procured under one of ComEds contingency plans.
Dynegy argues that to ensure a competitive auction, a volume adjustment should be one of the tools
in the Auction Managers arsenal. However, given the design of the auctions, once a base line has
been established and filled during the initial round of bidding, the rules of the auction itself
ensure that under-subscription cannot be a problem because the Auction Manager can make previous
bids binding.
Dynegy notes that there is disagreement over whether and when to permit such reductions in
subsequent rounds and whether to permit reduced tranches to be added to another product for which
there appears to be more interest. Staff believes the Auction Manager should have the ability to
make these modifications, for example, as a means to ensure that any given product does not become
undersubscribed. Dynegy asserts that if under-subscription alone were the concern, then the
auction rules prevent this from occurring after round one. Dynegy notes that as set forth in great
detail in the proposed auction rules, if supply drops below demand, the Auction Manager has various
tools to prevent the switching of tranches to other products and/or the withdrawal of tranches for
the product(s) whose supply would fall below demand.
Dynegy argues that differences in the pricing of certain products may arise for any number of
reasons such as bidders views of the relative risks inherent in the products. Dynegy further
argues that bidders need flexibility to decide when, in their views, the difference in prices
between products has reached a level when it becomes economic for them to switch between the
products. If that option is removed from them by constant adjustments to the target volumes, then
Suppliers will be less likely to bid in the first place.
Dynegy asserts that if the preference is to have parties engage in a give-and-take on such
items as the proper price spread among products, mix of products to be supplied, price and,
presumably at that point, numerous other items as well, then rather than constrain them in an
artificial setting of an auction, they should be permitted to negotiate a bilateral deal. That, of
course, is not the proposal before the Commission.
91
05-0159
Proposed Order
ComEds proposal to allow for volume reductions by the Auction Manager in the event that
interest in the auction by suppliers is not as high as expected best ensures that the auction
clearing price reflects competitive prices, with which no party disagreed. Though Staff witness
Salant initially recommended that the Auction Manager be permitted to make volume reductions to
exert pressure on suppliers, Staff ultimately concluded that the Auction Manager would not possess
sufficient information to make an informed judgment regarding supplier motivations, and that the
Commission is best suited to construct a remedy if the competitive integrity of the auction is
called into question. The Commission concurs.
ComEd notes that Staff witness Salant suggested that the volume reduction power be used to
readjust the individual auction product volumes, increasing volume for products with excess supply
and decreasing it for products with limited supply offers. ComEd states that Dr. Salants proposal
disregards the dynamic nature of the auction process in which switching among products is
anticipated and expected so that initial interest in particular products does not always reflect
the ultimate distribution of bids. According to ComEd, adjusting relative percentages of total
requirements among various products during the auction would destroy the careful balance between
price and stability that the choice of durations was intended to achieve. ComEd recommends that
this second volume reduction proposal be rejected as it is likely to be harmful to the auction
process.
Staff recommends that (1) the Commission authorize the Companys Auction Manager to utilize
the portfolio rebalancing option only after consulting with the Staff and there is consensus
between the Auction Manager and Staff that such action is appropriate, provided that (2) the
Companys Auction Manager, in consultation with the Staff and the Auction Advisor, can devise prior
to the auction a protocol deemed appropriate by the Auction Manager for carrying out such portfolio
rebalancing.
Dynegy supported ComEds proposal regarding volume reductions and portfolio reductions.
Dynegy noted that parties to the auction need to be assured that, absent some pre-defined events
occurring, the basic contours of the auction will not vary during the auction itself, and expressed
the opinion that ComEds proposal best meets that goal.
92
05-0159
Proposed Order
The record demonstrates that the volume reduction proposal to readjust the individual auction
product volumes, increasing volume for products with excess supply and decreasing it for products
with limited supply offers, should be rejected, as it is likely to be harmful to the auction
process.
|
7. |
|
Association and Confidential Information Rules |
ComEd notes that the Illinois Auction design includes detailed association and confidential
information rules comparable to those that have been used in New Jersey. According to ComEd, the
rules ensure the independence of bidders, prevents collusion among bidders, and prevents any one
bidder from gaining advantage in the auction through better information about its competitors.
Staff recognizes that there are reasonable arguments against requiring additional disclosure
of full-requirements contract information. It remains unclear to Staff how a common supplier of
full-requirements contracts, to two or more bidders, can lead to coordinated bidding. Considering
the real potential for some negative unintended consequences from its proposal, at this time, Staff
does not recommend that the Commission order the Company to modify the association and confidential
information rules.
PES is concerned about a bidders relationship to entities with which Retail Electric
Suppliers (RES) compete, and the Auction Manual, even with ComEds proposed modifications, does
not adequately address that concern. PES has concerns about a bidder sharing information with an
unaffiliated, but associated, RES. Second, PES has concerns that the exception for advisors
could be a substantial loophole. A bidder could legitimately consider an unaffiliated RES to be an
advisor in the process, and, in this advisory capacity, the unaffiliated RES could gain valuable
market intelligence, as well as share its own intelligence about the retail market with the bidder.
PES argues that having a non-RES bidder disclose information to a RES bidder can confer upon
that RES critical market information that is unavailable to other RESs. PES is not opposed to RESs
being able to bid and a RES should be free to participate as a bidder and develop its own market
information, but it should not be privy to another bidders confidential information even if the
association is disclosed to the Auction Manager. PES further argues that such information sharing,
and the attendant risk of undermining the integrity of the auction process and disadvantaging RESs
who lack access to confidential information, should not be permitted in the auction process. To
93
05-0159
Proposed Order
this end, PES proposes that a qualified bidder be required to certify that it will not
disclose any confidential information regarding the Auction Process to any company or any persons
within a division(s) or business unit(s) of the bidders company who is authorized to do business
as a Retail Electric Supplier or an Alternative Retail Electric Suppliers in Illinois.
PES proposes adding that an advisor also exclude any individual employed by companies or
divisions of companies that are authorized to do business as a Retail Electric Supplier or an
Alternative Retail Electric Suppliers in Illinois. PES proposal addresses the difficulty of
monitoring whether an individual, acting as a bidders advisor, is disclosing information to others
in his company or division. PES asserts that there is no evidence that excluding RESs and their
employees from the advisor role will prevent any qualified bidder from participating in the
auction. ComEds effort to address PE Services concerns is insufficient. Therefore, the Auction
Manual should be revised to preclude RESs and their employees from being advisors to bidders and to
require bidders to certify that they will not disclose information to RESs.
The Commission finds that the rules proposed by ComEd ensure the independence of bidders,
prevent collusion among bidders, and prevent any one bidder from gaining advantage in the auction
through better information about its competitors. The record further supports modification to the
Auction Manual concerning the term advisor, as proposed by ComEd. Such modifications provide
adequate assurance that confidential information is not inappropriately communicated by an advisor
to a bidder. The Commission does not adopt PES recommendation.
ComEd proposed to follow the New Jersey approach to tranche size, having suppliers bid to
provide a percentage of peak load approximating 100 MW. Following testimony from Staff witness
David Salant suggesting the use of a tranche size smaller than 100 MW, ComEd agreed to revise its
proposal to establish a tranche size of approximately 50 MW.
Staff notes that in the proposed auction, bidders vie to supply one or more tranches of one
or more of the sought-after products. Staff further notes that in its original filing, the Company
proposed that each tranche should be approximately 100 MW. Staff argues that the tranche size
should be significantly smaller than 100 MW at peak, in order to accommodate smaller suppliers or
even large suppliers that wish to supply odd lot sizes. Staff recommends an approximate tranche
size of 50 MW.
94
05-0159
Proposed Order
Staff notes that the Company reduced its proposed tranche size to 50 MW, in response to
Staffs concerns and Staff accepted this compromise. Staff recommends that the Commission approve
the revised proposal to define tranche size as approximately 50 MW of each customer segments peak
demand.
The record supports a tranche size of approximately 50 MW of each customer segments peak
demand. The Commission approves a tranche size of 50 MW for purposes of this proceeding.
|
9. |
|
Price Taker Proposal |
ComEd advocated for the open auction, requiring that market participants desiring to supply a
specified portion of ComEds load participate in the auction process.
In Staffs view, the price taker option is unlikely to have much of an effect on the auction,
either a positive or a negative effect. Hence, Staff is largely ambivalent to the proposal, at
this time. Furthermore, since suppliers can also sell their power to other bidders or into the PJM
organized markets, or in other bilateral markets, the price taker option is not necessary for
consumers to gain access to low-cost producers power. Thus, at this time, Staff does not
recommend that the Commission order the Company to incorporate the price taker option into the
auction.
MW Gen concluded that Staff witness Salants proposal would deter participation.
The open auction process is essential to maintain the auctions ability to encourage wide
participation to achieve low market prices for customers. The record demonstrates that the price
taker feature would jeopardize these fundamental advantages of the auction. Accordingly, the
Commission rejects Staffs proposal.
|
10. |
|
Other Format Concepts and Issues |
While this section was included as part of the brief outline, parties have placed discussion
of these issues in other parts of the order.
95
05-0159
Proposed Order
|
D. |
|
Clearing Price: Uniform vs. Pay-as-Bid |
ComEd notes that BOMA, has proposed a fundamental change in the auction design that would
render it unworkable. ComEd believes that the change, while presented as an enhancement that would
improve the chances of achieving lower prices for customers, actually conflicts with basic features
of the auction design. ComEd asserts that It would eliminate the transparency that drives down
supplier bids through multiple auction rounds, would pose a significant risk of gaming to defeat
the purpose of the auction and would increase the risk that products in the auction end up
undersubscribed.
The proposed modification to the auction design would provide for auction rounds in which the
price of each product would tick down by uniform amounts. Suppliers would submit bids in each
round for auction products without having any information about the total volume of bids in the
auction as a whole or for any particular product. The auction would continue until all prices
declined to a level at which no supplier was willing to bid. The winning bidders would then be
selected starting with the lowest prices bid and working upward until the necessary requirements
for each product had been procured. BOMA contends that this pay-as-bid proposal offers the
prospect of achieving lower prices than are possible under the Illinois Auctions uniform clearing
price auction design.
ComEd objects to the modification because it would eliminate one of the principal benefits of
the descending clock auction format the open provision of round-by-round information about the
volume of bids as compared to auction requirements that encourages suppliers to continue bidding to
compete for the right to provide supply.
ComEd argues that BOMA incorrectly assumes that suppliers will bid the same amounts whether an
auction is pay-as-bid or is settled at a clearing price. Instead, what is true is that bidders
respond to the incentives of the situation, and the incentives for the two types of auctions are
different. ComEd asserts that the way a bidder bids is driven by balancing two opposing
considerations: bidding low enough to win, and bidding high enough to cover its costs and make a
profit. In a uniform auction, bidding a low price has a big upside in that it increases the chances
that the bidder will win. Bidding low does not have a big downside because the bid does not
necessarily affect how much the bidder will be paid for its supply given that the bidders payment
is determined by the clearing price. In a pay-as-bid auction, bidding a low price has the same
upside in terms of increasing the chances of winning a bidder. But bidding low has a much bigger
downside because every dollar that is shaved off the bid is a dollar that is shaved off the price
paid to the bidder. When balancing the upside and downside of bidding a low price, a bidder in a
uniform price auction will bid lower.
ComEd believes that the pay-as-bid approach would have suppliers acting as silos in which
submitted bids would be no different than if there had never been an
96
05-0159
Proposed Order
auction, multiple rounds or a descending clock structure. ComEd also asserts that the
elimination of round-by-round information as proposed under the pay-as-bid modification also
prevents bidders from seeing the relationship between demand and likely price for one product as
compared with another. Unlike under the Illinois Auction, buyers would have no information on
which to base a decision to switch bids from one product that attracted significant interest (and
therefore lower prices) to another that had generated fewer bids (and offered a higher price).
ComEd argues that a variant of the pay-as-bid modification introduced by BOMA would permit
suppliers to game the auction in a way that would not be possible under the Illinois Auction
proposal. According to ComEd this variant would offer bidders the right to drop out of the auction
during any round and reenter during a later round when bidding was still taking place. Under
ComEds plan a bidder seeking to withdraw supply in an effort to influence pricing would be unable
to do so under the Illinois Auction because withdrawn supply could not thereafter be sold in the
auction. Under the pay-as-bid variant, no such limitation would exist and numerous gaming
opportunities would be presented.
ComEd states that the pay-as-bid modification to a multiple round, descending clock auction
has never been used in any jurisdiction in this country to procure supply for electric utility
customers.
Staff believes that the ComEds proposed auction would result in a uniform auction clearing
price for each product. Staff notes that BOMA presented an alternative auction proposal that
generally would not lead to a uniform auction clearing price for each product. Staff further notes
the AG also discussed a type of auction utilizing price caps, possibly distinct price caps for
distinct suppliers.
Staff concludes that the record evidence in this docket shows that the alternative auction
designs presented by BOMA and the AG are either flawed or unrealistic and tend to raise several
questions that their proponents have failed to address. Indeed, they are merely the bare bones of
auction proposalsinadequately delineated to be of practical value for purposes of this docket.
For all the above reasons, Staff recommends that the Commission reject the BOMA and the AG auction
proposals.
BOMA recommends that ComEds proposed auction procurement process be changed from a descending
clock, uniform price format to a descending clock, pay as bid approach. BOMA asserts that the
record establishes that in all likelihood its proposed pay as bid approach will result in ComEd
paying a lower price for its electricity supply than ComEds proposed uniform price method.
97
05-0159
Proposed Order
Instead of stopping the auction as ComEd proposes when the amount electricity supply offered
by bidders equals ComEds full electricity supply requirements, prices continue to tick down lower
until there remains no bidder willing to supply electricity at a lower price. Bidders would not be
informed when the amount of electricity supply being bid equaled ComEds full requirements.
Bidders would not be provided with round-to-round information on excess supply remaining in the
auction, as ComEd has proposed in its approach, in order to avoid implicit collusion among bidders
on when they should stop bidding. To further avoid facilitating implicit collusion among bidders,
the tick-down in price from round to round would be made in equal decrements rather than being
based on the excess supply remaining in the auction as ComEd has proposed. When proposed
descending clock, pay as bid auction is completed, bids would be accepted in ascending order of
price until ComEds full requirements are filled.
BOMA asserts that ComEds prohibition on suppliers bidding lower in a descending clock auction
makes sense only in the context of ComEds affiliate relationship with electricity supplier Exelon
Generation, which owns more than 10,000 megawatts of nuclear generating capacity located in ComEds
service territory. BOMA points out that ComEd has a serious conflict of interest due to its
affiliation with Exelon Generation. BOMA argues that although ComEds prohibition on bidders
bidding lower helps Exelon Generation, it is diametrically opposed to the interests of ComEds
consumers.
According to BOMA, ComEd could not rebut the conflict issue. Instead, ComEd contended through
their witnesses that their uniform, market clearing price approach might result in a lower supply
price than the pay as bid approach because bidders have the incentive to bid low prices in a market
clearing price auction since all bidders know they will receive the market clearing price
regardless of how low they bid. In a descending clock structure, BOMA argues that it is correct
that bidders should be allowed to bid as low as they desire in an effort to be successful in the
auction.
BOMA does not believe that adequate supply for ComEd auction products under the proposed pay
as bid approach is a real issue. BOMA asserts that the auction process will be the only
opportunity to obtain long-term supply contracts with ComEd. BOMA further asserts that in ComEds
service territory, the amount of generating capacity greatly exceeds the peak electricity demand
(i.e., there is substantial excess generating capacity). According to BOMA, ComEds premise that
adoption of the pay as bid method could somehow result in a lack of sufficient supply for
particular products is untenable.
BOMA notes that the remaining concern with its was that it would not get the best bids
because under the pay as bid approach information regarding the amount of excess supply being bid
into the auction would not be revealed to the bidders. BOMA suggests that one of the issues for
the Commission to decide is whether the adjustment in behavior by bidders is a good thing or a
bad thing for consumers. That is, does the adjustment of bidders behavior when they are
informed of the excess
98
05-0159
Proposed Order
supply remaining in the auction result in a lower price or higher price than if this
information was not revealed to the bidders?
BOMA argues that information will in fact allow bidders to implicitly collude on when to stop
bidding and thereby implicitly collude on a high auction price.
BOMA argues that ComEds flawed winners curse argument puts it in an incongruous position:
Having spared no effort to exalt the expertise and market savvy of its anticipated bidders, ComEd
must now portray these same bidders including financial players like Morgan Stanley and Goldman
Sachs as so naive that the Commission must protect them from the excesses of their own optimism.
Furthermore, to the extent that any bidder is at the risk of being carried away by his or her own
excessive optimism it is the bidder, not Illinois consumers that should bear this risk. BOMA
argues that it is not necessary to protect bidders in the ComEd auction from the so-called
winners curse by providing them information on the amount of excess supply being bid during the
course of the auction. To the contrary, bidders should not be informed of the amount of excess
supply remaining during the auction. If the bidders are not provided with this information and the
auction is not stopped at a uniform, market clearing price as has recommended, bidders will make
bids closer to their marginal costs of production and thereby lower the supply charges paid by
consumers to ComEd.
BOMA argues that the pay as bid method has been used in auctions for electricity and other
products that have already been successfully conducted. BOMA asserts that a pay as bid competitive
bidding approach was utilized in Massachusetts. BOMA also asserts that wholesale electricity
purchasers with the most experience using auctions to purchase electricity (i.e., utilities in the
United Kingdom) used a uniform, market clearing price auction beginning in 1990 and then switched
to a pay as bid auction in 2001.
BOMA argues that in Illinois, apparently unlike New Jersey, achieving the lowest possible
prices for consumers not only is a goal, it is the law. The Act requires that public utilities
provide service to their customers at the least cost. According to BOMA, however, ComEds auction
design prohibits bidders from bidding below the market clearing price at which ComEd stops its
auction. This approach violates the Acts least cost requirement. Moreover, BOMA argues that
ComEds proposed pass-through of these charges to consumers would violate the PUAs requirement
that utility rates be just and reasonable.
BOMA further argues that unlike ComEds proposal, the pay as bid approach insures that no
price would be paid to any supplier in excess of the lowest price at which the supplier was willing
to sell electricity to ComEd. Therefore BOMA recommends that the Commission reject ComEds
descending clock, uniform clearing price approach and instead adopt the proposed descending clock,
pay as bid recommendation as ComEds method of acquiring its full requirements for electricity
supply beginning January 1, 2007.
99
05-0159
Proposed Order
MW Gen believes that the pay-as-bid approach should be rejected. MW Gen argues that BOMA
presented no empirical evidence to support the conclusion that a pay-as-bid approach is likely to
result in lower prices to consumers than the market clearing approach in ComEds proposal.
MW Gen argues that given the substantial possibility that a pay-as-bid approach would depress
supplier participation and yield uncertain changes in bidding behavior that have not been tested
sufficiently, Illinois should not adopt this suggested modification to the proposed auction.
The AG argues that given the asymmetrical cost structure that exists in the electric
generation industry, it is self-defeating for consumers to limit the price decreases a supplier
might be willing to offer. Further, multilateral negotiations, or a reserve price in an auction
are better suited to capture the different cost structures that exist.
While the pay-as-bid approach has a certain appeal based on the claim of lower prices, the
Commission finds that the pay-as-bid auction is too untried to be usable in Illinois.
Accordingly, the Commission rejects the alternative theoretical untested approaches in favor of the
descending clock auction.
ComEd describes that the Illinois Auction would be administered by an independent, third-party
Auction Manager, performing a wide variety of functions necessary to successfully complete the
procurement process. ComEd states that it had discussed with Ameren the desirability of having a
single Auction Manager to conduct the auctions to procure supply to serve their customers, and that
Ameren and it were jointly proposing that Dr. Chantale LaCasse be retained for that purpose. ComEd
notes that Dr. LaCasse is recognized as an expert on auctions, has extensive experience in this
area, and has acted as Auction Manager for each of the New Jersey Basic Generation Service
auctions. ComEd further notes that Dr. LaCasse has wide ranging background with the design and
conduct of such auctions and is highly qualified to serve in this important capacity.
100
05-0159
Proposed Order
Staff has reviewed Dr. LaCasses qualifications and is satisfied that she is competent to be
the Auction Manager for this competitive procurement process. In addition, Staff expects that
whoever is chosen as Auction Manager would share a desire by the Company to have an auction that
runs smoothly and results in as many tranches being filled as possible.
However, Staff does have concerns over the independence of whomever ComEd and Ameren hire as
the Auction Manager. This concern arises primarily because both ComEd and Ameren have affiliates
who are engaged in the sale of wholesale power and who could be bidders in the proposed auctions.
This concern can be explained as follows.
Generally speaking, Staff believes that retail consumers want low prices, along with price
stability and service reliability. These are the goals that the Staff would want the Auction
Manager to embrace, wholeheartedly, and without reservation.
However, ComEd proposes a pass-through of procurement costs (i.e., a cost-tracking
mechanism, whereby the utility experiences neither gains nor losses on retail sales of
electricity). Hence, while ComEd arguably has no disincentive to obtain low prices, by the same
argument, it may have little to no incentive to do so, either.
In contrast, ComEds wholesale power generating and marketing affiliates (and hence, ComEds
holding company) cannot be expected to be in favor of or indifferent toward low prices; rather,
they can be expected to desire high prices. Herein lies the crux of the problem. The fact that
ComEd is owned by Exelon, and Exelon would profit from higher rather than lower auction prices (all
else constant), creates a tremendous conflict of interest for both ComEd (as electricity purchasing
agent for ratepayers) and the independent Auction Manager. The Auction Manager, nominally hired
by ComEd, is effectively working for two bosses with opposing incentives: one (ComEd) that has no
particularly strong incentives but at least a duty to get low prices for its retail customers; and
another (Exelon) that has an incentive to get high prices for its generation and marketing
affiliates participating in the auction.
Staff notes that ComEd agreed that it is reasonable for the Commission to direct that: (1) the
Auction Manager should conduct the auction in close consultation with Commission Staff, and that
decisions made by the exercise of the Auction Managers professional judgment during the auction
will be made in consultation with a Staff lead designated by the Manager of the Energy Division;
(2) ComEd representatives not be present in the room during the actual conduct of the auction,
not be permitted to direct or influence the Auction Managers conduct of the action, and not be
permitted to communicate with the Auction Manager during the running of the auction; and (3) ComEd
will be entitled to round by round data concerning the price and excess aggregate supply for each
product and term, provided that this information will only be shared with specific persons at ComEd
who will be identified by name to the Manager of
101
05-0159
Proposed Order
the Energy Division in advance. Staff also notes that ComEd is also committed to continuing to
define the auction process so the rules of the auction and the criteria by which bidders actions
are to be reviewed are known well before the auction begins.
In particular, the Auction Manager and the ICC Staff with the assistance of their Advisor, who
will all monitor the bids during the Auction and administer the bidding process, will have no
contact with ComEd during the auction.
Thus, for all the reasons discussed above, including the fact that Staff will be able to
monitor and provide input on the various Auction Manager functions, Staff respectfully recommends
that the Commission approve the Companys proposal to hire an independent Auction Manager.
The record shows that having an independent, third-party Auction Manager would be advantageous
in numerous respects. In addition, the record makes clear that Dr. LaCasse is highly qualified to
hold such a position, particularly in light of her significant experience in the New Jersey
auctions. The Commission, therefore, concludes that ComEd should retain Dr. LaCasse for the role of
independent, third-party Auction Manager. However, in the event that Dr. LaCasse is unable to
serve as Auction Manager, ComEd is required to seek Commission approval for a replacement before
the auction. The Commission approves the proposal as modified.
ComEd noted that although it will retain the Auction Manager, the Auction Manager will conduct
the auction independently in accordance with procedures approved by the Commission, and will not
under the direction of ComEd.
It is important that the Auction Manager function independently of any particular party, so as
to maintain the fairness of the auction and to keep it free of any bias. As noted above, ComEd have
agreed to certain measures to help promote that independence. The Commission therefore approves
ComEds proposed level of involvement in the auction process.
ComEd states that Staff will have a major role in all aspects of the auction process, ensuring
that the Commission-approved process is followed and that the
102
05-0159
Proposed Order
interests of customers are protected. ComEd also notes that following each auction, Staff
will submit to the Commission a formal report, which will provide an independent assessment whether
the auction was conducted fairly and appropriately and all necessary actions to ensure the
competitiveness and integrity of the process were taken. ComEd further states that Staff will also
highlight any issues or concerns for consideration by the Commission and will include
recommendations regarding further action.
Given all the discussion in sub-sections E.1 and E.2, above, Staff believes that as an agent
for the Commission, it should play a definite role in the implementation of any auction approved in
this docket. Staff agrees with ComEds suggested role for Staff in the auction, and agreed in
general with the outline for a Staff Report to the Commission following each auction, which would
address pre-auction activities, the conduct of the auction, external events that may have affected
the auction results, and any issues, concerns or recommendations identified by the Staff. Staff
also proposes some modifications to the Report.
The record shows that Staff will be actively involved in all parts of the auction process,
which will help ensure the protection of consumers. The record also shows that Staffs
post-auction reports will be useful for independently assessing the fairness and appropriateness of
the auction, for helping ensure its competitiveness, for addressing issues, and for considering
potential improvements. The Commission therefore approves the proposed full involvement of Staff
in the auction process, including its issuance of a post-auction report in the form of the revised
outline.
|
4. |
|
Representation of Consumer Interests/Separate Consumer Observer |
ComEd stated that it, along with other supporters of the Illinois Auction Proposal, agreed
that the interests of customers are important and should be considered at all stages of the auction
process. ComEd pointed out that concern for customer interests has played a major role in the
development of the Proposal, shaping many of the provisions that are reflected in ComEds tariffs.
ComEd noted that the auction design provides for significant regulatory oversight by the Commission
and its Staff, which will be present at all phases of the process to assure that the interests of
customers are promoted and protected. ComEd also noted Staffs unique regulatory role in
protecting consumers.
103
05-0159
Proposed Order
b. Staffs Position
While Staff is willing to accept the responsibility for observing and assessing the auction as
a neutral party, which Staff believes is in the best interest of consumers, Staff takes no position
with respect to the CUB-CCSAO proposal for an additional Consumer Observer.
c. CUB-CCSAOs Position
CUB-CCSAO claimed that if the Commission does not reject the auction, then it should provide
for a consumer observer. They asserted that such an observer should have the same access to
information and processes as the Staff Advisor, but would be charged with monitoring the process
and outcome from a consumer perspective and presenting that perspective to the Commission when the
Commission is deciding whether to accept or reject the results of the auction. CUB-CCSAO also
suggested that their observer play an active role in other reviews.
d. AGs Position
The AG expressed concern about the ability of Staff to represent customers and proposed that
the auction design incorporate a separate consumer advocate to perform that function.
e. Commission Conclusion
Staff has extensive experience and expertise in working to protect customer interests. The
auction process envisions a full and active role for Staff in providing such a function, and Staff
has indicated its willingness to perform it. In light of the broad range of this function,
including the provision of post-auction reports and recommendations, the Commission concludes that
there is no reason to establish a separate consumer advocate at this time.
F. Date of Initial Auction
1. ComEds Position
ComEd states that in order for supply arrangements to be in place by January 1, 2007, the
initial auction must occur sometime in 2006. ComEd proposed that the initial auction be conducted
in September 2006 a date that is sufficiently close to the period in which supply will be
provided to avoid potential risk premiums that might arise from a longer lag time between the
auction and the flow of energy. ComEd notes that a September date also would provide adequate lead
time for customers to make decisions about alternative supply options.
ComEd favors a joint auction with Ameren, which would require that a common date be selected.
Toward that end, ComEd notes it and Ameren, which originally had
104
05-0159
Proposed Order
proposed a May 2006 date, had agreed that the initial auctions should be conducted during the
first ten days of September 2006.
2. Staffs Position
Staff originally recommended July 2006 as the date for the initial auction. Staff argued
that, since the 2006 auctions would be the first of their kind in Illinois, it would be wise to
ensure that an adequate amount of preparation could occur before the auction takes place. When
compared to May 2006, a July 2006 date would provide two additional months of preparation time. As
a point of comparison, Staff points out that the first two New Jersey auctions were held nearly six
months prior to the delivery dates for those auctions. Only later, as more auction experience was
gained, did the gap between auction date and delivery date narrow to less than four months.
Staff notes that Ameren and ComEd had agreed on the first ten days of September 2006 as the
timeframe for the initial auction. In the alternative, ComEd stated would prefer July 2006, but
only if there were a determination that prospective bidders participation would not be affected by
holding the auction in that month.
Staff supports a September 2006 date for the initial auctions. This date should address any
concern that the Auction Manager will not have a sufficient amount of time following the
Commissions order in this proceeding to complete the tasks that must be completed prior to the
auction, such as the testing of and practice with software and supplier training. Staff states
that It would be preferable to spend more time ironing out any problems upfront rather than, as CES
suggests, scheduling the auctions at an early date and leaving September 2006 as a fallback date.
Staff recommends that the Commission approve the September 2006 timeframe for the initial
auction. However, Staff recognizes that holding the auctions in September 2006 would leave
relatively little time prior to January 2007 should the Commission reject the auction results.
Staff expects and recommends that the Commission find that ComEd should have a contingency plan
ready to present to Staff and the Commission in the event that the auction results are rejected.
3. IIECs Position
IIEC states that if an auction is approved, the initial auction should be held in September
2006, as proposed by ComEd. After the exchange of views inherent in the filing of written direct
and rebuttal testimonies, all parties except one appear to either support or not oppose a September
2006 date for ComEds initial auction. The single dissenter from that date is the CES, which
argues for a May 2006 auction. In IIECs view, there is no compelling reason for advancing the
initial auction to a point in time more than one-half year before the winning bidders will be
required to supply power, with the concomitant increase in risk and price.
105
05-0159
Proposed Order
IIEC argues that its member companies and other consumers would have to absorb any price
premium attributable to the risks of changes in future market prices. Any such premium can be
reduced by an auction date closer to the time when supplies must be provided. For this and the
other reasons detailed below, IIEC supports the September 2006 auction date if an auction is
approved.
IIEC asserts that the September 2006 date is a more advantageous date because an auction
closer to the time of physical delivery would produce a more accurate price. IIEC argues that
reducing the time gap between the auction and actual physical delivery of power reduces bidders
uncertainty in their market pricing forecasts and any associated risk premium. This reduction of
forecast uncertainty allows bidders to offer bids that better reflect market conditions at the time
of physical power delivery.
4. CCGs Position
CCG asserts that a May auction would be better because it would provide sufficient time,
subsequent to the initial auction, for the utilities, winning suppliers and the Midwest ISO and PJM
to ensure that all of the operational details associated with providing service are in place.
Notwithstanding its preference, CCG does not object to a simultaneous September auction, but
prefers May. In addition, ComEd suggested it would be amenable to a July auction if that were
Staffs preference. CCG does not object to a July auction, but it should be noted that it is its
last preference.
5. CES Position
CES believes that conducting the auction prior to September would increase flexibility and
options for the Commission, for regulators and policymakers and, most importantly, for customers.
Accordingly, CES advances an initial auction date in May or July 2006 as appropriate.
CES argues that the experience in other states demonstrates that it is unnecessary to hold the
initial auction in September to provide sufficient time for the Auction Manager to set up the
process, advertise to potential suppliers, or provide training to suppliers. According to CES,
assuming that a final order is issued by the Commission in or about January 2006, scheduling the
initial auction for May or July would afford the Auction Manager sufficient time to set up the
process, to advertise to potential suppliers, and to provide training to suppliers. CES argues
that a total of eight (8) months of process set up, advertisement, and supplier training simply is
not necessary.
CES further states that its comparison of historic wholesale electricity prices demonstrates
that ComEds assumption that a September auction would be more accurate than an earlier auction
is not always correct. CES argues that its comparison revealed market prices in May were as
accurate as the market prices in September for the upcoming calendar year.
106
05-0159
Proposed Order
CES argues that a May or July 2006 date for the initial auction would provide additional time
for customers particularly those below 1 MW of demand to assess their options prior to the
end of the mandatory transition period on January 1, 2007.
CES believes that it is critical that the initial auction be a success and that the market be
launched with the least amount of uncertainty. Unknown risks and issues resulting from
inexperience could impact the success of the initial auction; therefore, allowing for additional
time could help to minimize those potential risks. Holding the initial auction prior to September
2006 would provide auction participants, the Commission, and the Auction Manager the benefit of
additional time to make corrections or adjustments in the event of problems that impact either or
both the ComEd and the Ameren auctions.
CES asserts that setting a 2006 initial auction date, the Commission will be encouraging a
time frame that will help move all parties in the direction of defining the post-transition rules
of the game, thus bringing more certainty to the environment for customer decision-making.
6. Commission Conclusion
The record shows that conducting the ComEd and Ameren auctions simultaneously would be
beneficial to all concerned parties. The evidence also favors September 2006 over May 2006, as the
September date would permit more time to complete various pre-auction tasks and iron out any
problems, and would tend to provide more accurate prices, thereby reducing any need for a risk
premium to cover a longer period between the auctions and the January 2007 start date. The
Commission therefore approves the first ten days of September 2006 as the period for commencing the
initial ComEd and Ameren auctions.
G. Common vs. Parallel Auction
1. Among Fixed Price Products and Hourly Products
a. ComEds Position
In its original filings, ComEd proposed that various fixed price products should be grouped
together and auctioned simultaneously, while the hourly product should be purchased in its own
separate auction (held in parallel with the fixed price products auction). In addition,
ComEd proposed that its various products should be auctioned separately from Amerens products (in
parallel auctions). In its rebuttal testimony, ComEd modified its proposal to allow: (1) a common
auction for all of the fixed price products of both ComEd and Ameren; (2) a common auction for the
hourly products of both ComEd and Ameren; but (3) the two common auctions referenced above would be
conducted in parallel in relation to each other.
107
05-0159
Proposed Order
b. Staffs Position
Staff agrees with approach of combining products within a single common auction. Staff notes
the general efficiency gains and consumer benefits to the common auction approach (allowing
switching or arbitrage between products) as opposed to the separate but parallel auction
approach. In fact, as discussed in the next few sub-sections, Staff argues that more of the ComEd
and Ameren products should be auctioned simultaneously, within the same common auction.
c. Commission Conclusion
The Commission finds that a common auction for fixed-price products and a common auction for
hourly products is efficient, and provides additional benefits to consumers as compared with the
parallel auction approach. Accordingly, ComEds proposal, as modified in its rebuttal testimony,
is approved.
2. Between Fixed Price and Hourly Products
a. ComEds Position
ComEd states that the fixed and hourly products are not good substitutes for each other and
that switching between them would not be appropriate or effective. ComEd notes that switching
between these products would present risks of additional costs, complexity and potential for
strategic bidding behavior that may be detrimental to the auction.
b. Staffs Position
Staff notes that ComEd and Ameren both agreed to hold two common auctions: (1) for all of
their fixed-price products and (2) for both of their hourly products. Staff further notes that the
companies rejected Staffs proposal to combine the fixed price and hourly products under just one
common auction.
Staff had argued that allowing suppliers to switch between the fixed price and hourly price
products should impose little to no incremental costs on the utilities and that even a small number
of suppliers engaging in arbitrage can have a significant effect on the auction prices.
Based on the eventual concurrence between the witnesses who testified to the issue, and on the
fact that no other party opposed the auctioning of the fixed price and hourly products
separately (in parallel auctions), Staff respectfully recommends that the Commission approve this
feature of the proposed auction process.
108
05-0159
Proposed Order
c. Commission Conclusion
The record shows that allowing bidders to switch between fixed price and hourly products in an
auction setting would be neither appropriate nor effective. Additionally, the potential benefits
of combining the fixed price and hourly price contracts into a single auction are relatively small.
Therefore, the Commission accepts ComEds revised approach to product switching, recommending
approval of the proposal with fixed price and hourly products to be auctioned separately.
3. Between ComEd and Ameren Products
a. ComEds Position
ComEd initially considered separate parallel auctions by ComEd and by Ameren. Staff urged
that the auction rules provide for switching between the fixed price products of ComEd and Ameren.
Having reached agreement with Ameren (prior to the filing of rebuttal testimony) on a common date
for the initial auction, ComEd responded favorably to Staffs suggestion and proposed in Mr.
McNeils testimony that the auction provide for switching between ComEd and Ameren fixed price
products. ComEd also proposes that switching be permitted between the hourly products of ComEd and
the hourly products of Ameren. ComEd identified the fixed and hourly price products of ComEd and
Ameren to be included in the Illinois Auction divided between the Fixed Price Section (within which
switching is permitted) and the Hourly Price Section (within which switching is also permitted).
b. Staffs Position
Staff recommends that the Commission approve the proposal to combine ComEd products with
Ameren products, to the extent described above, in order to conduct two common auctions in parallel
with each other: (1) a fixed price product auction consisting of several fixed price products; and
(2) an hourly product auction consisting of two hourly products.
c. IIECs Position
IIEC supports the notion of a common auction between the ComEd and Ameren territories, should
an auction process be approved in this case. IIEC believes that since the load zones would not be
bifurcated into two separate auctions, lower market clearing prices would result from a joint
auction because the auction would be more competitive in both load zones. IIEC notes that
disparities such as the lack of a single common deliverability test, serve to bifurcate the
auctions and tend to make them less competitive, as bidders are unlikely to switch their bids
between load zones during auction rounds with such market bifurcation.
IIEC notes that another disparity between the ComEd and Ameren auctions is in the nature of
the auction segments, with differing load profiles for the annual fixed-price
109
05-0159
Proposed Order
products. According to IIEC, the current ComEd annual product auction (CPP-A) recommendation
is to put to auction the load of customers in the 400 kW through 3 MW class in one auction. Within
this customer class, some customers will be automatically migrated to the annual product, while
others will be automatically migrated to ComEds proposed hourly rate. IIEC contrasts the ComEd
proposed class definition, with the Ameren Companies proposal to cover all customers 1 MW and
above. IIEC argues that the Ameren class could potentially include customers with demands of tens
or even hundreds of megawatts of load. Because these annual segment customer classes are
potentially so radically different in terms of load profile, load factor and their propensity to
migrate to and from the annual product, it is unclear how auction suppliers could, as a practical
matter, readily switch their bids from one auction to the other. The cost of providing a full
requirements product for these customer segments can differ markedly and makes switching less
likely.
IIEC recommends a separate auction segment for customers with demands greater than 3 MW (in
conjunction with its proposal for ComEd to provide an annual fixed-price product to such
customers).
d. CES Position
CES does not object to this proposition, but that the desire for perfect congruence in auction
products between ComEd and Ameren should not come at the expense of interfering with the markets
role in allocating migration risk premiums.
CES believes that competition likely will develop in the Ameren service areas to a degree
similar to that which already has developed in the ComEd service area. The end of the transition
period should be the end of institutional obstacles, intended or inadvertent, that frustrate
customer choice in the Ameren service territories and the Coalition is confident that with
continued Commission oversight and intervention (if necessary), switching levels similar to ComEd
can be achieved in the Ameren service areas. Accordingly, CES states that it would be appropriate
to group all 400 kW to 1 MW customers together. Indeed, it would be improper for the Commission to
build incentives into the auction process for ComEds rates to displace products that easily can be
supplied by the competitive retail market.
CES argues that it is entirely appropriate to include those ComEd customers in the CPP-A
auction. Although it is likely that the 400 kW to 1 MW customers in the Ameren service territory
will experience similar switching levels following the transition period, their inclusion in the
Ameren equivalent of the CPP-A auction should not be determinative of the make-up of the ComEd
products.
e. Commission Conclusion
The Commission finds that the fixed price and hourly price products of ComEd and Ameren to be
included in the Illinois Auction divided between the Fixed Price Section (within which switching is
permitted) and the Hourly Price Section (within which
110
05-0159
Proposed Order
switching is also permitted) as identified in ComEd Ex. 11.5 (b) will be subject to common
auction, as proposed by ComEd. IIEC and CES proposals are addressed elsewhere in this Order.
4. Common Deliverability Test Applicable to Illinois Generation
a. Staffs Position
Staff expresses no position on the IIECs apparent recommendation that the Commission require
ComEd to work with Ameren, PJM and MISO to establish a common deliverability test for capacity
resources within the combined MISO and PJM footprint to the combined ComEd and Ameren load zones in
Illinois. Staff states that approval of ComEds proposed auctions should not be withheld until
such a common deliverability test is established, and cited the testimony of numerous witnesses who
indicated that there are benefits to a common auction, even if the seams between MISO and ComEd are
not completely eliminated.
b. IIECs Position
IIEC states that MISO and PJM each perform a test to determine whether capacity resources are
deliverable to aggregate load in their respective footprints. IIEC believes that if customers are
to receive the full benefit of having ComEd (and the Ameren Companies) conduct a single auction and
to facilitate the ability of bidders to switch between ComEd and Ameren fixed price products, ComEd
(and the Ameren Companies) should be directed to work with one another, as well as with MISO and
PJM to develop a single common deliverability test for resources in the combined PJM-MISO footprint
to load within the ComEd and Ameren service areas within the State of Illinois.
IIEC argues that there is a disparate treatment of capacity resources in the MISO versus those
in PJM for service to ComEd load in PJM and in treatment of capacity resources in PJM versus those
in MISO for service to Ameren load in MISO. Specifically, MISO and PJM separately perform a test
for capacity resources to determine whether those resources are deliverable to aggregate load in
their respective footprints. The tests are not the same. In addition, for a capacity resource in
one RTO to be deemed deliverable to load in the other RTO, firm point-to-point transmission service
must be requested from the capacity resource to the boundary with the other RTO. In addition,
case-by-case transmission studies that can be lengthy (at least 60 days) and costly (on the order
of tens of thousands of dollars) may be required both within the RTO in which the capacity resource
is located and in the RTO where the load is located. Furthermore, even if these studies show that
the resource is deliverable for one auction, the inter-RTO deliverability finding would not apply
in the other auction. New studies would be needed for future auctions.
IIEC asserts that these hurdles make it cumbersome and expensive for bidders to rely on
capacity resources in the MISO for the ComEd auctions and on capacity
111
05-0159
Proposed Order
resources in PJM for the Ameren auction. Thus, bidders will be inclined to rely on resources
inside PJM for the ComEd auction and on resources inside MISO for the Ameren auction. IIEC further
argues that it is unlikely, in the auctions as proposed, there will be much switching by bidders
between the ComEd and Ameren auctions due to the aforementioned lack of interchangeability of
capacity resources between the ComEd and Ameren load zones.
IIEC requests that as a condition of approval of its Illinois Auction Proposal ComEd should be
required to work with Ameren, PJM and the MISO to remove, as soon as practicable, those impediments
that preclude a single common market starting with the implementation as soon as practical of a
single common deliverability test for the delivery of resources in the combined PJM and MISO
footprint to the combined load zones of ComEd and Ameren in Illinois. In addition, ComEd should be
required to report on the status of the development of a single common deliverability test within
90 days of a Commission order in this proceeding and every 90 days thereafter until the single
common deliverability test is implemented.
c. Commission Conclusion
Based on the record, the Commission concludes that approval of ComEds proposed auctions
should not be withheld until such a common deliverability test is established.
H. Contract Durations for Blended, Fixed Price Product
1. Proposed Blends for Residential and Small Commercial Customer Supply
a. ComEds Position
ComEd has proposed to use a blend of contract durations to acquire supply for residential
customers. Under the Illinois Auction proposal, supply for ComEds residential customers will be
provided under agreements with a series of staggered 1, 3 and 5 year contract terms comprising 15%,
60%, and 25% of the auction respectively. ComEd states that this feature of the Illinois Auction
that has received broad support, notably the Staffs Final Report discussed the ways in which the
goals of rate stability and market based pricing can be balanced through separate products designed
for different customer groups, giving as one example the possibility of offering a relatively
stable product for small customers based on overlapping multi-year full requirements contracts with
suppliers . . . . ComEd maintains that its blended 1, 3 and 5 year contract product for
residential customers complies with the Staffs guidance, making a relatively stable product
available to provide supply for residential customers.
ComEd responds to DES proposal for 3-month contracts by noting that small customers will have
the option to choose short-term price signals through real-time pricing options. However, ComEd
maintains that it would be inappropriate to use such
112
05-0159
Proposed Order
short-term contracts for default service as customers would be unnecessarily exposed to price
volatility.
Regarding the concerns voiced by the AG and PES about the robustness of the five-year
contract, ComEd points out that markets exist for longer-term contracts. Second, ComEd states that
the actual offering of five-year contracts as part of the Illinois auction proposal will help to
create an even more robust market
b. Staffs Position
Staff notes that for the majority of customerswith peak demands under 400 kWComEd proposes
to maintain an annually-revised blend of 1-year, 3-year, and 5-year supply contracts. Staff
further notes that delivery under each contract would begin in June and end 12, 36, or 60 months
later in May. However, in the initial auction, delivery must begin in January, due to the December
31, 2006 expiration of the Companys existing supply contract. Staff comments that in order to
effectively transition to an annually-revised blend of 1-, 3-, and 5-year contracts, it is also
necessary to include within the initial auction some 4-year, 2-year, and additional 1-year
contracts (all of which would also include the extra 5 months for January through May of 2007).
Staff states that the appropriateness of the proposed 5-year, 3-year, and 1-year durations and
the appropriateness of the percentages to acquire of each (i.e., 25%, 60%, and 15%, respectively),
were issues in the case.
Staff concludes that the evidence supports adoption of the Companys proposed mix of 1-year,
3-year, and a conservatively small number of 5-year supply contracts for serving the so-called
blended segment. In Staffs view, at this time, there is no evidence of a better way of
balancing the twin goals of price stability and market sensitive pricing, which were reasonably
articulated by ComEd. Staff would be particularly concerned with proposals to use contracts of
less than 1 year, considering such alternatives inconsistent with obtaining price stability. Staff
would also be opposed to making significant greater use of long-term contracts, such as 5-year or
longer. Such alternatives would be inconsistent with obtaining market-sensitive pricing and could
entail significant risk premiums. Staff recommends that the Commission approve the Companys
proposed long-term mix of 25% 5-year, 60% 3-year, and 15% 1-year contracts, along with the
transitional use of other contract durations during the initial auction in order to arrive at this
long-term mix.
c. CCSAOs Position
CCSAO is concerned with ComEds procurement proposal noting that ComEd focuses on the
implementation details of an auction while glossing over the fundamental question of whether other
options would better serve the public interest. CCSAO asserts that in this proceeding, ComEd has
presented a single option for the
113
05-0159
Proposed Order
Commissions consideration, an option that relieves the Company of the greatest part of its
responsibility for the results of its power procurement decision.
CCSAO urge the Commission to reject ComEds proposal; open a new docket to consider the full
range of procurement options; and affirm that, regardless of which procurement method is employed,
retail rates remain subject to traditional regulatory standards of justness and reasonableness,
which entail a prudence review of the companys decisions.
CCSAO argues that the Commission should recognize that the Company retains responsibility for
making and managing the decisions and actions necessary to serve default service customers and
should clarify that the Commission will ensure, as part of its oversight responsibility, that the
Company has done so in a manner that best serves default service customers. CCSAO further argues
that the Commission needs to put ComEds auction proposal in context. One of ComEds experts, Dr.
Chantale LaCasse has been employed at NERA since 2001 and has been employed at least four times by
a utility or company working in the electric industry. CCSAO states that while the auction has
been used in New Jersey and attempted in Ohio it has not been proven in this case to meet the
requirements of the Public Utilities Act.
d. DES Position
Under the DES proposal, residential and small commercial customer supply (customers with
annual usage less than 15,000 kWh) would be procured using four quarterly auctions; supply for
larger commercial customers (with demands less than 1 MW) would be procured in monthly auctions.
e. Commission Conclusion
Many of the parties in this proceeding have put forth differing proposals regarding the blend
of contracts. While some parties suggest short-term contracts and some long-term contracts, ComEd
and Staff support a blend designed to balance price stability and market sensitivity. Staff
supported ComEds proposed blend of contracts with a risk analysis which showed that longer term
contracts would likely result in excessive risk premiums. ComEd has shown that the proposed blend
of a series of staggered 1, 3 and 5 year contract terms comprising 15%, 60%, and 25% of the auction
respectively is appropriate. The Commission approves ComEds proposed blend of contracts.
2. Five-Year Agreements
a. ComEds Position
As discussed Section V(H)(1), ComEd has proposed to use a blend of contracts composed of 25%
five-year contracts.
114
05-0159
Proposed Order
b. Staffs Position
Staffs position is discussed in Section V(H)(1). Staff supports the use of 25% five-year
contracts.
c. CUBs Position
CUB suggests that the number of 5-year agreements in the blend be increased and that the
percentage of 1-year contracts be decreased. In support of this approach, CUB noted that these
changes could reduce the percentage of ComEds total load that would be included in annual auctions
after the initial
d. DES Position
DES argues that the problem is that under the ComEd proposal there is little focus on making
retail competition work, for smaller business and residential customers. Long-term wholesale
contracts discourage movement toward a competitive retail electric market. In fact, the ComEd
proposal, based on such long-term, wholesale supply contracts, ignores the benefits of
market-reflective default pricing proposed by Direct Energy and USESC.
e. Commission Conclusion
As discussed in Section V(H)(1), ComEd has proposed a blend of contracts, including 25%
five-year contracts. Both Staff and ComEd have shown that long-term contracts are an important
part of a balanced portfolio to provide for price stability. However, due to risk premiums
included in five-year contract prices, there is a need to balance the associated cost with the
control of price volatility. The Commission adopts ComEds proposal to use 25% five-year contracts
as an appropriate balance.
3. Three-Year Agreements
a. ComEds Position
As discussed Section V(H)(1), ComEd has proposed to use a blend of contracts composed of 60%
three-year contracts as they provide a balance of price stability and market sensitivity.
b. Commission Conclusion
As discussed in Section V(H)(1), ComEd has proposed a blend of contracts including 60%
three-year contracts. Both Staff and ComEd have shown that mid-term contracts contribute to a
balanced portfolio. The Commission adopts ComEds proposal to use 60% three-year contracts.
115
05-0159
Proposed Order
4. One-Year Agreements
a. ComEds Position
As discussed more fully in Section V(H)(1), ComEd has proposed to use a blend consisting of
15% 1-year agreements. ComEd states that, even those who sought to eliminate 5- and 3-year
agreements entirely, acknowledge that they add an element of stability to the overall rate.
b. Commission Conclusion
As discussed in Section V(H)(1), ComEd has proposed a blend of contracts including 15%
one-year contracts. Both Staff and ComEd have shown that short-term contracts increase the risk of
price volatility. However, such contracts also provide the lowest risk premium. The Commission
finds that ComEds proposal strikes an appropriate balance. The Commission adopts ComEds proposal
to use 15% 1-year contracts.
5. Percentage of Supply Acquired at Subsequent Auctions
a. ComEds Position
ComEd has proposed a staggered-term structure which limits acquisition volume after the
initial auction to 40% of ComEds load.
b. Staffs Position
Staff supports ComEds proposed blend of contracts as well as the resulting amount of supply
to be acquired at subsequent auctions.
c. Commission Conclusion
ComEd has proposed a blend that will result in approximately 40% of its requirements to be
acquired at subsequent auctions. While CUB has indicated a desire to reduce that amount, Staff and
ComEd have shown that ComEds proposal reflects an appropriate balance between the risk premium of
long-term contracts, which would mean a lower amount of supply in subsequent auctions and the price
volatility of short-term contracts, which result in a higher amount of supply in subsequent
auctions.
116
05-0159
Proposed Order
I. Fixed Price Auction Product and Tariffed Services for Larger Customers
1. Nature of Auction Product and Tariffed Services for 1 3 MW
Customers
a. ComEds Position
ComEds initial proposal contemplates that supply for customers with peak demands between 1 MW
and 3 MW would be procured through agreements with one-year terms (CPP-A). The one-year fixed
price product for this customer group has remained unchanged.
Regarding the proposal by BOMA to allow 1-3 MW customers access to the CCP-B auction product,
ComEd expresses concern that allowing the 1-3 MW customer class access to the CPP-B product would
retard competition. In addition, ComEd points out that one of the purposes is to provide
unsophisticated customers with price volatility protection. However, ComEd states that the 1-3 MW
customers are sophisticated and do not need the additional protection of the blended product.
b. Staffs Position
Staff does not oppose ComEds surrebuttal proposal to set the range for the CPP-A class
between 400 kW and 3 MW. Switching data presented in Dr. OConnors rebuttal testimony indicates
that that customers in the 400 kW to 1 MW demand class currently exhibit switching characteristics
that are very similar toin fact almost indistinguishable fromcustomers with a peak demand of
greater than 1 MW but less than 3 MW. Staff agrees that not only does the inclusion of 400 KW to 1
MW customers in the CPP-A segment rather than the CPP-B segment provide a logical and reasonable
grouping based on statistical switching propensities, but such a grouping also eliminates the need
to utilize a migration risk allocation mechanism in the rate translation mechanism (or rate prism)
for the remainder of the mass market customers in the blended product (i.e., less than 400 KW).
c. DES Position
DES propose that for customers with demands equal to or over 1 MW that have not been declared
competitive, the bundled product should be an hourly energy product. Notably, for customers with
demands equal to or over 1 MW that have not been declared competitive, interval meters are already
installed, so no new metering technology would be required to implement this option.
d. BOMAs Position
BOMA insists that if an auction process is approved by the Commission, the Commission should
require that ComEds CPP-B auction product be made available to
117
05-0159
Proposed Order
customers with peak demands of 1 to 3 megawatts (MW) and should reject ComEds proposal that
this class of customers have a separate CPP-A auction product. BOMA asserts that the CPP-B auction
product should be made available to the 1-3 MW customer class in order to provide these customers
the same price volatility mitigation that ComEd has proposed for other classes of its customers.
BOMA notes that ComEd will procure its electric supply requirements for the CPP-B auction
product, which ComEd proposes for all customers with less than 400 kilowatts of peak demand, by
executing a blend of one-year, three-year and five-year contracts with suppliers. In contrast,
BOMA notes that ComEd will procure its full requirements electric supply for the CPP-A auction only
through one-year contracts.
BOMA argues that ComEds rational does not support the exclusion of 1-3 MW customers from the
CPP-B auction product. Merely because 1-3 MW customers may be more sophisticated than other
customers does not mean that they should not continue to be offered ComEd rates that mitigate price
volatility. Moreover, although BOMA agrees that the staggered contract terms of the CPP-B auction
will somewhat lessen price volatility, ComEds characterization of the CPP-B auction product as
price protection that could somehow retard the development of the competitive retail markets is
totally inaccurate. While the CPP-B auction product price will be less volatile than the price of
ComEds proposed CPP-A auction product, the CPP-B price is still a far cry from ComEds currently
frozen bundled rates.
BOMA argues that the record in this case clearly establishes that making the CPP-B auction
product available to the 1-3 MW class of customers will not affect the development of the
competitive market. Therefore, the Commission should reject ComEds proposed CPP-A auction product
and provide the CPP-B auction product to the 1-3 MW class of customers if an auction process is
approved by the Commission.
e. Commission Conclusion
ComEd has proposed placing the 1 MW to 3 MW customers on the CPP-A product. BOMA is the only
party who opposed this. BOMA has not presented sufficient evidence to show why this customer class
should be offered the blended auction product. Rather, ComEd has shown that the 1 MW to 3 MW
customers should be placed on the CPP-A product. The Commission accepts ComEds proposal to serve
1 to 3 MW customers with the CPP-A product.
2. Nature of Auction Product and Tariffed Services for 400 kW 1 MW Customers
a. ComEds Position
ComEds proposal envisioned that supply for 400 kW to 1 MW customers would be procured in the
one, three and five-year blended auction that also served residential customers.
118
05-0159
Proposed Order
After considering the views expressed by the Coalition and the Staff, ComEd revised its
proposal to include supply for 400 kW to 1 MW customers in the one-year fixed price auction, rather
than in the blended auction. ComEd notes that that change had the collateral effect of eliminating
the need for the migration adjustment factor initially proposed by ComEd to account for the
different propensity of 400 kW to 1 MW customers to switch suppliers as compared with residential
customers. As a result of ComEds revised proposal, ComEd states that there is now widespread
agreement on appropriate supply terms for customers with peak demands between 400 kW and 3 MW.
b. Staffs Position
Staff does not oppose ComEds surrebuttal position setting the range for the CPP-A product
between 400 kW and 3 MW. Staff notes that switching data supports this grouping.
c. BOMAs Position
BOMA claims that ComEds revised proposal to serve 400kw to 1 MW customers with the CPP-A
product would harm customers. BOMA claims that such customers need to have access to the blended
product to enjoy the benefits of market competition and to obtain protection against price
volatility.
d. DES Position
For customers with an annual peak demand under 1 MW and annual usage greater than 15,000 kWh
that have not been declared competitive, the DES proposal would have them be eligible for a Bundled
Product with a monthly energy price. These customers also would have access to a monthly Delivery
Service tariff. Customers with peak demands less than 15,000 kWh would be eligible for a Bundled
Product with a quarterly fixed price product. These customers would also have the right to access
a quarterly Delivery Service tariff.
e. Commission Conclusion
ComEd has proposed placing the 400 kW to 1 MW customers on the CPP-A product. Staff and CES
agree. ComEd has shown that the 400 kW to 1 MW customers should be serviced with the CPP-A
product. Although BOMA opposes this, it has not presented sufficient evidence to support its
proposal. The Commission accepts ComEds proposal to serve 400 kW to 1 MW customers with the CPP-A
product.
119
05-0159
Proposed Order
3. Treatment of Customers (³ 3MW) Taking Services Subject to a Competitive Declaration
a. ComEds Position
ComEd states that service to customers with peak demands in excess of 3 MW is subject to a
competitive declaration that became effective by operation of law in 2003. Given that competitive
declaration, ComEd notes that the legal status of these customers with respect to ComEd service
obligations is different from the status of other customers. ComEd indicates that tariffed service
for customers who are subject to a competitive declaration is not required a legal distinction
that recognizes the competitive alternatives that are available to this customer group.
Regarding the various proposals to advocate inclusion of this customer group in the one-year
fixed price supply auction, ComEd indicates that it understands that the Commission cannot require
this change for customers subject to a competitive declaration, and that the proposals by these
parties are in the nature of requests that ComEd voluntarily extend the one-year fixed price
auction to include customers who have no legal right to be included.
ComEd states that it has considered these suggestions, but determined that the line between
customers subject to a competitive declaration and those who are not should be respected. ComEd
maintains that there are already retail electric suppliers in Illinois offering service to this
customer group. Regarding the DOEs contention that a large federal government customer received
few, if any, responses to requests for proposals from retail suppliers, ComEd notes that cross
examination of the DOE witness suggested that the terms of the RFP were responsible for the outcome
because they included onerous provisions.
In contrast to DOEs and IIECs claims, ComEd states that the customers in the over 3 MW
category have alternative sources of supply if they agree to reasonable commercial terms. ComEd
states that it will continue to offer bundled service to over 3 MW customers, but the service would
be supplied through hourly energy purchases. ComEd notes that it is not required to provided a
fixed-price POLR product for large load customers and that hourly pricing will provide a sufficient
safety net in the unlikely event that such service is needed. ComEd further highlighted the fact
that the DOEs own contract terms have historically presented a hurdle for their receiving a RES
contract.
b. Staffs Position
Staff does not oppose the proposals offered by the representatives of the large customer
groups. There is obviously a demand among large customers for such a service, and Staff believes
that the existence of an additional auction for the large customer groups would only affect the
development of the retail market to a limited
120
05-0159
Proposed Order
extent. If the 3 MW and above customers are included in the auction, the most logical option
would be to include the 3 MW and above customer group in the CPP-A auction.
Staff notes that, while all customers in the 3 MW and above demand class that are not being
served by RESs through long-term contracts would find a fixed-rate offering to be valuable, the
primary beneficiaries of such an offering are those customers that have not been able to attract
satisfactory RES offers. Staff comments that under ComEds proposal, even though these customers
have not switched to RES service after several years of eligibility for delivery services, the only
supply option available to them would be the hourly service. According to Staff, a ComEd-offered
supply service would function as the price-to-beat, which would limit the prices that RES could
offer to prospective customers.
Staff asserts that ComEd should be indifferent as to its customers sources of power, since
ComEd is a delivery-only company without its own generation sources. Staff prefers the annual
product, and recommends that ComEd add the load of the 3 MW to the load of the customers eligible
for the CPP-A product. This alternative would make the CPP-A annual service very similar to the
corresponding proposed Ameren service offering for large customers, for which customers with a
demand exceeding 1 MW are eligible.
Staff does not object to the IIEC proposal of pre-qualification as it may tend to reduce any
risk premium that wholesale suppliers may consider adding to their bids. This proposal could also
be applied (at least on a voluntary basis) to the other customers eligible for the CPP-A auction.
c. DOEs Position
DOE notes that ComEd intends to provide fixed-price bundled POLR service to all of its
customers, except those large customers with loads of 3 MW or higher and proposes to provide to
these competitive customers only hourly priced POLR service, essentially forcing these large
customers to rely on the PJM hourly Locational Marginal Price (LMP) as their default service in the
event they are unable to obtain a reasonably priced supply contract from a RES. DOE argues that
ComEd offers no persuasive policy reasons for its failure to offer these customers a fixed-price
POLR product, but rather simply states that it has no obligation to do so and it chooses not to do
so.
DOE argues that its proposal for fixed price POLR service would allow dollar-for-dollar
recovery for ComEd of all supply-related costs, comparable to what the Company itself has proposed.
DOE further argues that its proposal requires any such procurement be conducted separately as
either an RFP or declining clock auction with large customer service as a separate product. The
large customers will be responsible for all costs of providing the POLR supply.
DOE argues that such a service offering is needed as a safety net in those instances when the
customer cannot secure a fixed-price RES contract on reasonable
121
05-0159
Proposed Order
terms. The hourly priced POLR imposes unacceptable risks, operational problems and
administrative costs on retail customers, particularly governmental customers that must adhere to
budgets.
DOE states that ComEd has provided no policy reason why a fixed-priced, product should not be
offered to these large customers, but rather has simply stated that it doesnt have to and so it
will not. DOE notes that all the parties representing the affected customers believe the provision
of such a product would provide a public service. Further, it has also been demonstrated that the
provision of such a public service would have no adverse impact on any other party to this
proceeding as ComEd would be fully compensated for all costs incurred in procuring the power and
providing the bundled fixed-price service to those customers.
DOE further argues that the provision of either a one-year or a quarterly fixed-price POLR
service would not adversely affect retail electricity suppliers nor slow the development of the
competitive retail market. Because of the significant load uncertainty that a wholesale supplier
will face when bidding for the supply under a fixed-price POLR service for above 3MW customers,
those suppliers will include a significant risk premium in the price.
DOE notes that for whatever reason, there is no guarantee that all customers above 3 MW will
always be able to secure long-term hedged contracts with retail suppliers. A one-year or, at
least, a quarterly fixed-price POLR product will provide a safety net to these customers who,
otherwise, would be forced onto the hourly market where their power costs will be determined by the
unstable hour-to-hour PJM locational marginal prices. That is a situation that causes great concern
among most large customers and on the part of Federal Executive Agency customers in particular.
DOE continues stating that there is a vital need for some sort of utility safety net service in a
form other than hourly-priced service.
d. CES Position
CES notes that service for the over 3MW customer group has been declared competitive. CES
maintains that several of the parties effectively seek to rescind that declaration, such as by
requiring ComEd to provide POLR service in the form of a fixed price product. CES opposes such
proposals.
e. IIECs Position
IIEC does not believe that having only an hourly energy price option will be a sufficient
utility default option for any customer group, including customers 3 MW and greater. That single,
price-volatile, option does not allow customers to enjoy the full benefits of the available
competitive markets.
122
05-0159
Proposed Order
IIEC states that there has been little overall change in the number of customers 3 MW and
larger who are taking RES supply and that this demonstrates a stagnation in movement from bundled
rates to third party supply.
IIEC argues that the existence of the competitive declaration (by operation of law) should not
be determinative of whether or not a fixed-price product should be offered to customers in any
event. In this case, ComEd has not even acknowledged an obligation to offer the hourly service
which it proposes to offer. IIEC asserts that customers generally, and 3 MW and larger customers
specifically, have not found hourly priced service useful or economic for their electric supply
needs.
The one-year product is not a bundled service, but a supply option that would be used with
unbundled delivery service.
IIEC asserts that the Commission should as a condition of the auction direct ComEd to provide
an annual fixed-price option to customers pursuant to an annual auction. If the Commission
believes it is prohibited legally from doing so because ComEds petition to declare Rate 6L service
competitive was allowed to take effect by operation of law, the Commission should immediately
reopen Docket No. 02-0479 for the purpose of ruling on (and explicitly denying), the petition for
competitive declaration so that it is not a barrier to all customers obtaining the full benefit of
the competitive wholesale market as intended by the General Assembly.
IIEC states that a fixed-price product is needed for customers 3 MW and over. Access to the
wholesale supply market via the ComEd auction is necessary to provide customers the full benefit of
a competitive market because of the current state of the retail market.
IIEC notes that ComEds rationale for opposing the provision of the fixed annual price service
to customers 3 MW and larger is that ComEd has no obligation to provide such service to these
customers and does not choose to offer it. IIEC further notes that ComEd suggests that offering a
fixed price product to 3 MW and over customers would retard the development of a competitive
market.
IIEC states that offering this service would not harm ComEd and it would not harm other
customers, since under IIECs proposal, the 3 MW and above segment would be separated from the
remaining customer load. Finally, it would not harm development of the competitive retail market.
IIEC agrees that providing customers with a fixed price product set at a market level will
allow customers to evaluate competitive offers from retail electric suppliers and encourage
efficient decisions and thus promote efficient retail competition. IIECs proposal to have ComEd
offer a fixed price service to 3 MW and over customers will accomplish this same purpose.
123
05-0159
Proposed Order
IIEC argues that ComEd should provide or be compelled to provide this product offering as a
condition of the auction. The offering of the product will not impair the development of an
efficiently competitive market.
IIEC asserts that a separate auction or auction segment be conducted. First, a separate
auction or auction segment would promote uniformity between the ComEd and Ameren products. Second,
a separate auction or auction segment would recognize the fact that the load characteristics of the
customers in the 3 MW and larger range may be significantly different from the customers in the 1-3
MW range (as originally proposed by ComEd) or the expanded 400 kW to 3 MW range. Third, for
suppliers associated with the 3 MW and larger customer group, there may be load risk (the risk the
actual load will vary from the projections used for the auction).
IIEC argues that this separate solicitation for the 3 MW and larger customer loads could be
done in an auction form at the same time as the other CPP auction segments, although a properly
designed RFP could also work. Accordingly, the Commission should approve a separate solicitation
for the 3 MW and larger customers as recommended by IIEC.
IIEC also recommends that a solicitation for a multi-year product should be considered in
addition to the one-year product for customers subject to the CPP-A (annual) auction. Large
customers, such as IIEC members, have a desire for a multi-year product, which will not be
available under a strictly annual approach. IIEC notes that ComEd proposes to offer to smaller
customers a blended product, which moderates price volatility by replacing only a portion of the
supply each year so customers will not feel the full year-to-year movement due to the product
blending.
IIEC recommends the same general procedures be used for a multi-year product as are used for a
one-year fixed product; that is, the product would be bid each year based on load that has
prequalified for service. Customers would then have a limited enrollment period once prices are
known and must commit to the full multi-year term.
IIEC also notes that this product is comparable to the primary product produced by the ComEd
auction process. IIEC recognizes that a multi-year product, while important in the initial period,
may not need to be permanent in nature. Over time, it may become clear that the multi-year product
is relatively unattractive to customers compared to third-party supply and as such, they may not
elect to even prequalify for the product. If no customer has elected to prequalify or take the
product for a number of auction cycles, such as three, it may be appropriate to discontinue the
multi-year product offering.
IIEC has proposed a method to mitigate this load risk by enhancing the certainty associated
with the load profile of these customers in aggregate. IIEC proposes to do this by requiring
customers in this group to prequalify their load for the auction.
124
05-0159
Proposed Order
The IIEC approach would prevent customers, precluded from electing the fixed-price service for
any reason, or otherwise not interested in being a part of the auction, from exacerbating the load
risk to the detriment of other customers in the class. IIEC asserts that the suppliers will not
have to worry with load they know in advance they will not need to serve.
IIEC further outlines its proposal as follows: this prequalification would not be a commitment
to take the ultimate fixed-price offer, as the pricing will not be known at that point, but will be
an affirmative indication of eligibility; if a customer does not prequalify its load, ComEd will
not need to include that load in the customer group for the fixed-price auction.
f. Commission Conclusion
ComEd has proposed to exclude customers with over 3 MW of demand from the CPP-A auction and to
provide hourly market service to those customers. IIEC and DOE have proposed to instead include
such customers in the CPP-A auction. However, IIEC and DOE have not shown that ComEd is required
to provide such a product to those customers. It appears that because the over 3 MW customer class
has been declared competitive, the Commission cannot require ComEd to provide such service. ComEd
has presented evidence that customers over 3 MW should be excluded from the CPP-A auction and
offered service under the hourly market. The Commission adopts ComEds proposal to offer hourly
service to customers having over 3 MW of demand.
4. Demand Charge Component for ³ 1MW Customers
IIEC recommended the isolation of a demand charge component for customers subject to the CPP-A
auction. IIEC claims that ComEds use of energy-only price will not fully recognize the benefits
of load factor in overall customer cost. IIEC proposes that ComEd isolate the capacity component
and charge it out on a per kW basis with the remainder of the auction price being charged on an
energy basis.
IIEC did not provide the details of its proposal. No other party submitted testimony
supporting IIECs proposal. The Commission declines to adopt IIECs proposal at this time, in view
of the lack of specificity and the absence of support from other parties.
J. Continuation of CPP-H Auction
1. ComEds Position
ComEd explains that the Illinois Auction design provides for ComEd to acquire supply for its
largest customers through the hourly CPP-H auction until the PJM Reliability Pricing Model (RPM)
or a functionally equivalent model is in place in PJM.
125
05-0159
Proposed Order
2. Staffs Position
Staff notes that IIEC recommended the Commission require ComEd to implement and maintain its
proposed CPP-H auction until such time as the proposed PJM RPMs centralized capacity market or the
equivalent is in operation and the Commission finds the PJM RPM centralized capacity market or its
equivalent is a reasonable approach for acquiring capacity for hourly pricing customers in
Illinois. Staff further notes that ComEd responded that the Company would maintain the CPP-H
auction until FERC approves the RPM and PJM puts a forward centralized capacity auction into
effect.
Subject to these limitations and clarifications, Staff concurs with IIEC recommendation for
ComEd to maintain its CPP-H auction until such time as the proposed PJM RPM centralized capacity
market or the equivalent is in operation and the Commission finds the PJM RPM centralized capacity
market or its equivalent is a reasonable approach for acquiring capacity for hourly pricing
customers in Illinois. Staff recommends that the Commission accept IIECs recommendation subject
to the limitations and clarifications that proffered during cross-examination.
3. IIECs Position
IIEC asserts that at this time, it is not clear what changes the FERC may make in the PJM RPM
proposal. Therefore, it is impossible for the ICC to determine whether the procurement of capacity
for hourly pricing customers through a centralized capacity market is a lower cost approach than
conducting ComEds proposed CPP-H auction. The Commission should require ComEd to implement and
maintain its proposed CPP-H auction until such time as the proposed PJM RPM centralized capacity
market is operational and ComEd demonstrates to the ICC that procurement through the centralized
capacity market approach is a just and reasonable approach for acquiring the capacity necessary to
serve hourly pricing customers.
If the PJM RPM is approved by the FERC in some form, under the filed rate doctrine ComEd will
have to conform to the requirements of the final PJM RPM requirements. However, if the final PJM
RPM provides more than one way to meet the PJM RPM requirements, ComEd will have a choice in regard
to how to meet the PJM RPM requirements for serving its hourly pricing customers. Under the Pike
County exception to the filed rate doctrine, the ICC has the authority to review the prudence of
ComEds choices.
IIEC argues that in the Pennsylvania Power Company case, the court found the utilitys
decision to enter into the sale and buy back agreement with another utility, though approved by the
FERC, was completely voluntary. Therefore, the court affirmed the public utility commissions
finding that the agreement to purchase the quantity of power at the FERC approved rate was
unreasonably excessive when lower cost power was readily available elsewhere.
126
05-0159
Proposed Order
IIEC further argues that the Illinois Supreme Court has acknowledged the doctrine of federal
preemption known as the filed rate doctrine, would not bar a consideration of the prudence of a
utility in its supply acquisition decision in appropriate circumstances; a State regulatory agency
could find that purchase of a particular quantity of power from a particular source was
unreasonable if lower cost power was available elsewhere, even if the cost of the purchased power
had been approved by FERC and therefore deemed reasonable. (General Motors Corporation v. Illinois
Com. Commn., 143 Ill 2d 407, 574 NE 2d 650, 658 (1991)).
IIEC asserts that the Commission is empowered to consider the prudence of ComEds supply
decisions in regard to its acquisition of capacity for the hourly product. There is no way for the
ICC at this time to know the final form of the PJM RPM. Therefore, ComEd should not be permitted
to deviate from the proposed CPP-H auction for hourly pricing customers until such time the PJM RPM
is operational and ComEd has made a showing that its proposed deviation from the CPP-H auction is
prudent to the extent other capacity supply options or approaches are available.
4. Commission Conclusion
ComEd indicates that it would continue to conduct the CPP-H auction until the PJM RPM or a
functionally equivalent model is in place in PJM. RPM had been filed with and approved by the
FERC, and the PJM forward centralized capacity auction was in effect. The Commission finds IIECs
suggestion that the Commission make a finding of reasonability regarding the RPM capacity market or
its equivalent to be appropriate. Thus, the Commission adopts IIECs request for an additional
requirement of Commission approval of the RPM capacity market or its equivalent at this time.
K. Contingencies
1. Volume Reduction
a. ComEds Position
ComEd notes that as discussed in Section V B(6), the Illinois Auction design provides for
volume reductions by the Auction Manager in the event that interest in the auction by suppliers is
not as high as expected. ComEd states that in this contingency, volume reductions serve as a
safety net to ensure that prices resulting from the auction are competitive. ComEd further states
that the Auction Manager will make an assessment of the competitiveness in the auction at the
indicative offer stage, and in the first round of the auction if the assessment indicates that
the level of interest from suppliers is not sufficient to provide assurances of a competitive
result, the Auction Manager can cut back the volume to be procured. ComEd believes that the volume
cutback means that a larger number of tranches bid will be chasing a smaller number of tranches of
available load, ensuring a more competitive bidding environment. ComEd has proposed a contingency
plan whereby in the event of a volume reduction any shortfall would be purchased at spot. This
will ensure that the auction is the only
127
05-0159
Proposed Order
opportunity to sell price-risk management services to ComEd and will encourage maximum
participation in the auction.
b. Staffs Position
Staff states that it does not oppose this contingency proposal, and agrees with ComEd that, in
a volume cutback scenario, purchasing power from the PJM spot market would be preferable to the
other alternatives. Staff suggests that this contingency be clarified so that in the event that
the Commission rejects the results of an auction, all of the tranches originally to be procured
through the rejected auction including any tranches not auctioned due to volume reductions -
should be handled pursuant to the rejection contingency provisions. Staff believes that if this
were not the case, the portion of ComEds load requirements separated from the auction due to the
volume reductions would be purchased using the supply options described in ComEds
undersubscription contingency plans, while the rest would be subject to the rejection contingency
provisions.
c. Commission Conclusion
The evidence shows that the proposed volume reduction contingency and the plan to purchase any
shortfall from the volume reduction at spot is reasonable and necessary. Accordingly, the
Commission approves this contingency, with the clarification that in the event the Commission
rejects the results of an auction, all of the tranches originally to be procured through the
rejected auction will be handled pursuant to the rejection contingency provisions.
2. Supplier Default
a. ComEds Position
ComEd notes that In the event that a supplier selected through the auction process defaults,
the process provides for replacement power to be procured in one of three ways through the PJM
markets, through an RFP-type solicitation process, or through another auction. ComEd states that
the method used would depend on the length of the remaining term of the affected contract and the
percentage of ComEds total retail load involved.
b. Staffs Position
Staff has no objection to the various plans for this contingency.
c. Commission Conclusion
The evidence shows that this contingency, including its three plans, is reasonable and
necessary. The Commission therefore approves it.
128
05-0159
Proposed Order
3. ICC Rejection
a. ComEds Position
ComEd notes that in the event that the Commission rejects the auction results, acquisition of
supply from the prevailing bidders would not proceed. ComEd further notes that a process involving
Staff, the Auction Manager, and ComEd would be initiated promptly to determine whether the reasons
for the rejection could be remedied by conducting another auction. ComEd states that if another
auction could not be conducted, a one-year interim procurement plan would be put in place until the
next annual auction with the approval of the Commission. ComEd states that any requirements needed
to meet customer needs prior to the time that an interim plan could be implemented would be
procured through PJM administered markets.
b. Staffs Position
Staff found ComEds proposal for addressing a Commission rejection of auction results to be
acceptable.
c. Commission Conclusion
The record shows that this multi-pronged proposal is reasonable and necessary. Accordingly,
the Commission approves it. Parties positions on the disputed issue of post-transaction prudency
reviews of contingency purchases are addressed elsewhere in this order.
L. Regulatory Oversight and Review
1. Nature and Timing of Prudency Reviews, including Contingency
Purchases
a. ComEds Position
With respect to the proposed auction process, ComEd argues, the time to determine prudence is
now, before the process has been implemented. The decisions about the overall approach and the
details of its execution should be considered in advance, when changes can be made to reflect the
Commissions judgment about how best to proceed. ComEd asserts that this proceeding offers the
ideal opportunity for the Commission to accomplish precisely what prudence review is intended to
provide a review of the decision that Illinois utilities are making about procurement of supply
for customers based on the facts that are available at the very time the decision must be made.
ComEd argues that the Commission has explained the nature and scope of its prudence review,
stating that the term prudent is defined as exercising good judgment
129
05-0159
Proposed Order
or common sense, and adopting the following standard for making prudence determinations in
Docket 84-0395:
Prudence is that standard of care which a reasonable person would be expected to
exercise under the same circumstances encountered by utility management at the time
decisions had to be made. In determining whether a judgment was prudently made,
only those facts available at the time judgment was exercised can be considered.
Hindsight review is impermissible.
Imprudence cannot be sustained by substituting ones judgment for that of another.
The prudence standard recognizes that reasonable persons can have honest differences
of opinion without one or the other necessarily being imprudent.
ComEd argues that a review of the prudence of the auction process should not take place after
the auction has occurred, for several reasons. First, hindsight review is impermissible in a
prudence review; any new facts that became available at that time would not be appropriate for
consideration. Second, the utility does not make any decisions during the course of the auction
that would subject it to review of the prudence of the auction process. Third, it would be too
late to implement any recommendations that the Commission concluded were meritorious. Finally, it
is essential from a commercial point of view to limit the post-auction review period to two days.
ComEd further argues that the record contains exhaustive reviews by other parties of ComEds
proposal, together with revisions to the proposal adopted by ComEd in response to suggestions that
have been made. It has the opportunity to consider each of the issues raised in this proceeding
concerning the process, as described in this brief, and to resolve any remaining disagreements
about the best approach to be followed. ComEd asserts that is the path the Commission should take,
and ComEd submits that it should determine that the Illinois Auction is a prudent and reasonable
method to acquire supply to serve customers needs.
ComEd notes that witnesses for the few parties opposing the Illinois Auction have essentially
conceded in testimony that the use of a vertical tranche auction to acquire supply for customers in
the wholesale market is not inherently imprudent.
ComEd states that opposing witness agreed that if ComEd procured power for its customers using
a competitive procurement process that the Commission determined was prudent and did not result in
any costs that were not entitled to be recovered under traditional ratemaking, ComEd would be
entitled to recover the resulting costs in its rates.
ComEd asks the Commission to review the detailed record describing the Illinois Auction
process and procedures and should determine that the process is a prudent
130
05-0159
Proposed Order
and reasonable means to acquire supply for customers. After reaching that determination, the
Commission should approve ComEds tariffs providing for the costs of the procurement to be
recovered from customers.
ComEd notes that in the event that replacement power must be procured as a result of a
suppliers default, ComEd will file a detailed report with the Commission concerning the default
and the actions that ComEd took to replace the power lost as a result of the default. In the event
that ComEds actions caused the supplier to default, those actions would be subject to a prudence
review and a determination whether any additional costs resulted from ComEds decisions.
ComEd further notes that if the Commission rejects the auction results and an interim supply
plan has to be implemented with Commission approval, the entire plan would be subject to review by
the Commission for prudence prior to its implementation.
ComEd states that it and Staff have reached a stipulation addressing the Commissions
oversight of purchases of replacement or additional power due to ComEds implementation of a
contingency plan, as is discussed elsewhere. ComEd further asserts that the stipulation, if
adopted, resolves all issues that have been raised by the Staff on this subject. It provides for
Commission review when review is appropriate and permissible under the Pike County exception to
FERCs exclusive jurisdiction over wholesale power transactions.
b. Staffs Position
Staff observes that as of the close of the hearings, ComEd and Staff were in agreement that
ComEds request for a prudence determination with respect to the contingency scenarios exempted or
excluded certain aspects or types of issues under those scenarios.
Staff notes that ComEd clarified that with respect to the contingency scenarios it is not
seeking a prudence determination where it will be taking future discretionary action, which may or
may not be prudent under applicable legal standards that could cause the need for such purchases or
impact the net amount to be charged to ratepayers for such purchases. With this understanding and
limitation, Staff supports the Companys request for a prudence determination for the alternative
procurement methods outlined in its contingency scenarios.
With respect to the potential contingency purchases at issue here, there are three general
aspects to a prudence determination. The first area of inquiry is whether the proposed purchases
themselves will result in prudently incurred reasonable costs. In other words, the first issue is
whether the prices to be paid pursuant to the contingency procurement methods should be
pre-approved as just and reasonable. Staff concurs with the Companys request that the Commission
find that the contingency purchases to be made through the PJM spot market, through a new auction
or through an RFP process, will result in prudently incurred reasonable costs for such supply.
131
05-0159
Proposed Order
Although Staff supports a prudence finding for the prices to be paid through these procurement
methods, there is one limitation that should be made clear. As discussed above, ComEds
contingency plan, in the event the Commission rejects the results of an auction, is to develop a
new supply plan to be brought to the Commission for approval. Obviously, it would be premature to
pre-approve the prudence of supply plans that have not been developed, including the prices that
would result from such unspecified plans, and ComEd agrees that it is not seeking a prudence
determination for that scenario in this proceeding.
A prudence inquiry for contingency purchases does not end with an examination of price
considerations. The second area of prudence inquiry is an analysis of the reasons for the
purchase. It is well established in Illinois jurisprudence that the prudency standard [is applied]
not only to the actual purchase amounts but [also] to the reasons for those purchases . . . .
(United Cities Gas Company v. Illinois Commerce Commn, 163 Ill. 2d 1, 17-18 (1994)) In other
words, if a utilitys imprudent acts or omissions cause certain costs to be incurred (i.e., the
reasons for the purchase), then those costs are not prudent notwithstanding the prudence of the
price paid or quantity purchased since the utility would not have incurred those particular costs
if its acts or omissions causing the need for the purchase had been prudent.
As is obvious from the contingency purchases description, the present analysis focuses on
how the Company will procure power in the event that certain future events develop and prevent it
from procuring power and energy through the SFCs resulting from annual auctions. Since those facts
will occur in the future, a full prudency determination cannot be made here, and the Commission
must retain the right to review the Companys prudence in light of the facts that do develop.
The third area of prudence inquiry with respect to the potential contingency purchases at
issue here is whether the Company has acted prudently with respect to the credit requirements.
Again, certain facts with respect to the Companys management of its credit requirements will not
be known until they occur in the future, and the Commission must maintain the ability to review
those facts when they occur.
Thus, while Staff supports ComEds contingency procurement proposals, Staff has concerns that
the Companys decisions or practices could lead to the need for additional or replacement power
purchases. As discussed in Section VII.B.5 of Staffs brief, Staff and ComEd have stipulated to an
agreement addressing Commission oversight of ComEds purchases of replacement or additional power
due to ComEds implementation of a contingency plan. Under this stipulation, the Commission could
determine whether the purchases were required because of an act or omission by ComEd, whether the
act or omission was imprudent, and, if so, whether the amount charged was unreasonable.
Staff fails to see how ComEds request for an upfront review rather than an after-the-fact
review avoids regulatory review. ComEds proposal fully articulates the criteria
132
05-0159
Proposed Order
and method by which ComEd will enter into contracts for wholesale power and energy to serve
its retail customers. ComEds proposal deprives neither parties nor the Commission of an
opportunity to assess ComEds decisions.
c. AGs Position
The AG argues that in asking the Commission to approve a process for obtaining market based
rates, ComEd is attempting to avoid the responsibility to charge consumers rates that can pass
regulatory review to insure they are fair, just and reasonable.
The AG further argues that the Commission must assess actual rates, whether they are presented
in a rate case under Part 285 (83 Ill. Adm. Code Part 285) and set prospectively, or presented in
the context of a retrospective review under section 9-220 of the PUA and subject to refund. (220
ILCS 5/9-220, 83 Ill. Adm. Code 425) The AG asserts that the PUA does not authorize the
pre-approval of blank rates under the guise of approving a process.
The AG continues arguing that the law requires that the rates consumers will actually pay be
included in tariff sheets on file with the Commission, so that the public can tell what rates the
utility is authorized to charge. (220 ILCS 5/9-103) Tariffs that do not contain the information
necessary to enable the Commission to review the rates and to protect consumers are unlawful.
(Citizens Utility Board v. Illinois Commerce Commission, 275 Ill.App.3d 329 (1st Dist 1995) (as
modified on rehearing))
The AG asserts that ComEds Rider CPP fails to specify the rates to be paid by consumers, and
like Rate CS, merely grants Edison the prospective right to set rates in the future. In this
docket ComEd proposes an unknown, future rate based on a process that has been used in only one
state. This request for authorization to set an unknown rate violates sections 9-102 and 9-201 of
the Public Utilities Act and is unlawful under Citizens Utility Board v. Illinois Commerce
Commission, supra.
The AG argues that ComEds proposal to restrict Commission review of replacement power
purchases leaves consumers with no protection when electricity is purchased outside the auction.
The AG argues that the PUA requires that the Commission review the rates ComEd charges
consumers either as part of a rate case under section 9-201, or as part of an annual reconciliation
docket examining the prudence of a uniform fuel adjustment clause charge.
The AG further argues that should the Commission adopt ComEds auction proposal, (which the AG
opposes), this language should be included to protect consumers when electricity is obtained
outside the auction.
133
05-0159
Proposed Order
According to the AG, the stipulation between ComEd and Staff does not protect consumers
interest in affordable service, and would leave substantial supply decisions unreviewed. It
contradicts Staffs testimony and should be rejected in favor of his rebuttal recommendation.
The AG objects to the stipulation on the grounds that it purports to limit Commission review
of non-auction purchases to whether the need for the purchases was imprudent. Only if the action
giving rise to the purchase is found imprudent could the Commission review the rates consumers will
be required to pay. Under the PUA, consumers are entitled to fair, just and reasonable, rates,
regardless of the reasons giving rise to the need to obtain service outside the auction.
The AG objects that the methods provided to obtain replacement supply are not so precise or
limited that all discretion and judgment are eliminated. For example, ComEd is to procure
under-subscribed power from PJM-administered markets. PJM-administered markets include real-time
and day-ahead markets as well as a larger market of transactions, such as for bilateral contracts,
with various types of products.
The AG asserts that the law prohibits a utility from imposing charges on consumers that have
not been filed and subject to regulatory review. (Citizens Utility Board v. Illinois Commerce
Commission, 275 Ill.App.3d 329 (1st Dist. 1995) (Rate CS)) Should ComEd choose to reinstitute its
UFAC, subsequent review of all purchases, including those from an auction, will be required. If
the Commission were to limit its review of the rates resulting from ComEds proposed auction,
subsequent review of non-auction purchases must be retained to provide the protection the law
requires.
The AG asserts that the Commission should refuse to provide the pre-approval the Company
seeks, and require the Company to use its best efforts, given the circumstances existing at the
time replacement electricity is needed, to obtain the least-cost supply for consumers. A
subsequent, annual review of such purchases is necessary, as required by Section 9-220 of the PUA,
to protect consumers and ensure that the utility acts reasonably. The AG further asserts that the
Commission must require the utility to use its best efforts to obtain least-cost electricity for
consumers regardless of the reason for needing replacement supply. The Commission should reject
the companys invitation to insulate it from accountability for the costs it will pass on to
consumers.
The AG argues that the law allows an alternative procedure for setting utility rates. Under
Section 9-220, the cost of purchased power can be passed through to consumers on a monthly basis,
and reconciled annually to insure that the correct amounts were charged. The annual reconciliation
provides the Commission and the public with the opportunity to ensure that the utility acted
prudently on behalf of its customers in incurring the costs that were passed on in rates. This
process protects consumers by allowing the review of purchasing decisions to make sure that they
were reasonable and prudent under the circumstances.
134
05-0159
Proposed Order
d. CUBs Position
CUB asserts that the auction proposals eliminate the ICCs obligation to perform an
after-the-fact prudence review of the resulting auction prices. The proposals further eliminate the
ICCs obligation to determine whether the rates are in fact just and reasonable. CUB argues that
this removes the only meaningful protections for consumers and subjects them to the substantial
risk of paying unreasonable and unjust rates, all of which is contrary to the Act.
CUB believes that ComEd does not share any risk that customers are not receiving fair market
pricing since its proposing that its cost of power be passed on to customers dollar for dollar.
Because of the lack of comparably priced market products, only an after-the-fact, traditional
ratemaking prudence review will detect whether the customer rates resulting from the auction prices
are just and reasonable. Such a prudence review is what ComEd wants to avoid.
CUB asserts that the ICC should not abdicate its responsibility to perform an after-the-fact
prudence review based on mere conjecture, disputed auction methods and ComEds distaste for
prudence reviews. CUB believes that customers should not lose their only true protection against
paying unjust and unreasonable prices, a risk that the customers only bear because ComEd intends to
recover every dollar it pays for the power from its customers.
CUB argues that an after the fact prudence review of ComEds conduct is mandatory even if the
auction is approved in other respects.
e. CCGs Position
CCG argues that parties who are suggestion a review at the end of the auction are missing the
point. CCG asserts that this proceeding is the vehicle within which to address prudence and it
will establish the process by which ComEd and all parties can be assured, in advance, that the
procurement practices are prudent. It is a contested case with notice and opportunity to be heard.
CCG notes that if the Commission approves the tariffs in the instant proceeding, it would be
approving the rules and the procedures under which ComEd will procure power and energy at the
wholesale market and would also approve the cost recovery to ComEd for those purchases.
CCG cites Illinois Commerce Commission vs. Illinois Power Company, Docket No. 01-0701 (Order
entered Feb. 19, 2004), wherein the Commission stated that the Commission has previously defined
prudence as the standard of care which a reasonable person would be expected to exercise under the
same circumstances by utility management at the time decisions had to be made.
CCG states that courts have also upheld the Commissions view of prudence. In Illinois
Commerce Commission vs. Illinois Power Company, 245 Ill. App. 3d 367 (3d Dist. 1993), the Court
stated, In determining whether a judgment was prudently made,
135
05-0159
Proposed Order
only those facts available at the time judgment was exercised can be considered. Hindsight
review is impermissible. (Id. at 371, quoting ICC Docket No. 88-0142 at 25-26 (Order entered Feb.
5, 1992))
According to CCG, prudence is the evaluation of circumstances surrounding the judgment of a
utility to make purchases at the time that the decision is made. The circumstances here would be
the Commission-approved mechanism and governing rules for the purchase of power and energy by
ComEd. The approved mechanism and rules would, therefore, be prudent and reasonable.
In order to eliminate the possibility of ambiguity as to the scope of the Commissions review
at the conclusion of the auction, CCG urges the Commission to define the scope of its post-auction
review as outlined above in its Order and to direct ComEd to modify its tariffs accordingly.
2. Accounting Reconciliation2
a. Staffs Position
In Section VII.B.9.c of its brief, Staff addresses its recommendation for annual docketed
accounting reconciliation proceedings to reconcile the cost of full requirements electric supply
purchased under Rider CPP with such revenues recorded. Staff also recommends that other
pass-through costs billed under Rider PPO-MVM and Rider TS-CPP be reconciled with revenues recorded
in annual docketed proceedings.
Staff states that ComEds objection to an annual public hearing is inconsistent with the
Procurement Working Groups first recommendation that a utilitys procurement process be highly
transparent. Staff believes the goal of transparency should be extended to annual proceedings to
reconcile ComEds cost to provide full requirements electric supply under Rider CPP with
recoveries.
Staff states that in the companion procurement dockets for the Ameren Companies, and
specifically with respect to Staffs proposal to establish Annual Reconciliation cases, Ameren
agreed that Staffs proposed Annual Reconciliation process seems reasonable with the focus being
the accuracy of accounting and to make sure that the MVAF reflects actual costs and the
reconciliation of revenues with the actual costs. Staff also argues that ComEd did not provide any
studies or documentation to support its belief that its customers would be best served without an
annual docketed proceeding to determine whether they were over charged or not.
Staff contends that it is not unusual for Staff and the utility company to be the only parties
in annual FAC and PGA reconciliations. Staff also argues that the existence of annual docket
reconciliations could have a positive impact on the accuracy of ComEds calculations. Staff
asserts that if one knows his work product is going to be reviewed then, one is more apt to take
care that it is correct and the same applies to
|
|
|
2 |
|
The accounting reconciliation discussion is placed in this section due to the inter-relationship of issues. |
136
05-0159
Proposed Order
ComEds process to issue bills and record revenues under the competitive procurement process.
In Staffs view, ComEds customers have a right to know that they are being charged the correct
rates and that ComEd should be required to demonstrate the correctness of those rates in annual
docket reconciliation proceedings.
According to Staff, annual docketed reconciliation proceedings would be the most efficient
means for determining expenses and revenues from the competitive procurement process. Staff states
that ComEds own accounting and reporting does not readily identify Rider CPP costs and Revenues.
Staff asserts that neither ComEd Exhibit 13.2 Revised, nor Form 21, ComEds annual report to
the Commission, provides the needed information for determining Rider CPP revenues and expenses
because the format and content of the report has not been determined. Staff contends that revenues
billed to customers in the aggregate do not provide revenues by class; nor does it provide revenues
from the full requirements customers or from those taking transmission services. Total revenues
does not provide the appropriate breakdown between Rider CPP revenues that are intended to recover
auction costs and base rate revenues which are intended to recover all other operating costs.
Thus, in Staffs view, the information provided by account in ComEds annual report will not
provide the detail because of the potential to commingle Rider CPP revenues with base rate revenues
in a single revenue account.
Staff recommends that the Commission order ComEd to modify its pass through cost riders
including Rider CPP, Rider PPO-MVM and Rider TS-CPP to provide for annual docketed reconciliation
proceedings. Staff does not believe such a requirement will be overly burdensome to ComEd.
b. ComEds Position
ComEd recommends that the Commission reject Staffs revised proposal for annual docketed
accounting reconciliation proceedings under Rider CPP, Rider PPO-MVM, and Rider TS-CPP.
ComEd states that if Staff, another interested party, or the Commission itself were to
identify a valid basis for conducting a formal proceeding to investigate the reconciliation of
costs and recoveries, and of whether the correct costs were included when calculating Supply
Charges or AAFs, then Rider CPP would permit the Commission to do so, as reflected in Staffs and
ComEds final revised proposal regarding review of Supply Charges and AAFs.
ComEd does not believe, however, that any valid basis has been shown for conducting annual
docketed reconciliation proceedings. According to ComEd, the evidence instead shows that such
automatic proceedings are not warranted and would impose unnecessary burdens on stakeholders,
ComEd, Staff, and the Commission.
137
05-0159
Proposed Order
ComEd also complains that Staffs proposed expansion of its proposal to Rider PPO-MVM and
Rider TS-CPP does not make sense. According to ComEd, all of the costs that Staff proposes to
reconcile in Rider PPO-MVM are costs calculated in determining the Supply Charges in Rider CPP that
are incorporated in Rider PPO-MVM. ComEd claims Staffs proposal is unwarranted as to the proven
approach adopted in Rider TS-CPP.
ComEd says the only contested issue here, as to Rider CPP and Rider PPO MVM, is whether, as
ComEd proposes, the Commission should initiate reconciliation proceedings when needed, with that
need determined by the Commission; or, as Staff proposes, the Commission should automatically
initiate annual docketed reconciliation proceedings.
ComEd claims it is willing to work with Staff to make sure Staff gets the information it
needs. ComEd contends that Staff cites no law or evidence that ComEd could, much less would,
thwart any Staff request for appropriate information. Additionally, ComEd claims Staff cites no
law or evidence for the notion that, if ComEd did so, that Staff could not at any point in the six
months file a report with the Commission, document the problem, and on that and/or any other
appropriate basis ask the Commission to initiate an investigation. ComEd states that Staff, in
rebuttal testimony, had the opportunity, but did not respond to ComEds proposal for a Staff
report.
ComEd states that with regard to Amerens agreement to automatic annual docketed
reconciliation proceedings in ICC Docket No. 05-0160, et al. Staff does not discuss, much less
provide evidence, regarding whether Ameren proposed or agreed to all of the other items that ComEd
proposed and accepted in this proceeding. In any event, ComEd says Staffs citation is not
evidence that such proceedings make sense given the facts here.
According to ComEd, Staffs contends that the absence of intervenor objection to ComEds
proposal, and the absence of intervenor support for Staffs proposal, does not mean that Staffs
proposal should be rejected. ComEd claims the silence speaks for itself. That is, intervenors have
expressed no objection to ComEds proposal and no support for Staffs proposal).
ComEd complains that Staff cites no evidence for the assertion that facing automatic annual
docketed reconciliation proceedings could have a positive impact on the accuracy of ComEds
calculations. ComEd says it has every intention and reason to accurately calculate the Supply
Charges and AAFs.
ComEd takes issue with Staffs proposition that it somehow is efficient to have automatic
annual docketed reconciliation proceedings. ComEd argues that with all of the reports and other
information that will be available to Staff, and with Staff having the ability to obtain the
additional appropriate information it needs, it is not reasonable to reject an approach in which an
investigation would be initiated only if there actually
138
05-0159
Proposed Order
appears to be a reason to conduct one. ComEd says Staffs complaint here, that the format and
content of the annual reports has not been finalized and that the reports will or might be
inadequate, has no basis.
It is ComEds position that Staffs proposal for automatic annual docketed reconciliation
proceedings lacks merit as to Rider CPP, Rider PPO-MVM, and Rider TS-CPP, and should not be
approved. (ComEd brief at 163, reply brief at 133)
c. AGs Position
The AG addresses Staffs recommendation for annual docketed accounting reconciliation
proceedings showing the costs and revenues collected pursuant to the variable rider.
According to the AG, ComEds proposal includes a variable pass-through of generation costs as
well as an accuracy assurance factor to insure that changes in demand do not affect its
collection of generation costs. If ComEds proposed auction process is allowed, the annual amounts
collected from ratepayers are accurately accounted for.
3. Three-day Post-Auction Commission Review of Results
a. ComEds Position
Under ComEds proposal, as in New Jersey, the Commission will conduct an immediate review of
the auction and will determine whether to accept the results or commence an investigation.
While ComEd understands the position of parties opposed to the immediate review, it continues
to believe that the Commission should not be constrained by a prescriptive standard. ComEds
tariffs provide an appropriate period for action and the scope of the Commissions consideration
should be governed by the facts and the law, not by pre-approved language that requires the
Commission to anticipate and define how it will proceed.
b. Staffs Position
The Staff recommends that the Commission reject CCGs and MSCGs arguments. Staff never
conceded that ComEds rider needed further direction in terms of the Commissions options to
review the auctions result as MSCG argues in its brief.
Second, there would be a significant disadvantage to accepting CCGs and MSCGs general
position that the Commission should limit its scope of review so that it is more defined. Staff
states that there are also pre-auction activities as well as external events that also should be
examined to gauge whether the auction results should be
139
05-0159
Proposed Order
accepted or rejected. In order for the Commission to have the flexibility that is necessary
to address the unknown, CCGs and MSCGs arguments should be rejected.
c. AGs Position
The AG claims that the proposed post-auction review is too rushed and limited to provide
customers with sufficient protection against unfair, unjust or unreasonable rates. The AG believes
that this is an extraordinarily short time to make such major decisions.
The AG notes that the three-day review period is made more burdensome and restrictive given
the magnitude of the procurement in the first auction and the lack of alternatives being offered by
the Company. The failure to provide a more comprehensive and diversified procurement method leaves
consumers exposed to unknown risks and uncertainties should the auction results be rejected. The
AG asserts that the post-auction review cannot be expected to provide protection for consumers
because the risks resulting from rejection are substantial.
The AG argues that given the fact that the review window is so small, the Commission could not
do much other than identify the grossest errors or issues. However, the Commission should not
limit the scope of its review or restrict its ability to respond to unforeseen or anomalous
circumstances.
The AG urges the Commission to reject MSCGs attempt to obtain absolute certainty at the
expense of ratepayers. Despite the fact that the review contained in ComEds proposal is
insufficient to allow a thorough review of either the process or the result, the slight delay in
certifying the results of the auction should not be seen as a major obstacle to bidder
participation. If it were a major obstacle, the state of the market would not support a
competitive auction taking place several months before the delivery of power, and including
contracts covering periods from one year to five years. The volatility MSCGs position implies,
where a several-day review period would discourage a bidder from participating, would if true,
render the proposed auction an unacceptable process.
d. CUBs Position
CUB notes that the after auction report merely provides a factual summary of the activities
and events that occurred during the course of the auction, the resulting prices and the managers
affirmation that the auction rules apparently were followed. CUB further notes that absent from the
report or from any other source is an after-the-fact analysis whether the prices resulting from the
auction are fair, reasonable or were prudently incurred by ComEd.
CUB asserts that the ICC, with no analysis of whether the resulting rates are in fact
reasonable, has only three business days from the close of the auction to accept the results. It
can reject the results only if there is unambiguous evidence that the auction process was not
followed.
140
05-0159
Proposed Order
CUB argues that ComEds testimony alone raises serious doubts about the reasonableness of such
a procedure. CUB notes that there will be no benchmarks to determine the reasonableness of the
auction clearing prices for the given products, because the products being auctioned are a fairly
specialized product and not the usual blocks of power traded in the electric market generally. CUB
argues that the absence of comparably priced products in the market leaves it virtually impossible
to determine in real time or immediately thereafter whether the ending auction prices are in fact
reasonable.
In CUBs view, the proposed process does not satisfy the requirement for an after-the-fact
prudency review, as summarized elsewhere in this order.
e. CCSAOs Position
CCSAO argues that no meaningful review to ensure compliance with Illinois law can be done in
three days to ensure that rates are just and reasonable. Additionally, three days is insufficient
to ensure that all other applicable laws and rules were complied with. CCSAO believes it would be
impossible to file a complaint under the Public Utilities Act to challenge an auction results
without access to the full range of information the Commission has in its possession.
Further, according to CCSAO, any review by the Commission in just three days would be very
superficial by its nature.
f. CCGs Position
Regarding the post-auction Commission review of results, CCG suggests that the Commission
consider adopting a post-auction review similar to the one adopted by the New Jersey BPU. By
defining the scope of the post-auction review so that it focuses on ensuring that the Commissions
approved auction process is followed and that no anomalies were found in the bids or process that
would call into question the competitiveness of the bids received, the potential bidders would
have confidence that the auction will result in executed SFCs. According to CCG, this type of
certainty would encourage suppliers to participate in the bidding process resulting in benefits to
consumers.
Therefore, CCG continues to urge the Commission to adopt a scope for its post-auction review
that is similar to that adopted by the New Jersey Board of Public Utilities. CCG believes that the
New Jersey BPU indicated that its review of the auction results focused on the mechanical elements
of the auction and on whether there was evidence of collusion, gaming or market anomalies.
141
05-0159
Proposed Order
g. MSCGs Position
MSGC argues that the Commission should affirm that it will institute an investigation or
otherwise reject and re-run the auction results only if the competitiveness of the auction is
believed to have been compromised.
More specifically, MSCG recommends that ComEd include in all applicable riders, including
Rider CPP and CPP-H, and at the beginning of the second paragraph of Sheet No. 269, immediately
before the phrase beginning with In the event that, the following clarifying language: The
ICC will take formal action regarding the auction results as described herein only if the conduct
or competitiveness of the Auction or outside events are believed to have compromised the Auction
process.
Without inclusion of MSCGs requested clarifying language the Commissions review could be
interpreted incorrectly as open-ended and undefined, thereby introducing prohibitively expensive
and unnecessary risk and uncertainty to the pre-bid and bidding processes, to the detriment of
Illinois consumers. If the Commission reserves a very broad post-auction flexibility for rejecting
an auctions results, bidders and winning suppliers will face uncertainty regarding the auction
results. Proposed original sheet Nos. 268 and 269 (Exhibit 7.1) do not yet indicate explicitly
that the Post Auction Reports and the Commissions analysis of whether to investigate the auction
results will focus only on whether the competitiveness of the auction has been compromised. ComEd,
however, believes the Commission should focus only on such issues.
MSCG argues that if the Commissions review criteria is not clarified, bidders face an
unsettling risk that an auction run competitively and fairly and resulting in an auction clearing
price closing below the auction starting price, may nevertheless be subject to a formal
investigation because the resulting price might be deemed too high in hindsight based on an
internal price benchmark (or formula or index), or other price or non-price related criteria that
were not revealed to bidders prior to the auction.
MSCG further argues that failure to inform bidders prior to the auction regarding how the
auction results will be evaluated and whether some other benchmark might be applied to judge the
price results even if a successfully cleared auction is deemed competitive would create an
untenable lack of transparency in the process. MSCG asserts that bidders must have all relevant
information set in the auction rules prior to the auction, especially with respect to how the
auction results will be judged, so that bidders may rely on that information in their calculations
and provide the lowest possible economic bid.
MSCG further argues that if an investigation is conducted by the Commission even when the
auction is deemed competitive and clears under the auction starting price, suppliers also will not
have the security of signed SFCs. When formulating bids, suppliers will face not only the risk
that the acceptance of bids may be delayed even if the auction was competitive but also an extended
risk until the Commission makes its
142
05-0159
Proposed Order
decision regarding the bids that were received and cleared below the auction starting price.
According to MSCG, bidders may include a risk premium to account for the risk present in an
open-ended review process, which may result in higher offer prices.
MSCG argues that the Commission should require more specific language in the rider and
auction rules limiting the acceptable reasons for rejecting auction results only to instances when
the competitiveness of the auction is believed to be compromised for example, through bidder
wrongdoing or material auction implementation flaws.
MSCG asserts that clarifying the rider language to focus the Commissions ability to institute
an investigation of the auction results also addresses another significant risk. Bidders face risk
if they do not have all necessary information to formulate bids, including any price benchmark or
formula the Commission might apply internally to judge a competitive, successfully cleared auction.
MSCG lastly asserts that the primary purpose of the Commissions review is not to compare the
auction clearing prices to some arbitrary benchmark value but instead to review the various
reports to assure that all criteria for a competitive result were met. Thus, according to MSCG,
the level of the auction clearing price alone, without a reasonable belief that the competitiveness
of the auction has been compromised, cannot be grounds to reject the auction results.
h. Dynegys Position
Dynegy agrees with the parties who have argued for a relatively short, post-auction review
period by the Commission, one that is limited in scope as well as duration. As a prospective
bidder in the auction, Dynegy wishes to emphasize that it is essential from a commercial point of
view to limit the post-auction review period to two days.
Dynegy asserts that any delay or uncertainty in the post-action review process will lead to
higher auction-clearing prices because Suppliers will include a risk premium to cover the risk
inherent in delay and uncertainty. Particularly harmful would be a full-blown review of the prices
that obtain from the auction, in the guise of a prudence review or otherwise. In such a case,
the Commission could well be creating a vicious feedback loop that will only drive prices up. On
the other hand, by focusing on whether the rules for the auction process were followed and whether
any anomalies arose, the Commission will send the proper signal and help ensure that prices that
result from the auction do not include unnecessary risk premiums.
143
05-0159
Proposed Order
i. Commission Conclusion
Previously, in Section III.E., the Commission stated its conclusions regarding prudency
reviews. The parties positions as summarized here were considered in reaching those conclusions.
As explained above, Constellation Energy Commodities Group urges the Commission to clarify the
scope of the post-auction review so that it focuses on ensuring that the Commissions approved
auction process is followed and that no anomalies were found in the bids or process that would
call into question the competitiveness of the bids received. That way, CCG reasons, the potential
bidders would have confidence that the auction will result in executed SFCs.
Similarly, Morgan Stanley Capital Group believes the tariffs should provide, The ICC will
take formal action regarding the auction results as described herein only if the conduct or
competitiveness of the Auction or outside events are believed to have compromised the Auction
process. Without this clarification, MSCG contends, bidders face risk that may be reflected in
higher offer prices.
ComEd, Staff and the AG disagree with those recommendations. ComEd argues in part that the
Commission should not be constrained by the prescriptive standards advanced by CCG and MSCG. In
Staffs view, CCGs and MSCGs arguments should be rejected so that the Commission will have the
flexibility that is necessary to address the unknown. The AG believes the Commission should not
limit its ability to respond to unforeseen or anomalous circumstances.
Having reviewed the positions of the parties, the Commission concludes that the language
proposed by CCG and MSCG should not be adopted. While the review should focus on the issues cited
by those parties, the Commission agrees with other parties that the restrictiveness of the language
would deprive the Commission of needed flexibility. Furthermore, the brevity of the Commissions
review period, consisting of three working days, should help alleviate the alleged risks, and MSCG
offered no prepared testimony to the contrary.
4. Workshops and Proceedings to Consider the Process
a. ComEds Position
ComEd proposes that after each auction, a well-designed post-auction workshop process will
take place, enabling parties to assess the need for improvements and any response to address
lessons learned from the process.
Regarding formal proceedings, the ComEd proposal calls for a formal proceeding to be conducted
once every three years to review the procurement experiences during a multi-year period,
determining whether changes in the process or details of the approach should be considered.
144
05-0159
Proposed Order
ComEd believes that annual proceedings are unnecessary because the ComEd auction proposal
already incorporates all of the post-auction review that is required or desirable. ComEd notes
that the Commission will conduct an immediate review of the auction results; post auction workshops
will take place to explore possible improvements to the process; and formal proceedings will be
initiated every three years.
ComEd states that in addition to the specific review proceedings and workshops to consider
auction issues, the Commission will retain its powers to initiate whatever investigations or
proceedings it sees fit under the provisions of the Public Utilities Act.
ComEd continues to disagree with the IIEC proposal for annual formal proceedings to consider
the process.
b. Staffs Position
Staff has no objection to ComEds recommendation to hold informal workshops after the
conclusion of the auction, rather than open annual proceedings. The workshops, under ComEds
proposal, would be sponsored by the Commission, and led by Staff, which should alleviate any
concern that any party who wishes to comment on the conduct (and the results) of the auction would
not have an opportunity to be heard in an open forum. While Staff understands that any tariff
proposals that result from the workshops would likely be initiated by ComEd, rather than
intervenors, parties would retain their rights to petition the Commission to open proceedings for
the purpose of examining ComEds tariffs, or, in fact, for the purpose of evaluating the auction
process itself. Moreover, under ComEds proposal, such proceedings would automatically be opened
by the Commission every three years.
Staff notes that in addition, parties would be able to petition the Commission to open
proceedings to examine the auction process and such proceedings would be automatically opened every
three years. In the Ameren Dockets (ICC Docket Nos. 05-0160/05-0161/05-0162 Consolidated), IIEC and
Ameren reached an agreement on this issue, which Staff opposed.
c. AGs Position
The AG argues that if the Commission accepts ComEds auction proposal, the IIEC initial brief
presents a compelling argument for mandating an annual docketed review of the auction. The AG
notes that contrary to the Companys claim that its proposal is tried and true, its proposal is
new and unique. The AG further notes that it is being proposed to replace and determine the prices
for electricity for which Illinois consumers now pay $3.5 billion. The AG recommends that the
Commission reserve the right to a regular and a rigorous review of ComEds procurement process and
not consider this docket an irrevocable commitment to an unproven procurement strategy.
145
05-0159
Proposed Order
The AG avers that in this docket, ComEd and other parties have used the Post-2006 Initiative
workshop process to marginalize and discredit parties who oppose the companys proposal. As IIEC
correctly noted, the People of the State of Illinois would be wary of another workshop process
where the parties attempt to resolve issues without the structure of a docketed case or a
rulemaking and where the proponents of a process or method take the lead in setting the agenda and
determining the outcome. The AG argues that the informality of a workshop does not lend itself to
the examination of something as crucial to the State as a $3.5 billion purchase of electric supply.
d. IIECs Position
IIEC argues that the focus of the discussion is the nature of the Commissions commitment to
and evaluation of the auction process. IIEC argues that the Commission should not commit itself
and consumers irrevocably to a barely tested procurement process and there should be a formal
process to review the successes and failures of that process and its various components.
IIEC submits that given the novelty of an auction process in Illinois unique environment and
the determinative ratemaking effect of the auction results requires a formal review process each
year.
IIEC asserts that a docketed proceeding, held before each auction, would afford opportunities
for ratepayer participation like those in other ratemaking proceedings. Each such proceeding would
determine whether an auction should be authorized for another annual period; consider all aspects
of the pre-approved procurement process, including such fundamental issues as the advisability of
continued reliance on an auction, the structure of the auction, and automatic translation of
auction results; and assure a timely Commission order on changes and continuation of the auction.
IIEC further asserts that the reasons for the alternative review process proposed by IIEC are
basic and well supported in the evidentiary record. First, there is the novelty of the process.
IIEC states that while ComEd characterizes the auction proposal as a proven technique and tried
and tested process, there have only been five such auctions for electricity. In addition, the
circumstances that prevailed during the auctions in New Jersey, a state in which most of those
auctions were held, are not necessarily constant or common to other states. There is no proof of
how the process will operate in Illinois different environment or in unfavorable market
circumstances. IIEC further notes that the New Jersey Board of Public Utilities (NJBPU) requires
annual proceedings, even after several years experience with the auction process.
IIEC argues that there is little reason for Illinois to commit itself to an auction mechanism,
which is untried in Illinois, more firmly than New Jersey has seen fit to do. IIEC further argues
that the Commission should not irrevocably enter into a novel process which has not been tested for
any extended period, not tested at all in Illinois, and never challenged by unfavorable
circumstances or the market concentration
146
05-0159
Proposed Order
concerns that exist in Illinois. An annual review of the need for, structure of, and
operation of the auction/ratemaking process is a reasonable course.
IIEC believes that workshops alone are unlikely to be adequate to that critical task. In
addition, workshop processes, which are not covered by the Commissions rules of practice, do not
assure that either participants or the Commission will have access to all relevant information and
ComEds proposal would apparently allow a third party to determine the need for a formal review by
the Commission in a fashion that excludes the input of customers.
The regular formal reviews proposed by IIEC are such a mechanism. With a requirement for
annual formal proceedings, the Commission and consumers can be assured that any design defects,
operational difficulties, or fundamental miscalculations will be quickly identified and addressed
in a timely manner by the Commission. ComEd suggests that needed changes can be made in 45-day
tariff filings. But absent a proceeding that yields a record to support a Commission order for
such a filing, only ComEd can choose to file such tariffs incorporating changes proposed by others.
IIEC argues that given these facts, the Illinois Commission should not as the ComEd proposal
essentially requires commit itself to the auction process without a prescribed, well-defined,
formal process to review the successes or problems of auction procurement.
e. CES Position
CES states that the issue of what products should be offered to which customers should be a
topic for thoughtful consideration by the Commission in the annual post-auction collaborative
effort, along with other issues. CES notes that the Commission has been well served by its ability
to respond to various market developments, and it should continue to evaluate the products,
customer class demarcations, and other important tariff terms and conditions to look for further
opportunities to promote the development of the competitive retail electric market in Illinois.
f. DES/USESCs Position
DES/USESC asserts that the Commission should articulate its vision for the achievement in
Illinois of a robust and fully competitive retail electric marketplace and should actively seek out
opportunities to promote fair and open competition in the provision of electric power and energy.
DES/USESC further asserts that the Commission must keep in mind that the end of this initial
transition period is only the beginning step in establishing a competitive retail electricity
market. DES/USESC recommends that the Commission needs to be mindful that nothing it implements in
this proceeding unnecessarily delays the day when all consumers will benefit from a competitive
retail electricity market.
147
05-0159
Proposed Order
DES/USESC recommends that the Commission could advance retail electric competition by
launching a Customer Choice initiative in the form of ongoing collaboratives that the Commission
could use to identify and eliminate barriers to the implementation of a competitive retail
electricity market for all customers. At the Commissions direction, Staff would work with all
interested parties to further develop the next steps necessary to advance competition in the
electric industry in Illinois. The Commission should direct Staff to report back specific
recommendations by December 31, 2006, with additional collaboratives resulting in specific
recommendations every 24 months.
DES/USESC also recommends that the Commission initiate an investigation to determine how
advanced metering technology could be deployed more widely so that all customers in Illinois can
readily obtain the benefits of real-time pricing and demand response programs. DES/USESC believes
that such an investigation would allow the Commission to collect additional data to develop and
implement retail rates that better reflect the true cost of producing electricity.
g. CCGs Position
CCG notes that the Commissions authority under the PUA to examine the auction process by
initiating a proceeding or by other mechanism permitted by law for the purpose of improving the
auction process for future auctions is not diminished, and the parties would continue to have the
option of petitioning the Commission.
h. Dynegys Position
Dynegy acknowledges that many different proposals have been advanced in terms of the process
the Commission should use for determining whether improvements can be made to subsequent
procurements by ComEd. Dynegy believes that annual workshops punctuated by formal triennial
proceedings (with no party forestalled from filing a formal proceeding more frequently if it
believes such is warranted) best balances (a) the need for some stability between auctions and the
need to determine if patterns have arisen over the course of several auctions with (b) the need to
ensure formal consideration (with the attendant rules for discovery and evidence) occurs
periodically.
i. Commission Conclusion
Having reviewed the recommendations of the parties, the Commission agrees with IIEC that a
docketed review of the auction process should be conducted on a periodic basis. Given the
significance of the auction process and the fact that it is untried in Illinois, a formal review of
it should not be delayed for three years. Further, as IIEC points out, New Jersey, the state with
several years of auction experience, conducts an annual review to evaluate the process.
148
05-0159
Proposed Order
The Commission finds that IIECs alternative review schedule should be adopted, whereby a
formal review will be conducted after the first two auctions, and every other two year after that.
M. Supplier Forward Contracts
1. Uniformity in General
a. ComEds Position
ComEd proposed the use of a uniform supply contract to eliminate negotiations over non-price
terms and to permit supplier offers to be compared directly on the basis of price. ComEd states
that the use of a standard contract enables bidders to become familiar with the details of the
transaction well in advance of the conduct of the auction and provides them with an opportunity to
resolve any questions or uncertainties before the process begins. According to ComEd, this will
help to eliminating uncertainties which would be reflected by a premium in bidders bids. In
addition, ComEd maintains that having all bidders addressing identical terms and conditions
enhances the competitiveness of the auction and provides the best means to achieve the lowest
expected market price for the products procured under this proposal for customers.
ComEd notes that the proposed Supplier Forward Contracts were largely modeled on the form of
agreement used with suppliers in the New Jersey Basic Generation Service auction. The initial
changes made to the provisions used in New Jersey were, ComEd states, mostly due to the differences
between New Jersey and Illinois restructuring rules. ComEd notes that in order to ensure that
potential suppliers had an opportunity to comment on and suggest changes to the agreement, ComEd
held public meetings with potential suppliers, solicited suggestions and incorporated numerous
modifications to address issues that were raised.
ComEd further suggested that, in the event that possible additional areas of uniformity can be
achieved, the Commission direct Staff, ComEd, and Ameren to meet to make a compliance filing
incorporating the revised agreements within 30 days of the entry of a final order.
ComEd opposes an additional period following the final order, during which suppliers could
provide additional input. ComEd maintains that all suppliers had the opportunity to participate in
previous input periods during which ComEd undertook to gather feedback on the contracts.
b. Staffs Position
As part of its filing in this proceeding, ComEd submitted model proposed supplier forward
contracts (SFCs). Ameren also proposed its own SFCs in its procurement proceeding, Docket Nos.
05-0160/05-0161/05-0162 Consolidated, (Ameren proceeding). Staff states that as originally
proposed both contracts differed in many
149
05-0159
Proposed Order
ways and, as a result, would increase bidder costs in reviewing and complying with the
contracts and would reduce competition in each auction.
Staff notes that ComEd has worked with Ameren to achieve uniformity on all the aspects of the
SFCs to the extent possible and proposed an amended contract. Staff recommends that the compliance
filing due date be changed to within sixty (60) days of the posting of the draft contract on the
auction web site, which should occur within (7) days of the entry of the final order in this
proceeding. Staff further recommends that the Commissions Order set forth additional details
regarding the process for the compliance filing, such as identifying unresolved issues and
directing ComEd, Ameren and the Auction Manager to file a petition with the Commission to resolve
any open issues within 21 days of the compliance filing, with notice of such filing to the service
list in Docket No. 05-0159.
Staff continues to recommend a 60-day compliance filing for finalizing the SFCs. Staff argues
that to remove suppliers from the process in the final stage is inappropriate and unreasonable. A
60-day compliance filing would allow bidders time to provide comments regarding finalizing the SFCs
and would also allow ComEd, Ameren, Staff and the Auction Manager time to consider, respond to and,
if necessary, incorporate such comments into the final SFCs.
c. Dynegys Position
Dynegy asserts that the SFC will constitute one of the most important operative legal
documents between the Supplier and ComEd. Dynegy argues that making sure the provisions are set
appropriately is important because properly designed SFCs can encourage participation by more
potential suppliers and offer the possibility of lower auction-clearing prices, which would
directly translate into lower retail prices.
Dynegy asserts that the SFCs proposed by ComEd (even as refined over the course of this
proceeding) do not strike the proper balance. Dynegy has provided a complete revision to the CPP-B
SFC as DYN Ex. 1.1. Dynegy urges the Commission to adopt that version as a part of this proceeding
and conforming changes made to the other CPP SFCs. (Ibid)
Dynegy argues that the Commission may clearly detail the final terms and conditions to be
incorporated into the SFCs as a part of its final Order in this proceeding. If that occurs, little
more than a compliance check by Staff will be needed in terms of reviewing the final ComEd SFCs.
If, however, there is any room for substantive language to be altered prior to the finalizing of
the SFCs, then Dynegy urges that Suppliers be permitted to take part in the negotiation and
crafting of those provisions.
Dynegy notes that because the auctions will be conducted at the same time with switching
permitted between like products offered by ComEd and Ameren, uniformity between the contracts is
all the more important. Removing sources of possible
150
05-0159
Proposed Order
difference between the two utilities offerings will aid potential Suppliers by simplifying the
information they must learn and then use to develop their bidding strategies. No party appears to
disagree that the goal of uniformity is appropriate, with due recognition that there will need to
be some differences due to such items as the different RTOs to which ComEd and the Ameren Utilities
belong.
d. Commission Conclusion
ComEd has proposed to utilize uniform supply contracts based on those used in the New Jersey
auction. ComEd has also worked with Ameren to achieve as much uniformity as possible between the
ComEd and Ameren SFCs. ComEd has adopted various changes to the supply contracts it is proposing
based on various comments of parties in this proceeding as well as based on public meetings with
potential suppliers who would be subject to the contracts. ComEd has shown that its uniform supply
contracts are appropriate. Staffs proposal to allow for a 60 day period for a compliance filing
to allow for additional supplier input is necessary. The Commission finds that ComEds proposed
uniform supply contracts, as modified by Staffs compliance filing proposal, are reasonable and are
therefore adopted.
2. Credit Requirements
a. ComEds Position
ComEd notes that adequate supplier credit requirements are important because they serve to
protect customers from the costs and risks of supplier default, particularly at times when the
market price increases after the contract is executed, and the contract price becomes lower than
the market price. Under the Supplier Forward Contracts, Suppliers can qualify for unsecured credit
lines based on their own credit ratings and balance sheet strength or those of a guarantor. In
addition, suppliers are required to post collateral for any exposure amounts in excess of their
unsecured credit lines. ComEd states that because energy prices change from time to time, the
exposure amount is determined through a mark-to-market mechanism designed to capture the effect of
energy price fluctuations on the incremental cost of replacement supply.
The New Jersey supplier agreement also includes base credit requirements, and ComEd initially
incorporated that feature in the draft contract discussed with suppliers. However, concerns were
raised that the base credit requirements were too onerous, particularly for non-investment grade
suppliers, and would discourage participation in the auction. Faced with these concerns and the
prospect that a more competitive price with adequate customer protections could be achieved if the
base credit requirement were eliminated, ComEd agreed to dispense with the base requirement
feature.
In response to Staffs opposition to the provision regarding ComEds unilateral power to
change the credit requirements, ComEd proposed eliminating the provision.
151
05-0159
Proposed Order
b. Staffs Position
Staff notes that Article 6 of ComEds proposed SFCs describes the credit requirements. Staff
makes three recommendations regarding ComEds proposed credit requirements: (1) the level of
ComEds proposed credit requirements should be approved; (2) ComEd should eliminate the provision
to notch down issuer credit ratings by Moodys Investors Service; and (3) there should be a
reporting requirement for ComEd in connection with the credit provision that allows ComEd to
unilaterally reduce its credit requirements. Staff states that the only remaining contested issue
relates to the credit provision that allows ComEd to unilaterally reduce its credit requirements,
as described hereafter.
Staff recommends acceptance of the credit requirements provided in Article 6 of ComEds SFCs.
Staff does not object to ComEds proposed credit requirements differing from those proposed in the
Ameren proceeding. Staff recommends eliminating the credit provision in ComEds proposed SFCs that
requires notching down the corporate issuer credit rating from Moodys Investors Service
(Moodys) because Moodys issuer ratings are already equivalent to unsecured credit ratings.
Staff states that ComEd agreed to modify its SFCs to eliminate notching Moodys issuer credit
ratings by revising its proposed SFCs to read as follows:
In the event that senior unsecured debt ratings are unavailable from [Standard &
Poors] and Fitch, the corporate issuer rating, discounted by one notch will be
used. In the event that senior unsecured debt ratings, or their equivalent, are
unavailable from Moodys, the lowest secured debt rating, discounted by one notch,
will be used.
Staff notes that Section 6.1 of ComEds proposed SFCs initially allowed the Company to
unilaterally reduce its credit requirements, which provided ComEd the flexibility to respond to an
industry event, or unanticipated conditions in the wholesale marketplace. Staff recommends that
should ComEd change the SFC credit requirements, it should file within 15 days of the changes in
credit requirements a report with the Manager of the Commissions Finance Department and the Chief
Clerk that identifies the effective date, explains the reason for the change and summarizes any
facts and analyses on which the decision to change the credit requirements was based. Staff also
recommends ComEd clarify whether the SFCs permit ComEd to restore the credit requirements to their
initial level as circumstances permit.
In response to Staffs proposed reporting requirement, ComEd proposed eliminating the credit
provision from Section 6.1 of the SFCs that allows the Company to unilaterally reduce its credit
requirements. Staff found ComEds argument for including this credit provision convincing and
believes that the flexibility provided by this credit provision could potentially benefit both
customers and suppliers. Moreover, according to Staff, ComEd has not provided any details regarding
its proposal to confer with the Commission or Staff before reducing the credit requirements.
152
05-0159
Proposed Order
c. MW Gens Position
MW Gen supports ComEds proposal not to include a base credit requirement in its proposed
CPP-B and CPP-A SFCs. Although this issue is not contested, MW Gen wishes to inform the Commission
that this is an important issue for suppliers such as MW Gen, and MW Gen agrees with ComEd on this
topic. Specifically, MW Gen believes that an independent base credit requirement would be too
onerous for suppliers and could diminish auction participation without providing added consumer
protection. MW Gen believes that the consumer protections that ComEd has incorporated into the
SFCs (e.g. mark-to-market and expedited termination and re-contracting procedures), as well as the
PJM credit requirement, are sufficient to ensure credit protection for this initial auction, and
will provide effective consumer protection without the need for an independent base credit
requirement that would impose an unwarranted burden on suppliers.
d. MSCGs Position
MSCG points out that, under the SFCs, bidders must meet certain credit requirements
established in order to protect ComEd and its customers against the risks of default by suppliers.
MSCG further notes that ComEd allows any bidder to submit an alternate form of guaranty rather than
the form of guaranty included with ComEds filing.
Morgan Stanley states that the Commission should confirm that New York law may be designated
in the alternate guaranty as the choice of law that governs the interpretation of that alternate
guaranty approved as described in the Part I Application Form, Appendix C. Morgan Stanley explains
that treasury departments of guarantors likely will submit as alternate guaranties their own,
strongly preferred standard guaranties These guarantors standard forms of guaranty include all of
their preferred terms, often including New York governing law, a provision critical to many
guarantors. Because virtually every issue regarding the law of guaranties has been handled in New
York, most guaranties in any context are governed by New York law. Morgan Stanley asserted that to
encourage wider participation in the auction, then, bidders should be allowed to submit alternative
forms of guaranty governed by New York law. Morgan Stanley pointed out that, with respect to their
standard offer procurements similar to that proposed by the Ameren Companies, Maryland has required
and New Jersey has allowed New York law to govern interpretation of their guaranties and/or
alternate guaranties.
e. Commission Conclusion
The Commission notes that ComEd has adjusted the credit requirements based upon the feedback
and proposals in this proceeding, including Staffs proposed reporting requirement. ComEds
proposal to allow suppliers to qualify for unsecured credit lines based on their own credit ratings
and balance sheet strength or those of a guarantor or to post collateral for any exposure amounts
in excess of their unsecured credit lines reaches a reasonable balance. The Commission finds
ComEds proposed
153
05-0159
Proposed Order
credit requirements to be appropriate. Therefore, the Commission approves ComEds credit
requirement proposals.
3. Proposed Clarifications and Modifications Accepted by ComEd
Throughout the discussions with suppliers prior to the filing of this proceeding, ComEd
accepted many suggestions for modifications to the proposed supplier forward contract. Additional
suggestions were made in testimony that ComEd has also agreed to incorporate. With respect to a
few changes proposed by Mr. Huddleston and Mr. Dauphinais, ComEd has included modifications that
address issues raised, but that do not track in all respects the proposed revisions requested.
With respect to those changes, ComEd believes that it has been responsive, has made appropriate
modifications and that there are valid reasons, explained by Ms. Juracek, for not including all of
the language suggested by the witnesses.
Constellation proposed four changes, which ComEd has accepted. The first two relate to
Section 5.4e regarding situations where multiple contracts exist between the same parties.
Constellations first proposed change to Section 5.4e provides that, when multiple agreements are
in existence between the ComEd and the same supplier, the Non-Defaulting Party as well as ComEd
would calculate the termination payment. Constellations second proposal regarding Section 5.4e
provides that, when there is termination of one SFC between ComEd and a supplier because of a
default, all SFCs between the same parties are terminated. Constellations third proposal changes
Section 15.13 to require parties to provide copies of any applicable tax exemption certificates.
Constellations fourth proposed change relates to Section 13.2 clarifying whether ComEd or the
supplier is responsible for changes in charges associated with delivery services or NITS.
Morgan Stanley proposed that New York law govern the guaranties that are available under the
Illinois auction proposal as one way to meet the credit requirements. Morgan Stanley maintains
that it is standard to use New York law to govern guaranties, as New York has the most well
developed body of law regarding guaranties. Morgan Stanley suggests that New York law also govern
any alternative guaranties. ComEd agreed.
4. Proposed Clarifications and Modifications not Accepted by ComEd
a. ComEds Right to Withhold Payments from Suppliers
i. MW Gens Position
MW Gen identifies two provisions of the Supplier Forward Contracts with which Midwest Gen
takes issue. The first provision to which Midwest Gen objects is ComEds right to withhold
payments from suppliers. This provision provides that a party who
154
05-0159
Proposed Order
improperly withholds an amount in dispute shall pay to the other the amount due plus interest.
Midwest Gen reasons that because ComEd is projected to be the net payer under the contracts, the
provision will unfairly apply only to suppliers. MW Gen claims that under the SFCs ComEd can
withhold payment for up to ninety days without justification. MW Gen claims that given the amount
of money that will be due the suppliers, such a delay could place them into dire financial
conditions. MW Gen also argues that the interest rate provided for in the SFCs (currently tied to
the Federal Funds Effective Rate) is insufficient to compensate suppliers if ComEd arbitrarily
withholds payment. MW Gen proposes language providing that ComEd cannot withhold payment at its
discretion without being required to justify that withholding promptly and paying a compensatory
interest rate.
ii. ComEds Position
ComEd maintains that the language allowing ComEd to withhold payments from suppliers is
necessary to protect customers. ComEd stated that it does not intend to arbitrarily withhold
payments; therefore no change is necessary to the provision.
iii. Commission Conclusion
ComEd has shown that its proposed language allowing the withholding of payments to suppliers
is necessary. The Commission finds that ComEds proposal appropriate and therefore adopts ComEds
proposed language.
b. Supplier Indemnification of ComEd Liability
Under Section 16-125
i. MW Gens Position
MW Gen objects to the SFCs language providing for ComEds shifting of liability under Section
16-125. Section 16-125 requires a utility to pay affected customers for actual damages where more
than 30,000 customers are affected for more than 4 hours or where transmission is at less than 50%
and the replacement value of all goods damaged as a result of a power surge or other fluctuation
affecting more than 30,000 customers. MW Gen argues that ComEd should not be allowed to shift its
liability under Section 16-125.
ii. ComEds Position
ComEd maintains that the SFC language is appropriate. ComEd notes that a supplier is
responsible for the 16-125 damages only when it was caused by or occurs as a result of an act or
omission of the supplier. ComEd states that, although Midwest Gen claims that ComEd can cause the
outage and still shift the charges to the supplier, the language clearly states that the supplier
must cause the event which leads to the damages. ComEd clarified that the intent of this provision
is to place the liability for an outage with the entity causing the outage. ComEd maintains that
this is an important
155
05-0159
Proposed Order
feature necessary to protect both customers and ComEd given the need to rely on electricity
suppliers.
iii. Commission Conclusion
MW Gen objects to ComEds proposal to hold the suppliers responsible for damages resulting
from their action or inaction. ComEd has shown that such a provision is both allowable under
Section 16-125 and is a reasonable manner for placing the burden for damages on the appropriate
party. The Commission adopts ComEds proposed language.
c. Additional Supplier Input into Final ComEd
Supply Forward Contracts
i. Dynegys Position
Dynegy proposes that workshops be convened to provide an open forum to allow all suppliers to
provide input regarding the SFCs. Dynegy acknowledges ComEds willingness to work with suppliers,
noting the numerous compromises and changes made to the SFCs. However, Dynegy claims that it would
be inappropriate to approve the SFCs with only input from one side, i.e. ComEd.
ii. ComEds Position
ComEd opposes further opportunities for input regarding the SFCs. ComEd notes that it has
undertaken an open process to elicit information from suppliers. ComEd also notes the numerous
changes made to the SFCs as a result of the current proceeding. ComEd states that Dynegys
proposal would be unduly burdensome and unnecessary.
iii. Commission Conclusion
ComEd has actively solicited feedback from suppliers in crafting the SFCs. In addition,
numerous parties to this proceeding have provided comments and proposals regarding the SFCs. The
Commission agrees with ComEd that there is no need to provide another opportunity for suppliers to
provide input at this time.
VI. PROCUREMENT PROCESSES ALTERNATIVES
A. Active Portfolio Management
1. ComEds Position
ComEd opposes the use of an active portfolio management procurement process. ComEd points out
that portfolio management would rely on the judgment of one party ComEd to assemble the
necessary portfolio instead of relying on multiple
156
05-0159
Proposed Order
suppliers, each of whom might employ different strategies and techniques to meet the variable
demands of customers. ComEd also notes that the same products available to ComEd in a portfolio
management process are available to suppliers bidding in the auction, but with the added benefit of
planning by multiple parties. ComEd states that whether and how to use such products are questions
that would be considered by each of the bidders and the resulting diversity of solutions would
provide assurance that only the most effective alternatives for meeting customer needs would be
selected. By this means, risk is managed by those entities that are able to do it at the lowest
possible cost.
ComEd notes that reliance on a number of sophisticated suppliers to arrive at the best supply
approach will not only achieve a better result, but it will eliminate the risk of huge losses that
can arise when a utility undertakes unilateral responsibility for supply decisions. ComEd states
that one particular problem is that active portfolio management can leave a utility with long term,
fixed volume contracts that are no longer needed if customers switch to alternative suppliers and
the costs of such contracts must then be spread over a shrinking pool of customers, driving rates
up. ComEd characterizes active portfolio management as a very difficult process that has been
proven in Illinois and other jurisdictions to increase customers costs.
ComEd notes that Dr. Steinhurst admitted that, under the Vermont long range planning process
that he oversaw electric rates were well above the national average. The Illinois Auction and
its full requirements product will free ComEds customers from significant risks inherent in the
active portfolio management approach.
Regarding CUB/CCSAOs claim that ComEd could extract better offers from suppliers as an active
portfolio manager than will result from the auction process, ComEd maintains that there is no basis
for reaching any such conclusion. ComEd states that it has no special bargaining position that
would generate below market offers from suppliers. Rather, bidders in the auction and suppliers
outside an auction would both consider available opportunities to sell in the marketplace. ComEd
stresses that for both auction suppliers and suppliers under a portfolio procurement mechanism,
there is an open market where suppliers have many opportunities to sell; they have absolutely no
reason or incentive to sell below what they could receive in the market.
ComEd also rebuts the claims by the AG and CUB/CCSAO that ComEd did not consider active
portfolio management, as it was one of the procurement scenarios considered during the Commissions
Post 2006 Initiative. ComEd notes that the Staffs Final Report did not recommend that ComEd
pursue this approach, with good reason. ComEd also maintains that contrary to the AG and
CUB/CCSAOs unsupported arguments, the choice of the Illinois Auction process is likely to reduce
costs through the transparent, dynamic descending clock mechanism that tends to drive prices down.
157
05-0159
Proposed Order
2. Staffs Position
Staff notes that AG and CUB/CCSAO witnesses argued in favor of so-called active portfolio
management that includes utilization of the many other standard products available in the market,
and the possibility of negotiating prices and other contract terms with suppliers. Staff opposes
the active portfolio management approach, recommending that the Commission reject it.
In Staffs view, if the Commission were to find (e.g., in this docket) that the proposed
auction process is a just and reasonable mechanism to use to secure power and energy, it strains
the bounds of fairness to subject the utility to after-the-fact prudence reviews, except for those
aspects of the process where the utility retains discretion. Staffs position, in this docket, has
been to remove as much discretion as possible from the Company and place it in the hands of a
transparent competitive process that would be pre-approved by the Commission.
In this case, active portfolio management raises several concerns for Staff, which are
discussed in this subsection.
First, active portfolio management, by definition, places significant discretion in the hands
of the utility company with regard to purchasing power and energy. Staff notes that ComEd (and
Ameren) both have large power generating and marketing affiliates. Their existence supplies the
utilities with a conflict of interest. Thus, in what would amount to a beauty contest between one
complex procurement plan and another complex procurement plan (with a multitude of criteria for
selection), it would probably be as difficult for the utility to avoid playing favorites as it
would for the Commission to determine if that were happening. This type of problem is avoided to a
tremendous extent through the vertical tranche auction approach, where all the criteria for
selection have worked out in advance and presented to the Commission for its approval, and the
focus of the auction is on only one completely objective criteria: price.
Staff argues that what CUB and the AG miss is that when the portfolio management service is in
the hands of the competitive market, as it is in the Auction Process proposed by ComEd, the
competitive suppliers are the ones who will decide how efficient it is to leave some of the
position open. The competitive suppliers will factor any such advantages directly into their bids.
Customers will get the benefit of such cost minimizing strategies, and they will get this benefit
at a fixed price.
In summary, Staff does not believe that there is sufficient evidence in the record to reject
the proposed SCDA approach for what some witnesses have referred to as active portfolio
management. Indeed, even those witnesses who seem to be most inclined toward active portfolio
management have not gone so far as to actually recommend that the Commission order the utilities to
utilize the approach. Rather, they prefer to let ComEd and Ameren make that decision, themselves,
at their own peril. In contrast, there are several advantages over active portfolio management
that have
158
05-0159
Proposed Order
been firmly established in the record. Thus, for all the above reasons, Staff respectfully
recommends that the Commission reject active portfolio management at this time.
3. AGs Position
The AG notes that active portfolio management involves at least two well defined functions:
(1) product or portfolio design and (2) procurement. Product or portfolio design is the
identification of customer needs and constraints, such as tolerance for risk, identification of the
types of resources necessary and appropriate to meet those needs and constraints, and managing
those elements to acquire electricity at a price that is as low cost and reliable as possible.
Procurement is the process whereby resources are actually acquired. There is a range of
procurement alternatives, including bilateral agreements, affiliate contracts, requests for
proposals, and auctions.
The AG continues stating that active portfolio management would allow the utility to consider
a wide range of products, including standard market products (e.g. baseload, peak, super-peak, full
requirements or load following), unit contingent products (contracts for output from specific
facilities), various contract durations, and various pricing options (fixed price, tolling, index)
and some spot market purchases. The AG asserts that these products reflect varying degrees of
risk, and enable the buyer to negotiate to capture the lower costs associated with baseload plants
(e.g. nuclear powered, coal powered) as compared to the higher costs of peaker plants, which use
more expensive fuel (e.g. natural gas), but are needed for less time.
The AG argues that ComEds auction proposal would unnecessarily and unfairly limit its
opportunities to obtain low prices for consumers, particularly when compared to more active
management of supply. The AG insists that multilateral negotiations can yield lower prices than a
simultaneous descending clock auction for the reason a multilateral negotiation might yield a lower
price than a simultaneous descending clock auction is that direct participation allows a shrewd
buyer to implement price caps by holding firm and refusing to purchase from suppliers at prices
above which the buyer expects they can afford to accept.
The AG argues that ComEds potential suppliers have different operating costs, with some
suppliers using nuclear fuel and operations, some using coal, and some using natural gas. The AG
asserts that ComEd personnel have knowledge of the operation and cost of electric generation. The
AG notes the proposed auction has no cap. The AG further notes that ComEd is the largest purchaser
in northern Illinois, and one of the largest purchasers in the nation, accounting for approximately
14% of PJMs present peak load. According to the AG, under these circumstances, ComEd should be
able to bargain effectively on behalf of its over 3 million captive customers to obtain the lowest
possible price for electricity.
The AG argues that ComEds auction proposal would forego the benefits of multi-lateral
negotiations and a flexible and customized procurement strategy for an approach that is rigidly
limited to one type of product and one type of procurement method. The
159
05-0159
Proposed Order
AG asserts that ComEd would relegate the management of supply to a process that minimizes
discretion, insulates ComEd from any responsibility for the prices consumers would be forced to
pay, allows suppliers to set the price paid by consumers, and removes Commission oversight of
prices entirely.
The AG states that the mandatory transition period in the 1997 Amendments has given ComEd and
the other utilities significant time to learn how to obtain supply. The AG asserts that active
portfolio management would allow it to continue to act as the agent of monopoly consumers and to
use all of the variables that go into purchasing to the advantage of consumers.
The AG notes that ComEds supply contracts expire on December 31, 2006. The AG asserts that
this abrupt discontinuity is a significant risk factor for consumers. It leaves the utility and
its customers vulnerable to price changes for its entire load and gives up any benefit the utility
could have obtained by locking in current prices or by hedging. This problem is compounded by the
use of an annual auction, leaving the utility in the position to purchase all of its load under
whatever market conditions exist on the day of the auction.
The AG argues that active portfolio management would enable ComEd to space its purchases to
minimize or hedge risk. Although no one can claim to know exactly when to buy to obtain the lowest
long term price, spreading purchases over time minimizes the risk that any one purchase will have a
major, disruptive impact on prices.
4. CUBs Position
CUB argues that ComEd should have presented the ICC with a full exploration of the range of
options for procuring resources to serve default service customers, comparing them objectively in
terms of their impact on the costs and risks. Such a proceeding could have allowed a reasoned
determination of which approach would best satisfy the needs of ratepayers and other parties.
CUB further argues that ComEd would have certain advantages in managing its own portfolio,
including experience, access to the best information about customers and their requirements,
ongoing real time data collection, and potentially lower equity return requirements and debt rates.
CUB argues that diversified, actively-managed procurement would allow flexibility in procurement
decisions and negotiations. If properly managed and utilized, this flexibility can provide
benefits that would not be possible under rigid auction rules. CUB believes that the full range of
opportunities and benefits to the supplierincluding non-monetary benefits, such as a stable income
stream, the value of a business relationship, or any aspect of the transaction that has value to
the supplier and lead it to reduce the price vis-à-vis an alternativemust be considered for this
comparison.
CUB states there are many products that ComEd can combine into an actively managed portfolio
design. CUB asserts that just a few of the products that should be
160
05-0159
Proposed Order
evaluated to determine how their costs and risk profiles would affect default service rates
include standard wholesale electric power market forward contracts of various lengths from a month
to a number of years and a wide range of starting dates; spot purchases; bilateral negotiated
contracts of varied terms, sizes or start dates; unit-specific power contracts with owners of
existing units; non-unit-specific power contracts with owners of groups of existing units; residual
load following contracts; options to buy (or sell) power at various prices at various times; and
at-cost, fixed price, turn-key or other types of arrangements for power from new or existing units
at various locations.
CUB asserts that ComEd would have significant bargaining power and could bring discipline to
the wholesale markets. CUB states that choosing a diverse portfolio of resources, actively managed
for the benefit of default service customers would allow ComEd to pick and choose among offers of
different types, opt for short-term or open positions if markets do not produce reasonable results,
or fall back on any or all of the many other product choices listed above, all in an infinite range
of combinations driven by the actual offers available.
CUB asserts that ComEd, as a buyer, also could optimize its portfolio with a different
objective (protecting customer interests and risk preferences) than suppliers that will optimize
based upon their own risk preferences. According to CUB, a diverse, actively-managed portfolio can
be readily adapted to cope with changes in markets, both supply and demand. CUB argues that
ComEds proposed portfolio design and procurement method not only passes through to default service
consumers all the costs and risks of that procurement, but actually exacerbates some of those risks
by placing all of the default service load on single-product, single-date auctions.
CUB argues that ComEd proposes to deprive default service customers of the benefits that could
be obtained from a more diversified portfolio and procurement process, simply so it can avoid the
responsibility for making portfolio design and management decisions, tasks that it once routinely
performed and are routinely performed by its affiliates today (albeit not for the benefit of
ratepayers), and by commodity managers for all sorts of businesses.
CUB further argues that ComEd misrepresents both the breadth of procurement options open to
it, as well as the considerable flexibility given to it under Illinois restructuring legislation.
ComEd continues to have all the flexibility it always did in choosing resources and procurement
methods, plus additional new flexibility in how it runs its business. Clearly prudent utilities
have relied on a wide range of products, term lengths, and procurement methods to manage risk and
cost. Few, if any, have had the temerity to place their entire resource portfolio in a blind
trust. Given the magnitude of the costs and risks from uncompetitive wholesale markets, it is not
appropriate for ComEd to simply give up on protecting consumers from those costs and risks without
seriously examining the alternatives.
CUB asserts that ComEds true motives in favoring the auction over other procurement methods
are to financially benefit Exelon and ExGen, and to avoid the
161
05-0159
Proposed Order
risks of after-the-fact prudence reviews and after-the-fact determinations of just and
reasonable rates.
5. Commission Conclusion
The Commission finds at this time that the auction proposal is a better procurement method
than an active portfolio.
B. Request for Proposal
1. ComEds Position
ComEd states that no party is contending that supply for customers should be acquired through
a request for proposal (RFP) process. ComEd notes that the RFP process was one of the
alternatives considered during the Post 2006 initiative, but that Staffs Final Report rejected
that option, recommending instead that large utilities use a vertical tranche auction. ComEd
evaluated the RFP process and likewise concluded that the Illinois Auction was the preferable
procurement approach.
ComEd maintains that there are several practical advantages to utilizing the auction process
as opposed to the RFP process. First, and probably most importantly, the descending clock auction
process provides the transparency that suppliers need to efficiently bid on the tranches. The
clarity of price signals and the ability for suppliers to modify their bids requires bidders to
aggressively bid in order to win. ComEd states that the auction constitutes a market in which
suppliers compete in an open process that permits ComEd to obtain the supply needed to serve its
customers at the lowest expected market prices. These aspects of the auction process cannot be
fully duplicated in a RFP process. ComEd asserts that suppliers are attracted to such auctions
because of the transparency of the process. This provides more certainty, relative to a RFP
process, that there will be sufficient levels of competition to make the process work. Third, the
auction process more easily accommodates multiple products as opposed to a RFP process as the
bidders all can see what products are being sold and at what current prices and can quickly modify
their offerings to arbitrage price differences. Because one of the key features of the proposal is
to use multiple products to help mitigate short-term price risk, the descending clock auction
process was a natural choice. Finally, it is important to note that ComEd did not choose this
process on its own. It hired Dr. LaCasse to provide a recommendation based on her substantial
experience in the field, and she recommended the descending clock auction process.
ComEd believes that the Illinois Auction is a better means to acquire supply for customers
than the RFP process.
2. Staffs Position
Staff notes that requests for proposals, auctions, bilateral negotiations, and purchases from
the centralized PJM markets are all alternative ways of obtaining contracts for power from markets.
Staff further notes that using a request for proposal
162
05-0159
Proposed Order
(RFP) does not imply that the utility can avoid going to markets. At one extreme, RFPs
could be used to solicit bids for new generating equipmenteither turn-key operations or
components. Several different RFPs could be used to solicit bids for base load, intermediate load,
and peaking load (consistent with the active portfolio management approach discussed in the
previous subsection). At the other extreme, RFPs could be used to solicit bids for vertical
tranches (i.e., percent of full-requirements load), as in the Companys proposal. In other words,
a request for proposal is merely an alternative to using an auction process for soliciting bids
from potential suppliers.
As far as Staff can tell, no witness has actually proposed that ComEd utilize RFPs as a means
to solicit bids for power in the post 2006 era. Hence, Staff recommends that the Commission reject
substituting one or more RFPs for the proposed auction process.
3. Commission Conclusion
There is no action for the Commission to take on the issue of RFPs. Although included in the
Post 2006 Initiative, no party has proposed that power be acquired through RFPs.
C. Affiliate Contract
1. ComEds Position
ComEd states that in designing the Illinois auction proposal, it has attempted to design a
competitive procurement process that facilitates the participation of as many suppliers as
possible. Because Exelon Generation is affiliated with ComEd, ComEd notes that additional
requirements apply under federal law to any power purchase agreement (PPA) between the companies.
As explained by Elizabeth Moler, former Chair of the Federal Energy Regulatory Commission, FERC
requires the parties to show by objective market value criteria that the terms of the PPA are
reasonable. Ms. Moler discussed the 1991 Edgar decision in which FERC set forth these three
criteria by which the applicant could make such a showing: (1) evidence of direct competition
between the affiliated supplier and non-affiliated suppliers; (2) comparable sales by the
affiliated supplier to non-affiliated purchasers; and (3) benchmark evidence of sales involving
other parties. Ms. Moler also stressed that FERC has recently reiterated the importance of the
Edgar criteria and has applied them to numerous affiliate transactions.
ComEd maintains that the Illinois auction includes the features that meet the requirements set
forth under the Edgar standard. ComEd states that the Illinois auction process maximizes the
transparency of the procurement decision. In the Illinois auction proposal, ComEd highlights that
all bidders, including any ComEd affiliates, compete on an equal footing and the price is set by
the forces of supply and demand. Thus, ComEd notes that there is no way for the utility to favor
its affiliate in such a process.
163
05-0159
Proposed Order
Regarding the use of a purchase directly from ComEds affiliate ExGen, ComEd states that it
cannot force ExGen to sell below market prices any more than ComEd can force any other generator to
supply ComEd at below market prices. ComEd notes that energy generators have many potential
purchasers. Thus, generators, including ExGen, are going to seek a price based on the market price
they could receive. ComEd maintains that it is illogical to assume that generators such as ExGen
will agree to sell to ComEd at a price less than what they could receive by selling to other
purchasers.
2. Staffs Position
Staff notes that, pursuant to the Customer Choice and Rate Relief Law of 1997, ComEd was
allowed to divest itself of its generating assets. Thus, unless the generating assets are bought
back by ComEd, the cost of those plants and the cost of operating them cannot directly form the
basis for a reassessment of ComEds rates following the rate freeze. Staff states that these
plants are now a part of market supply. From ComEds perspective, the cost of producing power
and energy from these plants is not and may never again be determined by an accounting of the cost
of building and operating these plants.
Staff agrees that it would be desirable for ratepayers if Exelon (and/or other suppliers)
could be convinced to provide power and energy to Illinois utilities at below-market prices.
However, Staff is of the opinion that it is highly unlikely and unrealistic to assume that ComEd
can acquire power and energy at below-market prices, and there is no viable plan for making it
happen.
Staff argues that the Commission simply cannot prevent Exelon from being enriched by such
sales, if Exelons costs happen to be lower than those market-based prices. Staff notes that
assuming no accounting or rate design improprieties, such market-based purchases are fully
consistent with ComEd having cost-based rates. Based on the above discussion, Staff respectfully
recommends that the Commission take no action to direct ComEd to acquire power from affiliates, but
that the Commission recognize and accept that the proposed auction may result in ComEd affiliates
supplying part of the Companys full-requirement needs. In addition, Staff respectfully recommends
against the Commission dictating to ComEd that the Company must negotiate or demand purchases from
affiliates at anything other than FERC-approved prices, whether or not they are market-based.
3. AGs Position
The AG asserts that ComEd should use its substantial buying power to negotiate with its
generation affiliate. The AG assets that prior affiliate contracts between ExGen and ComEd were
able to save consumers money while providing compensatory returns to both ComEd and ExGen.
Regarding ComEds comments that ExGen and other generators will not accept below market prices,
the AG claims that many different market prices for electricity exist due to the different types of
buyers and sellers. The AG contends that Illinois customers paid for, and in some situations,
164
05-0159
Proposed Order
continue to pay for the nuclear plants that allow ExGen to have among the lowest cost of
production of any electric generator. The AG asserts that ComEd should seek to capture ExGens low
cost of production though the use of affiliate contracts, such as those currently in place. The AG
stresses that ComEd has substantial bargaining power to negotiate with its affiliate to buy ExGens
low-cost electricity for ComEd customers in 2007 and beyond.
4. Commission Conclusion
The Commission finds that any procurement strategy must be grounded in the real world.
Neither this Commission nor ComEd can compel any supplier to sell power to ComEd at a price lower
than that which would result from a competitive auction.
D. Other Competitive Procurement Mechanisms
ComEd has noted that Staff and the other participants in the Post 2006 Initiative, including
many of the intervenors in this proceeding, did not confine their analysis to a limited group of
options. They considered a broad range of alternative scenarios and variants of those scenarios.
They analyzed the advantages and disadvantages of each approach. The effort was lengthy and
detailed, providing a searching review of the available options. ComEd has presented detailed
evidence supporting the choice of a competitive procurement auction as suggested by Staffs Final
Report. The Commission finds that nothing that has been presented in this proceeding or in any
other forum provides any basis for reaching a different outcome or for proposing any other
procurement approach. Therefore, as modified elsewhere in this Order, the Commission approves
ComEds tariffs incorporating a competitive procurement auction.
E. Other Procurement Processes Alternatives
Parties did not identify any additional alternatives.
VII. TARIFF AND RATE DESIGN ISSUES
A. Rider CPP
1. Organization
ComEd recommends that the Commission approve the organizational structure of proposed Rider
CPP, as revised by ComEd in its rebuttal testimony to reflect suggestions made in Staffs direct
testimony. ComEd says it and Staff are in agreement on this subject and that no intervenor has
submitted any testimony on this subject.
In its brief, Staff describes the purpose of Rider CPP and its nine parts. Additionally,
Staff says it and ComEd agree that there is the need for a uniform index for Rider CPP. According
to Staff, in its rebuttal testimony ComEd indicated that in the future it would be making a
housekeeping type filing that would impact the index. Staff
165
05-0159
Proposed Order
does not have a position on ComEds statement that it would eventually move all definitions
contained in the definitions part of Rider CPP to ComEds Terms and Conditions in a subsequent
housekeeping type filing. Staff says that until it actually sees the filing it cannot respond to
the proposal. In Staffs view, while such a housekeeping filing would cause a change to the index
outline proposed, no such filing has been made by ComEd and therefore the index that should be
approved in this docket is the one which is set forth in Schedule 19.1 to Ms. Hardens rebuttal
testimony.
In the Commissions view, there is no real contested issue here. The organizational structure
agreed to by ComEd and Staff, as reflected in Schedule 19.1 attached to Staff Ex. 19.0, is hereby
approved.
2. Customer Supply Group Definitions
ComEd states that in light of certain Staff and intervenor direct and rebuttal testimony, in
its surrebuttal testimony, ComEd proposed an integrated package of three auction/rate design
changes: (1) moving the Large Load Customer Supply Group from the CPP-B auction segment to the
CPP-A auction segment, (2) changing the CPP-A enrollment window from an opt in to an opt out
window of 30 days, (3) eliminating the Migration Risk Factor component from the CPP-B translation
formulae.
According to ComEd, if the Large Load Customer Supply Group is moved from the CPP-B auction
segment to the CPP-A auction segment, then, in the last sentence of the definition of that Group,
the word Blended should be changed to Annual.
Above in this Order, the Commission approved moving the Large Load Customer Supply Group from
the CPP-B auction segment to the CPP-A auction segment. Additionally, while the Commission
appreciates the efforts of ComEd and the other parties to reduce contested issues by modifying
proposals during the course of this proceeding, the Commission cannot simply adopt ComEds
integrated package of proposals. While the Commission understands that the three issues are
related, it must evaluate each on its own merits.
3. Peak and Off-Peak Period Definitions
a. ComEds Position
ComEd originally proposed new Peak and Off-Peak period definitions for purposes of the time of
use Supply Charges calculated under Rider CPP that it says would conform both the prisms and the
retail rate structure with what ComEd describes as the commonly used definitions in the wholesale
market. ComEd claims its proposal was intended to enhance the transparency of, and simplify the
Supply Charges calculations.
Staff and BOMA opposed, on different grounds, ComEds proposed new Peak and Off-Peak period
definitions, and urged the use of existing definitions.
166
05-0159
Proposed Order
ComEd and Dynegy, in rebuttal, supported ComEds proposed new Peak and Off-Peak period
definitions.
In the interest of further narrowing the outstanding issues in this proceeding, ComEd says it
is willing to use the existing peak and off-peak period definitions, with the North American
Electric Reliability Council holidays, for purposes of determining and applying Supply Charges
pursuant to Rider CPP and to reflect such changes as part of a compliance filing ordered in the
instant proceeding.
If the Commission rejects the proposal to continue using the existing Peak and Off-Peak period
definitions, with the NERC holidays, ComEd recommends adopting its original proposal.
b. Staffs Position
According to Staff, maintaining the existing definitions of Peak and Off-Peak Periods offers
significant advantages over ComEds proposal. First, it removes from the Peak Period the hours of
6 a.m.-9 a.m. when demands on the system and the need for supply resources are low. Second, the
continuity with the current Peak Period definition offers benefits to customers who are on
time-of-day rates and have aligned their consumption behavior to take advantage of the current
definitions of Peak and Off-Peak hours. If the definition of the Peak were to be broadened, then
these customers would find it necessary to change their consumption behavior once again to take
advantage of an extended peak period. In addition, precedence exists for divergence between the
retail and wholesale peak periods. Staff claims New Jersey utilities do not consistently adhere to
the 6 a.m.-10 p.m. (Central) Peak Period prevailing in the PJM wholesale market to devise Peak
Periods for their retail customers.
c Dynegys Position
In its reply brief, Dynegy states that although it continues to believe that the definitions
used for retail purposes should mirror those used in the wholesale markets, it is willing to accept
for purposes of the initial auction, the definition agreed to between Staff and ComEd, with the
understanding that this may be revisited as a part of the post-auction process.
d. Commissions Analysis and Conclusions
The Commission finds ComEds existing Peak and Off Peak period definitions, with the NERC
holidays, to be reasonable and supported by the record evidence. The Commission approves use of
these definitions in this proceeding.
167
05-0159
Proposed Order
4. Specification of Competitive Procurement Process
According to ComEd, the Competitive Procurement Process part serves to: (1) note the role of
the CPP auctions in establishing pricing; (2) describe key elements of the CPP auctions from a
ratemaking perspective; (3) describe the respective responsibilities of certain participants in the
CPP auctions, such as the independent Auction Manager; (4) address certain documents and
information provided to prospective bidders and the Commission, including the load caps,
association criteria, and credit requirements set forth in those documents; and (5) set forth the
CPP Timeline.
5. Retail Customer Switching Rules Enrollment Window
a. ComEds Position
ComEd proposed that eligible customers have a 30-day enrollment window following the auction
within which customers who were not previously taking bundled service from ComEd would have the
opportunity to opt-in to the CPP-A fixed price service. Following discussions with other parties
who expressed views about the appropriate length of the enrollment window, ComEd has agreed to
modify its proposal to provide for a 50-day enrollment window in the first auction year and a
45-day window in all subsequent auction years.
BOMA and CES argue that the 30-day enrollment period for PPO and delivery service customers to
opt in to bundled service supplied through the CPP-A auction is too short and should be extended
to 75 days to provide more time for customers to make decisions about their supply alternatives.
ComEd expressed concern that a longer period would increase the costs customers pay for supply.
ComEd contends that suppliers who bid in the auction will take into account that customers have the
right to choose between auction-procured supply and alternative arrangements. ComEd argues that
the fixed price auction bidders offer, therefore, constitutes a call option, enabling customers
to consider alternatives while auction bidders are forced to hold open a firm price for supply,
which customers may or may not choose to accept. According to ComEd, the cost of making that
option available for 30 days will be priced into the bids. By extending the length of the option
to 75-days, ComEd asserts that the risk to suppliers increases and the increased cost associated
with the option will cause the auction bids to rise in response.
It is ComEds position that the length of the enrollment period is a matter of judgment on
which reasonable people can have different views. ComEd avers that the challenge is to strike the
right balance between providing customers time within which to make decisions and avoiding the high
premium that would result if suppliers were forced to hold out fixed price call options for long
periods of time. ComEd suggests a 50-day enrollment window in the first auction year, when
customers are becoming accustomed to the new procurement environment, is appropriate, and that, for
all subsequent years, a 45-day window is adequate.
168
05-0159
Proposed Order
b. CES Position
CES argues that the 30 day enrollment period is especially problematic for many types of
retail customers, such as school districts, governmental entities and hospitals. Additionally, CES
claims companies that hire energy consultants and issue requests for proposals might need more than
30 days to make their supply decisions. CES believes 30 days is an insufficient amount of time to
prepare bids for and negotiate with hundreds of prospective retail customers.
In its brief and draft order, CES indicates that in an effort to resolve a disputed issue, it
now supports ComEds newest proposal as it strikes a reasonable balance between the competing
proposals. As a result, CES is no longer asking the Commission to adopt an enrollment window
equivalent to ComEds currently established 75-day Power Purchase Option (PPO) enrollment window.
CES argues that in a competitive environment, the theoretical premiums asserted by the IIEC,
Dynegy and the Staff likely will be squeezed out of bids and, therefore, will not be reflected in
the final prices bid into the wholesale auction. It is CES position that even if Staffs figures
are accepted at face value for the sake of argument, this theoretical premium is a small price to
pay to afford customers a meaningful opportunity to evaluate, negotiate, and execute their choices
while, at the same time, provide sufficient time for the utility to make the appropriate changes,
should an error be discovered during the enrollment window.
CES contends that it and ComEd acknowledge that, even if a premium associated with providing
customers with additional time does exist, and CES claims no evidence was presented to prove it
does, customers would be better served by paying the premium because they would have valuable
additional time within which to make their enrollment decisions.
CES argues that if the enrollment window is too short, many customers simply will accept the
utility supply option, not because it is the most economical option, but rather because customers
simply lack sufficient time to implement and complete the decision-making steps necessary to meet
their supply needs. CES asserts that unlike the very large customers represented by IIEC, most
CPP-A customers do not have personnel or offices dedicated to buying electricity. According to
CES, many of these customers simply require more than 30 days to analyze their electricity choices,
move proposals through the corporate or institutional chain of command, negotiate contracts, and,
finally, execute purchase transactions.
CES believes the Commissions decision regarding the duration of the enrollment window will
have a direct, immediate, and significant impact upon the development of the Illinois retail
electric market. CES asserts that the rules governing the auction as well as the types of the
wholesale products included in the auction will directly impact the products and services offered
to retail customers by RESs. CES believes an
169
05-0159
Proposed Order
appropriately defined enrollment window, because it directly affects customers abilities to
assess supply options, is critical.
c. Staffs Position
According to Staff, ComEds selection of the 30-day enrollment period was not based on any
empirical analysis. Rather, in arriving at 30 days as the appropriate duration, Staff says ComEd
was trying to balance giving customers enough time to make supply decisions with trying to keep the
risks associated with the product as small as possible.
In response to claims that it would be impossible to verify whether a risk premium would exist
if the enrollment period were increased from 30 days to 75 days, Staff witness Dr. Schlaf presented
an option pricing model to estimate the size of the risk premium that suppliers might be expected
to add to their bids if the duration enrollment period were increased by a given number of days.
Staff says the rationale for using this type of option pricing model is that customers hold an
option for a certain number of days to buy the annual service product at a fixed strike price.
Staff states that while customers are considering this option, offers from RESs presumably will be
available in the market and their prices would follow the volatility of annual forward contracts.
According to Staff, suppliers might be expected to add about 3.2% of the forward price if the
enrollment window were set at 30 days. For each additional 10 days that the size of the enrollment
window is increased, Staff states that bidders might be expected to add another 0.4% of the forward
price to their bids. Staff claims that for an increase in the enrollment window from 30 days to 75
days, the model shows that suppliers might add about 1.8% of the forward price to their bids. Staff
considers the extra 1.8% a significant amount of additional cost. Staff also points out that no
other party presented any empirical evidence on this issue.
Staff states that in surrebuttal testimony, ComEd proposed that the 30 day enrollment window
remain intact, but that existing bundled service customers could leave CPP-A service to take
service from RESs.
Staff suggests one way to resolve this issue is to compromise on an enrollment window duration
that is between 30 days and 75 days, with the understanding that enlarging the window would
inevitably lead to somewhat higher costs for customers that remain on CPP-A service for the entire
supply period. Thus, in an effort to resolve the issue, Staff recommends that the Commission
enlarge the enrollment window to no more than 40 or 45 days. Staff asserts that this policy would
give RESs and customers more time to negotiate deals, but at a cost (according to the model
results, about an additional 0.4% to 0.5% of the forward price) to CPP-A customers. Staff,
however, does not advocate a longer enrollment period than 40 or 45 days, especially in light of
ComEds surrebuttal proposal to allow existing bundled customers to move off CPP-A service during
the supply period, and the possibility that extra days would cause CPP-A costs to rise.
Additionally, Staff suggests that the Company be required to study the
170
05-0159
Proposed Order
issue of the appropriate duration of the enrollment period, and bring the results of its
analysis to the attention of Staff and other parties prior to the next auction.
According to Staff, the difference between a 30-day enrollment period that is advocated by
IIEC, and the 50-day enrollment period now supported by ComEd and CES, is about 0.8% of the forward
price. Staff considers a 0.8% generation cost increase to be significant, and would be paid by the
customers that are the least able to attract offers from RESs. Staff, therefore, recommends that
the Commission adopt an enrollment period of no more than 45 days, which, based its analysis, would
result in an increase of only 0.6% above the risk premium associated with a 30-day enrollment
window.
d. IIECs Position
IIEC supports ComEds proposed 30-day enrollment window for customers electing service under
ComEds annual fixed-price product. It is IIECs position that proposals by certain parties
related to expanding the 30-day sign up window for the annual fixed-price product to 75 days should
be rejected. IIEC asserts that the proposed expansion of the sign up period will increase risk to
potential suppliers and in turn increase auction prices. IIEC believes that thirty days represents
a reasonable balance of the competing interests of offering customers time to make decisions on
competitive supply options and keeping the bid price premiums to a minimum.
IIEC supports the 30-day sign up window because it believes the evidence indicates that a
longer signup window would produce a risk premium from suppliers which would in turn increase
auction prices.
According to IIEC, CES and BOMA have supported their request for a 75 day window, by comparing
the sign up window for the fixed-price product with the current 75-day sign up window that applies
to ComEds PPO service. IIEC argues that the comparison of the annual fixed-price product to PPO
is misplaced because PPO prices are administratively determined, based on limited snapshot views of
wholesale market conditions. IIEC states that in contrast, the annual fixed-price option in this
case is an actual power supply offer, which wholesale suppliers take on risk to provide. IIEC
states that the length of the PPO sign up window has no effect on PPO price.
IIEC asserts that ComEds proposal for a 50-day window for the first auction and a 45-day
window for all subsequent auctions will cause potential bidders in the auction to add an additional
risk premium to their bid and thereby raise the auction clearing price to the benefit of the RESs
and low-cost bidders in the auction, which may include ComEds own generating affiliate. IIEC
claims that, on the other hand, ComEds decision will be detrimental to customers, who will, by
definition, pay a higher price for power that ComEd acquires for them in the auction.
According to IIEC, CES supports ComEds proposal to increase prices to retail customers
because it gives retail suppliers more headroom, arguing that the premium
171
05-0159
Proposed Order
associated with holding the CPP-A auction price open is merely theoretical. Ironically, IIEC
asserts, CES relies in large part on the testimony of its witness Dr. OConnor, Vice-President for
the Illinois Market for Constellation NewEnergy and ignores the testimony of Michael Smith, Vice
President of Regulatory and Legislative Affairs for another Constellation company, Constellation
Energy Commodities Group, Inc. IIEC says Mr. Smith testified that it was likely that suppliers
would price an auction premium into their bid to account for the optionality associated with the
period of time the customer would have to choose to take CPP-A service. IIEC states that another
potential supplier, Dynegy, also testified that the more risk and uncertainty suppliers are
required to accept, the higher the auction clearing prices will be, and that time-related
uncertainty is one of the reasons prices are not kept open by suppliers for extended periods of
time.
IIEC argues that the premium for holding open the price for the CPP-A product is hardly
theoretical. IIEC states that Dr. OConnor himself had to agree that his own company, as a
standard rule, would not hold open prices for the 75 days recommended by CES. In IIECs view, CES
cannot now credibly argue that the premium for holding open the CPP-A price is merely theoretical.
If it were, IIEC avers, then Mr. Smith and Mr. Huddleston would not have testified otherwise, and
Dr. OConnors company would routinely hold its prices open for extended periods of time.
IIEC states that CES next reasoned that customers require more time to decide on taking the
CPP-A product and that giving these customers additional time is worth the additional premium
(price increase) customers would pay. However, IIEC argues, CES does not speak for larger
customers who have stated they do not require additional time and prefer not to pay the additional
premium. In addition, IIEC says the Commission should remember that CES is a coalition of retail
electric suppliers who will not pay the premium, but rather will benefit from it. Therefore, IIEC
asserts that they have nothing to lose by suggesting customers would rather pay the premium in
return for more time to make their decision about the CPP-A product.
In its reply brief, IIEC states that ComEd did not discuss the 50/45-day window with all
parties that expressed views on this subject. IIEC asserts that ComEd spoke only with retail
electric suppliers, did not speak with IIEC and apparently did not speak with DOE.
IIEC states that while Staff would not support a window in excess of 45 days, it would accept
as a compromise a 40 to 45-day enrollment window and recommends that ComEd be required to study the
appropriate duration of the enrollment window and report to Staff and the parties on the results of
its analysis. IIEC disagrees with Staffs suggestion. In IIECs view, the record demonstrates
that the market clearing price in the auction will be higher than it would have otherwise been as a
result of extending the enrollment window. IIEC also claims that at least two customer groups
(IIEC and DOE) have stated they do not require the additional time and would prefer not to pay the
premium. Therefore, while IIEC disagrees with Staffs recommendation, if Staffs approach is
adopted, the expanded enrollment window should apply only to smaller customers (1 MW or less). If
IIECs recommendation for a separate auction segment for
172
05-0159
Proposed Order
customers 3 MW and over is adopted, IIEC says the 30-day window should be applied to this
segment.
e. DOEs Position
DOE states that while the need for a defined window for large customers is accepted, the
length is in dispute. DOE recognizes that fixed price POLR is a call option for large customers,
and the length of the sign up window will play a part in determining the cost of that call option
to suppliers. DOE states that the longer the duration of the window the more exposed is the
wholesale supplier to changes in market conditions. According to DOE, there is no question that
this will be priced into the POLR supply bids, unduly increasing the cost of the product. Based on
DOEs market experience, it concurs that lengthening the duration of the window beyond 30 days to
75 days will significantly increase the cost of a product likely to be expensive to begin with.
DOE states that the other part of the issue is whether 30 days is sufficient in order for the
customer (i.e., a large customer) to identify supply options and properly respond to the POLR price
signals. DOE says it has extensive marketplace experience with procurement and conducting retail
solicitations. DOE believes 30 days is adequate time to complete retail procurement as long as
ComEd makes its procurement time table known in advance.
In its reply brief, DOE states it is willing to support a modest extension of the window to 40
days as proposed by Staff. However, DOE urges the Commission to adopt the IIECs recommendation
that, if for any reason the Commission determines a longer enrollment window is needed for small
customers, the 30 day enrollment window should apply to larger customers (3 MW and over).
f. Dynegys Position
Dynegy recognizes that customers need some time to decide whether to sign up for CPP-A service
or be foreclosed from it for a year. Thus, Dynegy did not oppose the 30-day window proposed by
ComEd. CES and BOMA have proposed lengthening the window to 75 days because of concerns that
customers will be unable to make a decision in only 30 days. While Dynegy understands that
concern, it opposes the longer period because it imposes added and unnecessary costs on those
customers who either choose to stay on CPP-A service or have no option other than to stay on such
service. Dynegy says the premium could be as high as 1.8%, and while this may not seem like a
large value, one must remember that these are large customers (1-3 MW in size) and this premium
would be assessed on each kWh of energy they used.
Dynegy also asserts that, from a Supplier perspective, the risk premium may need to be even
higher than that calculated by Dr. Schlaf due to a timing issue. If the first auction is held in
early September as currently proposed, and if a 75-day window is used as proposed by CES and BOMA,
Dynegy claims Suppliers will know barely a
173
05-0159
Proposed Order
month before energy must be delivered the exact size of the class of customers to be served on
CPP-A. In Dynegys view, this added uncertainty will also be factored in to the risk premium
Suppliers will include in their bidding strategies.
It is Dynegys position that absent a better showing that larger customers cannot act in 30
days, especially if much of the pre-work between customers and RESs is done prior to the auction
date, the 75 day window should be rejected. According to Dynegy, IIECs opposition to a longer
window speaks volumes on this score and the Commission should reject a 75-day window.
Dynegy states that after the close of the evidentiary record, ComEd appears to have reached an
agreement on a 50-day window for the first auction year and 45-days for subsequent years. Dynegy
believes this agreement should be rejected. Dynegy finds it incredible that ComEd would indicate
that Following discussions with other parties who expressed views about the appropriate length of
the enrollment window, ComEd has agreed . . . . Dynegy says it expressed views on the length of
the window; yet, Dynegy is unaware of any discussions between ComEd and Dynegy on this topic.
Dynegy argues that substantively, the agreement cannot and should not be entered for two
reasons. Dynegy says not all of the parties to this case are in agreement, Dynegy and presumably
others remain opposed to such a lengthy window. Dynegy contends the agreement of ComEd and CES
cannot be accepted on its own. (Dynegy reply brief at 8, citing Business & Prof. People for the
Pub. Interest v. ICC, 136 Ill.2d 192, 209, 555 N.E.2d 693, 700 (Ill. 1989) (In order for the
Commission to dispose of a case by settlement, however, all of the parties and intervenors must
agree to the settlement.))
Dynegy also asserts that the agreement has no evidentiary support. Dynegy says no witness
testified that a 50-day window would be appropriate, much less provided any support for such a
window. As for a 45-day window, Dynegy states that the only possible evidence is Dr. Schlafs
acknowledgement that a window of no more than 40 or 45 days would be reasonable. It is Dynegys
position that while the Commission may have the latitude to use its discretion to craft an
appropriate window in light of the divergent testimony, in doing so, it should take into
consideration what the record evidence will support and here there is virtually none in favor of
the compromise offered by ComEd and CES. Dynegy suggests that Staffs proposal of no more than 40
or 45 days is a recommendation that has at least a fig leaf of evidentiary support to cover it.
In Dynegys view, CES attempt to cast Staffs premium analysis as merely theoretical is
ironic. Dynegy states that on cross-examination, Dr. Schlaf admitted that his premium was
theoretical. Dynegy claims that does not end the story. Dynegy states that Staffs analysis
relied on the same model as used by ComEd to develop its proposed migration risk factor, and,
although CES sought to change two variables in the migration risk analysis, it recognized that the
basic use of the model was a sensible
174
05-0159
Proposed Order
approach. According to Dynegy, CES never explains how this sensible approach somehow morphs
into mere theory when applied in a context it finds inconvenient.
Dynegy contends that CES complaints are attempts to create artificial headroom. Dynegy
asserts that such attempts should be rejected because they benefit no one except RESs.
g. CCGs Position
CCG does not take a position as to the duration of the enrollment window and only makes an
observation that the duration could impact price. CCG states that since the CPP-A customer will
have a period of time within which to choose to take the CPP-A service it is likely that the
generation supply rates for CPP-A customers will be higher as suppliers will likely price an
auction premium into their bids to account for this optionality.
h. DES-USECs Position
DES-USEC argues that in order to develop a competitive market capable of producing sustained,
long-term benefits for Illinois electric consumers there should be no restrictions placed on
switching between electric suppliers. DES-USEC believe that restrictions on switching suppliers,
such as enrollment windows and minimum stay requirements, impair the ability of customers to take
advantage of competitive offers already in the market; discourage competitors from entering the
market; and serve to enrich the wholesale providers by decreasing their risk that customers will
switch providers while at the same time allowing wholesale providers to charge a significant
premium for their long term contracts.
DES-USEC states that the premium associated with migration risk is especially pronounced
under ComEds proposal, with its heavy reliance on long term wholesale supply contracts. DES-USEC
argues that under its proposal, with its monthly and quarterly auction products, potential
migration risk is reduced exponentially. As a result, there is no need under the DES-USEC proposal
for minimum stays or enrollment windows. DES-USEC contends that under its proposal, suppliers do
not have an ongoing commitment beyond the upcoming month or quarter, and customers would be able to
decide to switch on a monthly or bill cycle basis without having to pay an exit fee.
i. Commissions Analysis and Conclusions
The Commission agrees with those parties who suggest the length of the enrollment period is a
matter of judgment on which reasonable people can have different views. The challenge is to strike
the right balance between providing customers time within which to make decisions and avoiding the
higher premium that would result if suppliers were forced to hold out fixed price call options for
longer periods of time.
175
05-0159
Proposed Order
As previously discussed, the Commission appreciates the efforts of those parties who worked
together and developed compromises to reduce the number of contested issues in this proceeding.
However, in this instance, the Commission is concerned that ComEd and CES attempted to develop a
compromise without the input of other interested parties.
Based on the evidence in the record, the Commission finds that a longer enrollment window will
in all likelihood lead to higher auction prices. The Commission finds the evidence presented by
Staff on this point is convincing and unrefuted. While CES position that customers require
sufficient time to make informed decisions has merit, the Commission cannot ignore the fact that
the CES members benefit directly and proportionally from higher auction prices and longer
enrollment windows.
Given the Commissions concern regarding the absolute level of retail prices, the Commission
concludes that, at this time, the enrollment window should be no longer than 40 days. In the
Commissions view, the record supports a finding that while smaller customers may benefit from an
enrollment window somewhat longer than 30 days, larger customers do not need or desire additional
time. Therefore, the Commission adopts the recommendation of IIEC to adopt a 30-day enrollment
window for customers with demands greater than three megawatts. The Commission adopts an
enrollment window of 40 days for customers with demands less than three megawatts. Finally, the
Commission adopts Staffs recommendation and directs ComEd to study the appropriate duration of the
enrollment period and report on the results of its analysis prior to the next auction.
6. Opt In vs. Opt Out
ComEd initially proposed that the one-year fixed price product would be an optional service
available to 13 MW customers who would be required to choose this alternative by opting in
during an enrollment window period each year. According to ComEd, the expansion of the one-year
product to include customers with demands between 400 kW and 1 MW caused ComEd to evaluate whether
the product should continue to be provided only to customers who affirmatively elected it or
whether it should be a default product, provided to customers unless they chose to opt out.
Under ComEds amended proposal, customers taking bundled service under Rate 6, Rate 6L or
Rider 24 the one-year product would be the default service from which customers could opt out if
they chose. For customers taking delivery services and RES supply, the one-year product would be
an optional service that could be elected by opting in within the designated enrollment window
under ComEds amended proposal.
Based on the evidence in the record, the Commission approves the opt out proposal for
customers on Rates 6 and 6L and Rider 24 for CPP-A service. The Commission concludes that ComEds
revised proposal on this issue is a reasonable balance of the competing concerns.
176
05-0159
Proposed Order
7. Other Switching Rule Issues
a. ComEds Position
With regard to the two issues related to CPP-A service, ComEd says it is willing to agree to
permit new accounts that are eligible for CPP-A service to elect to take CPP-A service outside of
the enrollment window, provided that the definition of new accounts does not permit successor
accounts to existing customers that were eligible for, but chose not to take, CPP-A service, to
elect to take CPP-A service outside of the enrollment window.
ComEd says that while it appreciates Staffs attempt in its rebuttal testimony to draw a
workable distinction, Staff did not do so, apparently due to a misinterpretation of ComEds
rebuttal testimony. ComEds concern is not with existing customers legally changing their
corporate name, but rather much more broadly with customers simply changing the name on their
account and then claiming the right to be treated as a new customer. In the event of such a name
change on the account, which may or may not reflect an actual change in ownership or an actual
change in a corporate name, ComEd argues that it would be costly and burdensome to have to
implement the internal processes that would be needed in order to determine whether a successor
account actually involves new ownership.
ComEd asserts that if Staffs proposal as formulated in its rebuttal testimony were adopted,
ComEd would have to incur the burden and costs of such investigative processes. ComEd complains
that ultimately would redound to the detriment of customers in future rates. ComEd also expressed
concern that a customer might dispute ComEds conclusion, which could lead to informal or formal
complaints and imposing burdens on Staff and the Commission as well.
ComEd states that while it is willing to accept permitting new accounts that are eligible for
CPP-A service to elect to take CPP-A service outside of the enrollment window, and to permit
successor accounts to elect to take CPP-A service outside of the enrollment window where the
existing account is taking CPP-A service, ComEd believes that the evidence does not warrant
exempting successor accounts from the enrollment window that is applicable to all other existing
customers where the existing account is not taking CPP-A service, and that any theoretical benefits
of creating the latter special exemption as to successor accounts that involve actual changes in
ownership would be outweighed by the burdens and costs of requiring ComEd to investigate and
distinguish among different types of successor accounts.
In its reply brief, ComEd says there is a third CPP-A issue. According to ComEd, Dynegy
opposes ComEds proposal that CPP-A eligible customers that were on Rates 6, 6L, and 24 that were
migrated to CPP-A service should be allowed to switch to delivery services and obtain supply
service from a RES with 7 days notice. ComEd
177
05-0159
Proposed Order
argues that this feature of ComEds compromise proposal should be approved, on balance,
because of the flexibility it gives to these customers.
ComEd originally proposed that CPP-H customers be required to give 60 days advance notice
before terminating service. ComEd proposed a 60 day notice period in order to balance two
different, and in this case competing, interests of customers flexibility in switching and lower
prices. ComEd claims that customers interests conflict here because the greater the switching
flexibility, the more the uncertainty faced by wholesale suppliers, and thus the greater the risk
that the suppliers will add an increment to their auction bids due to that uncertainty.
ComEd says it is willing to agree to reduce the advance notice period for termination of CPP-H
service to the seven calendar days advance notice required under the existing Direct Access Service
Request (DASR) rules relating to delivery services, provided that the termination of service
occurs only on the customers normally scheduled meter reading date.
Staff and CES argued for a different balance, however, proposing that CPP-H customers be
allowed to terminate that service under the existing DASR rules relating to delivery services.
ComEd responded that it was willing to permit CPP-H customers to terminate that service under the
existing DASR rules, provided that such terminations occurred only on the customers normally
scheduled meter reading date, because off-cycle switching would impose substantial unwarranted
administrative burdens and costs on ComEd. Staff remains opposed to ComEds revised proposal.
ComEd argues that Staff failed to take into account that there may be far greater interest on
the part of customer agents (General Account Agents) in having customers move on to and off of
CPP-H service in the post-transition period, which would mean that off-cycle switching could be far
more burdensome and costly for ComEd after 2006 than Staffs position assumed. According to ComEd,
RESs acting as General Account Agents could potentially drop hundreds of customers and pick them
back up on a calendar month basis or potentially even drop customers and pick them back up within
as little as two weeks. ComEd does not believe it should have the administrative burden placed on
it to deal with such a situation.
ComEd contends that to accommodate off-cycle switching for CPP-H service, it would incur extra
work and costs in its back office, such as the work to coordinate with customers, manual
interventions in information systems, work to coordinate with the billing system, etc. ComEd says
that although in theory an off-cycle switching fee could be set that would enable ComEd to recover
from CPP-H customers that switch off-cycle the costs of the additional burdens imposed on ComEd, no
such fee has been proposed in this Docket. ComEd suggests that if the Commission were to direct
that ComEd permit off cycle switching in relation to CPP-H service, then ComEd would request that
the Order also state or indicate that ComEd may apply an off-cycle switching fee to such switching
subject to its being supported and reviewed in ComEds pending (Docket 05-0597) and future rate
cases.
178
05-0159
Proposed Order
ComEd says while it is willing to accept switching in relation to CPP-H service on the general
DASR timeline, ComEd believes that the case for permitting off-cycle switching in relation to CPP-H
service has not been made, and that the disadvantages of permitting off-cycle switching here
outweigh any benefits.
b. Staffs Position
Staff supports the proposal to allow bundled customers that have not made a supply selection
to remain on bundled service rather to be switched to the hourly service, as ComEd first proposed,
because a customer should not lose bundled service simply because it forgets to make a supply
selection. ComEds proposal to allow former bundled customers to switch to RES service during the
supply period would give a boost to retail competition because it would give RESs much more time
(in fact, the entire supply period) to offer supply deals to bundled customers. Staff recognizes
that this proposal will result in some additional supply uncertainty and thus might lead bidders to
add a premium to their bids. According to Staff, the data presented in Table 4A of CES witness
OConnors rebuttal testimony show that only about one-fourth to one-third of current bundled load
would be eligible to move from CPP-A during the supply period. Thus, Staff argues that this
premium is likely to be small.
ComEd proposed that former bundled customers could move to RES service during the supply
period, but would not be permitted to move to the hourly service. Staff claims that only 63
customers are currently taking ComEds hourly service, and it seems unlikely that customers would
relinquish the security of bundled service to take hourly service. Thus, Staff recommends that the
Commission permit former bundled customers to move to hourly service if the Commission approves
ComEds proposal to allow such customers to move to RES service.
While Staff supports ComEds proposal to allow hourly service customers to move to another
service on seven days notice (rather than 60 days, as ComEd originally proposed), Staff does not
recommend that the Commission approve ComEds proposal to only allow customers that move to the
hourly service to switch on the customers regularly scheduled switch date. Staff argues that very
few customers are likely to switch to the hourly service and ComEd has a tariff in place that
permits customers to switch between services on a date other than their regularly scheduled meter
readings dates. It is Staffs position that until the burden on ComEd of switching hourly service
customers on a non-standard basis becomes excessive, customers should be permitted to switch (and
escape hourly service charges) by paying the non-standard switching fee.
According to Staff, if suppliers were prone to move their customers between supply options in
order to take advantage of price movements, then admittedly ComEds scenario could occur,
potentially putting a strain on ComEds administrative resources. Nevertheless, Staff recommends
that the Commission direct ComEd to allow switching from CPP-H service to other services on dates
other than the customers regularly
179
05-0159
Proposed Order
scheduled meter reading date. Staff argues that requiring customers to remain on CPP-H
service potentially could be very costly for some customers, who would eagerly pay a switching fee
just to move from hourly pricing.
Staff suggests that if General Account Agents even once actually park their customers on CPP-H
service in such a way as to place an undue burden on ComEd, then ComEd should ask the Commission
for permission to place switching restrictions on CPP-H service switches.
Regarding new customers, Staff has no objection to the proposal regarding new customers that
ComEd panel witnesses Alongi and Crurmine offered in their surrebuttal testimony and that ComEd
witness McNeil described as Rule 17 in his surrebuttal testimony. Under this proposal, a new
customer could receive CPP-A service, and a successor customer could only be permitted to take
CPP-A service if its predecessor customer was on the default rate. Staff agrees that customers
that change their corporate name simply to avoid CPP-A charges should not be considered to be new
customers.
c. Dynegys Position
Dynegy recommends that the Commission reject an aspect of ComEds surrebuttal proposal.
Dynegy says that under ComEds alternative presented in surrebuttal, the class of customers
eligible for CPP-A would be expanded down to 400 kW and certain customers in this class would
automatically default to CPP-A service (i.e., would not have to opt-in in order to take such
service) and this same subset of customers would be eligible to switch off of CPP-A service at any
point during the annual period. For this subset of customers, Dynegy says the alternative proposal
essentially creates a 365-day option. Dynegy adds that a 365-day option would be more expensive
than a 75-day or a 30-day option. According to Dynegy, using the same daily premium value
estimated by Dr. Schlaf (.04% per day) the added premium compared to a 30-day option is 13.4%. It
is Dynegys position that given a 75-day option should be rejected because of the added premium for
that lengthened window, it follows with substantially more force that a 365-day window must be
rejected due to the much larger premium.
Dynegy argues that even if this premium only affects the pricing on 25% of the CPP-A load,
this still means that a 3.35% premium might be added to every CPP-A customers bill, a much larger
premium than Staff was willing to advocate with respect to the 75-day window. It is Dynegys
position that even recognizing that ComEd has crafted its surrebuttal proposal as a package deal,
the Commission should reject this aspect (and, if need be, the entire surrebuttal proposal) rather
than foist upon all CPP-A customers such a large premium.
180
05-0159
Proposed Order
d. Commissions Analysis and Conclusions
The first issue relates to new customer accounts electing to take CPP-A service outside the
enrollment window. ComEd and Staff appear to agree that allowing new customers to elect CPP-A
service outside the enrollment window is appropriate and no other party seems to object to this
plan. It is therefore approved. Additionally, during this proceeding there was disagreement
between ComEd and Staff regarding whether the definition of new accounts would permit successor
accounts to existing customers to elect to take CPP-A service outside the enrollment. While it
appears that ComEd and Staff may have reached agreement on this issue, the Commission,
nevertheless, finds ComEds arguments on this issue convincing. The Commission believes it is
appropriate to accommodate new customers and allow them to participate in the competitive retail
market, however, it would be overly burdensome to require ComEd to investigate the whether
successor accounts are actually new customers. As a result, the Commission will not impose this
burden on ComEd and successor accounts will not be exempt from selecting CPP-A service during the
enrollment window adopted in this Order. To the extent Staff is still pursuing this proposal, it
is rejected.
As the Commission understands it, ComEd and Staff advocate a process whereby CPP-A eligible
customers that were on Rate 6, 6L, and Rate 24 that were migrated to the annual default rate can
switch to delivery service and obtain supply service from a RES with 7 days notice. Whereas, they
propose CPP-A eligible customers that were taking delivery service with Rider PPO or ISS (ComEd
supply) and elected the annual default rate must remain for the full annual term. Dynegy objects
to the proposal that would allow Rate 6, 6L and Rate 24 customers to migrate to RES supply outside
the enrollment window.
In essence, ComEd and Staff endorse this open enrollment process because they believe the
benefits for these customers and the competitive retail market exceed any potential increase in
cost that suppliers in the auction will demand. Dynegy takes the opposite view.
In the Commissions view, there is no clear way to compare the costs and benefits to
ratepayers and suppliers that depend on the conclusion reached on this issue. It is clear,
however, that the Commission would like to encourage competition in the retail marketplace.
Additionally, it is clear that suppliers are free to use the available information and develop bid
strategies that are most favorable to them. Thus, the Commission believes it is in the public
interest to adopt the proposed open enrollment process for CPP-A eligible customers that were on
Rate 6, 6L and 24. This result will provide much flexibility to customers but should not adversely
affect bidders as they will be aware of the result and can incorporate it into their bid
strategies.
ComEd has indicated that it is willing to reduce the advance notice period for termination of
CCP-H service from the originally proposed 60 days to seven days under the existing DASR rules.
ComEd, however, believes that termination of CPP-H service should only occur on the customers
normally scheduled meter read date. Staff argues
181
05-0159
Proposed Order
that the off-cycle switches should be allowed and should be governed by the existing delivery
services rules and charges.
The Commission has reviewed the argument of the parties and finds that the proposal to reduce
the notice requirement to terminate CPP-H service from 60 days to seven days reasonable and it is
hereby approved. With respect to off-cycle switching, ComEd is directed to allow customers to
terminate CPP-H service on other than the normally scheduled meter read date. As for fees or
charges associated with off-cycle switching, ComEd will be permitted to assess charges based upon
its effective tariffs. To the extent ComEd demonstrates in an appropriate forum that off-cycle
switching causes ComEd to incur costs, ComEd will be permitted to implement tariffs reflecting such
costs.
In the event ComEd, or any other party, believes additional restrictions on either CPP-H
customers or their agents are necessary, the Commission would be willing to consider any such
additional restrictions in an appropriate forum.
Finally, the Commission rejects Staffs proposal to permit bundled fixed price customers to
move to hourly service at any time during the supply period. Despite having reviewed ComEds
briefs and the surrebuttal testimony of Mr. NcNeil (ComEd Ex. 18.0) ComEds position on this issue
is not clear to the Commission. Nevertheless, the Commission believes adopting Staffs proposal
would be inconsistent with the purpose for enrollment windows adopted herein, might be detrimental
to the competitive retail electric market in Illinois and would enhance opportunities for customers
to game the system to the detriment of auction bidders.
8. Limitations and Contingencies
According to ComEd, the Limitations and Contingencies addresses the contingent competitive
procurement processes to be used in the event of auction under subscription or default under an SFC
resulting from an auction. ComEd states that the open questions are entirely derivative in that
they simply are what conforming changes will be needed to implement the Commissions decisions on
those processes.
Staff states that it and ComEd stipulated to tariff language that would be included in Rider
CPP. Staff says that under the stipulation, should ComEd purchase electricity outside of the
auction, ComEd would first provide Staff a report concerning the circumstances of the purchases.
Staff also says the stipulation provides that ComEd would not have to file the report if the
purchases occurred due to an undersubscription of the auction, and costs incurred in such a
situation could be recovered as if they were incurred under a SFC. According to Staff, the
Commission could open an investigation to determine whether an act or omission of the Company
caused a need for the purchases, whether such acts or omissions were imprudent, and, if so, whether
refunds of any incremental costs (i.e., costs above what would have been paid under the SFCs) would
be appropriate.
182
05-0159
Proposed Order
Except to the extent modified by other conclusions in this Order, the Commission approves the
tariff language stipulated to by ComEd and Staff on the Limitations and Contingencies provisions of
Rider CPP. ComEd is directed to file tariffs that conform to the conclusions contained in this
Order relating to the Limitations and Contingencies provisions of Rider CPP.
9. Translation to Retail Charges
ComEd proposed translation formulae (also referred to as prisms) to translate the
results of the CPP-B and CPP-A auction segments and the potential CPP-H auction into retail Supply
Charges for each Customer Supply Group, as applicable. According to ComEd, the translation
methodology serves to develop ratios that reflect the cost-causation contribution of each Customer
Supply Group to the auction (segment) relating to that group, in each auction cycle. ComEd states
that the ratios take into account usage (including demands), time of use (peak, off-peak periods),
seasonality (summer, and nonsummer periods), and transmission and distribution line losses; and the
ratios also take into account forward market costs for electric energy and generation capacity,
estimated ancillary transmission services, and costs associated with migration risks. ComEd
continues that the methodology applies the ratios to a load weighted average of the clearing prices
resulting from the applicable auction (segment), taking into account seasonal supplier payment
differences, in order to arrive at the retail Supply Charges for the monthly billing periods in
which the charges will be applicable.
10. Customer Supply Group Migration Risk Factor
a. ComEds Position
ComEd originally proposed to include a Migration Risk Factor in the translation methodology
for calculating CPP-B service Supply Charges, at a time when ComEd was proposing that the Large
Load Customer Supply Group would be part of the CPP-B auction segment. ComEd asserts that the
Large Load Customer Group had by far the greatest migration risk impact per MWh, more than twice
that of the next most significant Group while residential customers had the lowest impact.
CES, in its direct testimony, supported the concept of a Migration Risk Factor but proposed
revisions to the Migration Risk Factor ComEd says that would likely result in a greater allocation
of costs to non-residential customers and a lesser allocation of costs to residential customers.
Staff and BOMA, in their respective direct testimony, recommended the elimination of the Migration
Risk Factor, on various grounds. ComEd, in rebuttal testimony, continued to support its original
proposal, while CES, Staff, and BOMA adhered to their respective positions.
ComEd, in surrebuttal, proposed an integrated package of three auction / rate design
changes, two of which were to move the Large Load Customer Supply Group out of CPP-B and into CPP-A
and to eliminate the Migration Risk Factor from the
183
05-0159
Proposed Order
translation methodology for CPP-B. ComEd states that in the interests of narrowing the
issues, it is willing to accept the elimination of the Migration Risk Factor in that scenario.
It is ComEds position that if that integrated proposal were not to be approved, however, then
ComEds formulation of the Migration Risk Factor (not that of CES) should be incorporated within
the CPP B translation methodology.
b. Staffs Position
Staff objected to ComEds original proposal arguing that it is deficient in both theory and
practice. Staff claims it is poor policy because it sends the wrong message to consumers concerning
their role in the development of a competitive electricity marketplace.
Staff further asserts ComEds proposal is counter-productive from an overall cost standpoint
because the factor increases the share of bundled power costs paid by the larger customers that are
most likely to migrate to RES service. Staff also complains that ComEd can identify no other
utility that has implemented a migration risk factor. Staff states that the proposal seeks to
estimate this cost for suppliers indirectly by estimating the value of migration for consumers.
Staff contends that whatever value the migration option offers for consumers, it does not explain
what cost migration risk might impose on suppliers.
According to Staff, ComEds Initial Brief offers no meaningful evidence beyond a statement
that the migration risk factor should be approved in the event the CPP-B auction remains unchanged.
In Staffs view, this leaves the Commission with no basis for adopting the migration risk factor.
Staff claims it has presented numerous compelling arguments explaining why the migration risk
factor should be rejected. Staff believes these arguments give the Commission ample basis to reject
the migration risk proposal whether or not the CPP-B auction pool is reduced.
As for the arguments of CES, Staff claims they amount to speculation on the part of the
witnesses about what drives customer decisions concerning PPO and RES service. (Staff brief at
162) According to Staff, the starting point for the CES position is the assumption that the
migration risk factor is reasonable and CES focuses its attention on why its proposed revisions
should be adopted. Staff says it is CES position that ComEd should have assumed that 100%, rather
than 50%, of PPO load migrates to alternative supply and that ComEd should have assumed that
forward price volatility should have been tied more closely to the auction date. Staff states that
CES proposed to increase the size of the migration risk factor and, thereby, increase the relative
cost of power for larger customers within the CPP-B auction who are most likely to migrate to
alternative supply.
Staff claims that while customers are concerned about price, the decision to receive RES
service is about more than just price. According to Staff, it also involves relying on market
forces, rather than regulation, to ensure the price and quality of the
184
05-0159
Proposed Order
power received. In deciding to migrate to RES service, customers must have confidence that the
market can meet their needs over the longer term. In Staffs view, to argue that this decision is
solely based on price oversimplifies a more complicated decision-making process.
Staff labels as flawed, CES assertion that ComEds approach understates price volatility
which leads to a lower migration risk factor calculation. CES complains that ComEd used too long a
time period (1.5 years) to measure price volatility whereas a shorter time frame would increase
price volatility and raise the migration risk factor. According to Staff, the key factor for
migration risk is not forward price volatility but rather relative power prices of bundled and
RES-supplied power. Staff claims the key question is how volatility impacts the relative prices of
these two service options. According to Staff, neither the Company, nor CES provide any meaningful
answer to this question. In Staffs view, the problem again lies with the estimation approach that
supports the positions of both the Company and CES. Staff believes this further demonstrates why
the Commission should reject the concept of a migration risk factor in its entirety.
c. CES Position
CES expressed support for ComEds proposed translation mechanism because it believes it
appropriately includes an adjustment to reflect the migration risk within each customer group. CES
asserts, however, that the size of the factor should be greater than ComEd proposed. Specifically,
CES supports a higher number by asserting that 100% of Power Purchase Option (PPO) load that
should be considered at risk of migration, rather than 50% under the ComEd proposal. In support
of its position, CES cited movements by customers in and out of PPO and RES service as evidence of
their willingness to switch solely on the basis of price.
CES suggests that ComEds modified customer groupings, as revealed in the Companys
surrebuttal testimony, largely resolves the problem inherent in the development and application of
any migration risk premium allocation. CES says that once the 400 kW to 1 MW customer group is
removed from the CPP-B product and included with the CPP-A product, any migration risk premium that
suppliers might include in the blended product auction price would be smaller and easier to handle,
and any error in managing that allocation would have fewer consequences.
CES states that by expanding the CPP-A product to include the 400 kW to 1 MW customers,
whatever migration risk premium suppliers priced into their bids would be related to and allocated
among customers within that group. This would obviate any need to use the Prism to allocate any
premium as it might be related to this customer group. CES also suggests that the allocation
method in the Prism, as originally advocated by ComEd, relies on historical switching levels rather
than on market expectations of prospective switching by customers under 1 MW. CES favors the
Companys revised proposal, as proposed in surrebuttal testimony, as the inclusion of
185
05-0159
Proposed Order
the 400 kW to 1 MW customers into the CPP-A product group, will isolate any migration risk
premium to that group in the auction itself.
In its reply brief, CES argues that regardless of the customer groupings that the Commission
ultimately adopts, the Commission should direct ComEd to include a properly-calculated migration
risk factor in its translation tariff. CES believes such a migration risk factor is a necessary
element of any translation methodology, and is required to account for prevailing market conditions
at the time bids are formulated and to minimize the volatility of short-term fluctuations in
forward prices due to potential anomalies in market conditions. CES asserts that rather than
eliminating the migration risk factor from the translation methodology for calculating the CPP-B
Supply Charges as proposed by ComEd and Staff, the Commission should order ComEd to revise its
migration risk factor to more accurately account for: (1) the amount of load that is likely to
switch if savings were available; and (2) the volatility associated with the forward price for a
given delivery period.
According to CES, numerous expert witnesses testified on behalf of ComEd, CES, and customer
groups that wholesale suppliers will make assumptions about the migration risk factor, and that
these assumptions will be informed by the observations and experiences of prior switching behavior
of the customers in the ComEd service territory. CES asserts that pretending this risk factor does
not exist will not make it go away. CES claims that ComEds originally-proposed translation
mechanism or Prism appropriately included an adjustment to reflect the migration risk within each
customer group.
CES recommends that the Commission reject the proposals of ComEd and Staff to eliminate a
migration risk factor from the translation methodology for calculating the CPP-B service Supply
Charges and to order ComEd to revise its migration risk factor to more accurately assign costs to
each customer class.
d. BOMAs Position
BOMAs position is that no customer supply group migration risk factor should be used in the
translation of the CPP-B auction prices into retail rates regardless of the customer classes which
are offered the CPP-B auction product. BOMA disputes the validity of ComEds premise that a
customer supply group migration risk factor could be calculated for post-2006 rates for different
customer classes based on switching statistics during the transition period. BOMA argues that
larger customers will want to lock in electricity costs through long-term contracts with
competitive electric suppliers post-2006 since ComEds post-2006 bundled rates will change at least
annually. BOMA asserts that these long-term contracts could significantly change customers
switching behavior post-2006. BOMA believes that the unpredictability of switching between ComEd
and competitive suppliers post-2006 means that ComEds calculation of customer supply group
migration risk factors based on transition period statistics will unfairly shift costs to larger
non-residential customers.
186
05-0159
Proposed Order
In its reply brief, BOMA says ComEd admits that it cannot accurately estimate the supplier
risk premium resulting from migration risks within the CPP-B auction segment but wants approval to
use it anyway if the 400 kW 1MW customer class is included in this segment.
BOMA maintains that ComEd has not provided any empirical evidence that the methodology ComEd
used to formulate its migration risk factor is a reasonable or meaningful estimate of the risk
premium a winning bidder in the auction might add to its supply price to account for migration
risks. BOMA concludes that regardless of whether the Commission approves or rejects ComEds
current proposal to include the 400 kW 1 MW customer class in the CPP-B auction segment, the
Commission should not allow ComEd to use a customer supply group migration risk factor in
translating CPP-B auction prices into retail rates.
e. Commissions Analysis and Conclusions
The Commission has reviewed the record, as well as the arguments of the parties, regarding
migration risk factors. In the Commissions view, it seems entirely logical that the when
developing bidding strategies and prices suppliers will consider the likelihood and level of
possible customer switching. However, the record does not support including a migration risk
factor.
The divergence of opinions regarding the anticipated level of customer switching makes the
Commission uncomfortable in administratively establishing a migration factor. The differences
relate to not only the underlying rationale for estimating customer migration as well as the
resulting estimates of customer migration. The Commission simply does not find the arguments for
adopting a migration factor convincing and the record attempting to quantify future migration is
weak, at best.
Given the record on this issue, the Commission finds it is best to allow suppliers to include
in their bids their expectations of customer migration. At this time, the Commission rejects the
proposals to include an explicit migration risk factor.
11. Market Cost InformationMarket Energy Costs
ComEd proposes to use, within the Market Cost Information component of the formulae, forward
prices for electricity delivered into the Northern Illinois Hub (Ni-Hub), by peak and off-peak
period, for each month for which retail Supply Charges are being determined. According to ComEd,
no witness is advocating use of LMPs and its proposed use of forward price data in the translation
formulae should be approved.
The Commission approves ComEds use of forward price information in the translation formulae.
187
05-0159
Proposed Order
12. Accuracy Assurance Mechanisms and Subsequent
Review/Contingencies
a. ComEds Position
According to ComEd, the Accuracy Assurance Mechanism (AAM) part of Rider CPP is intended to
ensure accurate cost recovery, which benefits customers and the utility alike. The AAM part
provides for a monthly charge or credit (depending on the underlying calculations applicable to any
given month) called the Accuracy Assurance Factor (AAF).
ComEd states that the AAF is composed of two factors, the Customer Demand and Usage (CDU)
Factor and the Contingency Factor (CF). ComEd says the CDU Factor serves to balance the amounts
billed to retail customers taking ComEd supply service with payments made to suppliers as a
function of the contract terms and prices determined in accordance with Rider CPP, and based on
changes in retail customers usage and demands. The need for this factor stems from the fact that
there will be differences between retail customers actual demands and usage and the historical
retail customer demand and usage data used in developing the wholesale to retail translation
ratios. ComEd says the CF addresses the Companys net costs in the event of use of the contingent
wholesale market competitive procurement processes provided for in the Limitations and
Contingencies part of proposed Rider CPP. ComEd states that Rider CPP provides for ComEds
submitting to the Commission, on a monthly basis, informational filings regarding the AAF and the
underlying data and calculations.
Numerous issues relating to the AAM part of Rider CPP have been resolved, subject to the
Commissions approval. Staff and ComEd have reached an accord on ComEds conducting an annual
internal audit of costs and recoveries under Rider CPP and ComEds filing a copy of the report to
Staff by April 30th of each year.
Staff and ComEd also have reached an accord on ComEds filing with the Staff, by April 30th of
each year, an annual report that summarizes the operation of the AAM part for the previous year.
ComEds current understanding is that Staff is amenable to working out the details of the format
and content of ComEds monthly informational filing setting forth the AAFs. ComEds understanding
is that Staff no longer disputes ComEds identification of the particular expense and revenues
Accounts within the Uniform System of Accounts (the USoA) that should be used to record the
components of the AAF calculations. ComEd, in its rebuttal testimony, agreed to modify language of
the AAM part to clarify that certain components of the formulae therein are calculated on an
accrual basis, in accord with Staffs preference. ComEd, in its surrebuttal testimony, accepted
Staffs proposal that ComEd use forecasts in the CDU Factor and CF formulae denominators, with some
limited conforming and related language changes that ComEd says are appropriate and that, as far as
ComEd knows, are not contested by Staff. ComEd and Staff are in partial agreement on the addition
of a factor to the CDU Factor and CF calculations referred to by ComEd as Factor A and by Staff
as Factor O to reflect adjustments for refunds or additional collections,
188
05-0159
Proposed Order
but ComEd and Staff differ in part on both the substance and the name of this factor. ComEd,
in its rebuttal testimony, accepted Staffs proposal to add interest components to the CDU Factor
and the CF. ComEd clarified that it does not propose to include supply-related uncollectibles
expenses in the balancing provided for in the AAM part, addressing a Staff concern. ComEd
clarified that it does not intend to bill the AAF on a prorated basis, addressing another Staff
concern.
ComEd proposed to make its monthly informational filings setting forth the AAFs no later than
the third business day before the monthly billing period in which the AAFs will be applicable.
According to ComEd, Staff, in its direct testimony, proposed that the filings should be postmarked
by the twentieth day of the month before the monthly billing period in which the AAFs will be
applicable. Staff further proposed that if an informational filing were to be submitted after the
twentieth day, then it would be accepted only if it corrected an informational filing that was
filed by that deadline for the same month. Staff also argued that if an informational filing did
not meet those timing criteria, then it would be accepted only if filed as a special permission
filing under 220 ILCS 5/9201(a) and 83 Illinois Administrative Code Part 255. Staff, in its
rebuttal testimony, adhered to those criteria and that legal position, and offered the possible
revision of changing the AAF determination from one made over two months to one made over three
months to give ComEd more time to prepare the filings.
ComEd argues that while this disagreement might seem like a detail, Staffs position, if it
were adopted, would unnecessarily cause serious practical problems for customers as well as the
utility. ComEd claims that to submit the AAF informational filing any sooner may well have the
unintended effect of undermining ComEds efforts to ensure the accuracy of such calculations.
Because of the importance of accurately billing its customers, ComEd says it needs to extensively
test any changes in rates in its billing system prior to the first billing day of the cycle. Under
Staffs proposal, ComEd complains that there would be insufficient time to re-process and re-test
any changes made after the twentieth of the calendar month. Once changes to rates are entered into
the billing system, adjustments to those rates likely could not be processed and tested until the
next billing cycle/month because the testing process must be completed before subsequent changes
could be incorporated. According to ComEd, a filing deadline of the twentieth of the calendar
month would not create sufficient time for the error correction process Staffs proposal
contemplates.
According to ComEd, Staff, after listing dozens of issues as to the AAM part on which ComEd
reached agreement with Staff, appears to criticize ComEd for its unwillingness to compromise on
this particular issue. ComEd says it did not compromise here because its proposed due date is in
the best interests of customers and the utility.
ComEd also says it cannot accept Staffs proposal to extend the lag period to three months.
In light of the fact that the purpose of the AAF is to balance the several billions of dollars of
revenues and expenses that will be incurred annually, ComEd has proposed a process that would
minimize the lag to the shortest period practicable (i.e., a
189
05-0159
Proposed Order
two month lag). ComEd believes it is important for both customers and ComEd to reflect the
appropriate charge or credit through the AAF in as timely a fashion as possible. Therefore, ComEd
believes it would be inappropriate to inject an additional months delay into the process. ComEd
claims that ComEd and Exelon Corporation controls for the calculation and implementation of the
AAFs will ensure that customer bills reflect the appropriate factors. ComEd says such processes
will result in accurate monthly AAF calculations, thereby minimizing the likelihood of such an
occurrence and eliminating the need for lengthy Staff reviews of the monthly informational filings.
In ComEds view, to delay the AAF by a month, in any given month, is needlessly going to cause
either customers or the utility to lose the time value of money, possibly very substantial amounts
in the aggregate, and that would occur every month, one way or the other. ComEd also argues that
delays in implementing CPP-B and CPP A-AAFs could even jeopardize rate stability.
According to ComEd, Staff does not, and cannot, argue that, under ComEds proposal, an error
in an AAF, if such were to occur, will not be corrected. ComEd argues that such an error is highly
unlikely, although, if Staffs proposal led to AAF changes being implemented without extensive
testing, then they would be more likely. ComEd maintains that under its proposal, any such error
will be corrected in the following monthly billing period.
ComEd also asserts that Staffs proposal regarding special permission filings was impractical,
inconsistent with the informational filing process for other Commission-approved formula rates,
such as Rider PPO-MI, is potentially burdensome for both the Commission and the utility and could
force delays in the implementation of monthly AAFs, thereby jeopardizing rate stability.
Additionally, ComEd does not believe that there is any legal basis in 220 ILCS 5/9201(a) and 83
Illinois Administrative Code 255 that mandate Staffs proposed requirement of special permission
filings.
ComEd contends that Staffs special permission reasoning is circular, i.e., it assumes that
the Act requires a special permission filing, but it does not actually show that there is any such
requirement.
ComEd recommends that the Commission reject Staffs proposal for further contested proceedings
and for Commission review of ComEds identification of the Accounts that should be used to record
the components of the AAF calculations, and of the specific sub-Accounts that ultimately will be
created for use in those calculations. ComEd describes Staffs proposal as unprecedented,
unwarranted and unreasonable.
ComEd claims it has identified the correct Accounts in ComEd Ex. 13.2 Revised in accordance
with the USoA, establishing that it is inappropriate and detrimental from an accounting and
internal controls perspective to create the sub-Accounts prematurely (before the CPP auctions) as
Staff proposes, and asserts that Staffs proposal is unjustified, inappropriate, and detrimental.
ComEd further contends that Staff apparently does not now dispute ComEds identification in ComEd
Ex. 13.2 Revised of
190
05-0159
Proposed Order
the particular Accounts that should be used to record the components of the AAF calculations.
In its reply brief, ComEd argues that the language of Rider CPP, not the Accounts or
sub-Accounts that ComEd uses to account for costs and revenues should and does determine which
categories of costs and revenues properly flow through the AAF calculations.
According to ComEd, Staffs observation that some of the Accounts in ComEd Ex. 13.2 (Revised)
will include other costs and revenues that do not belong in the AAF calculation is not relevant.
ComEd maintains that it is the tariff that determines which costs and revenues properly flow
through the AAF calculation. ComEd says it is simply complying with the USoA and that does not
mean that any costs or revenues included in those Accounts, that do not belong in the AAF
calculation, by virtue of those Accounts being listed in ComEd Ex. 13.2 (Revised), become
eligible for inclusion in the calculation.
In ComEds view, Staffs complaint that ComEds proposal does not provide Staff or the
Commission any process by which to contest the future decisions that ComEd makes in determining the
appropriate sub-accounts to flow through the AAF mechanism, is incorrect and ignores ComEds
express commitment to work with Staff on this subject.
ComEd claims that it and Staff are in partial agreement on the addition of a factor to the CDU
Factor and CF calculations referred to by ComEd as Factor A and by Staff as Factor O to
reflect adjustments for refunds or additional collections, but ComEd and Staff differ on both the
substance, in two respects, and the name of this factor. ComEd claims the first substantive
dispute is simple. Staff wishes Factor A to be limited to adjustments made pursuant to a
Commission Order. ComEd believes, however, that Factor A should cover both adjustments made based
on the utility working with Staff to resolve disputed issues without a formal Commission proceeding
and adjustments made pursuant to a Commission Order. ComEd argues that to assume, or require, that
all such disputed issues be resolved through formal proceedings, when they might well be resolved
by Staff and ComEd working together and reaching an accord, would be unnecessary, overly litigious,
and administratively burdensome on ComEd, Staff, and the Commission, and potentially other
stakeholders, and it could unnecessarily delay, possibly for extended periods, the correction of
errors, which may have significant adverse consequences for customers and the utility.
According to ComEd, Staffs Initial Brief has simplified, somewhat, the first substantive
issue, which relates to informal dispute resolution, and the issue of the name of the factor.
Staff agrees that, if the Commission agrees with ComEds position, that Staff and ComEd should be
allowed to attempt to resolve any disputes regarding AAF calculations on an informal basis, then
the adjustment factor may then be named Factor A. ComEd says Staff argues, however, that, if the
Commission agrees with Staffs position, that resolution of such disputes should not be allowed on
an informal
191
05-0159
Proposed Order
basis, and that they should only be resolved through the automatic annual docketed
reconciliation proceedings, then the adjustment factor should be called Factor O for ordered.
In ComEds view, it is not clear why Staff has coupled the question of whether Staff and ComEd
should be allowed to attempt to resolve any disputes regarding AAF calculations on an informal
basis with the question of whether there should be automatic annual docketed reconciliation
proceedings. ComEd sees no reason that such disputes cannot or should not be resolved informally
when possible, even if, hypothetically, there were to be such proceedings. According to ComEd, the
evidence shows that: (1) Factor A should cover both adjustments made based on the utility working
with Staff to resolve disputed issues without a formal Commission proceeding and adjustments made
pursuant to a Commission Order, if any; (2) to assume, or require, that all such disputed issues be
resolved through formal proceedings only would be unnecessary, overly litigious, and
administratively burdensome on ComEd, Staff, and the Commission, and potentially other
stakeholders; and (3) such a requirement could unnecessarily delay, possibly for extended periods,
the correction of errors, which may significantly harm customers and the utility.
ComEd says the gist of the second substantive dispute relating to Factor A also is simple.
ComEd proposed that Factor A permit ComEd to amortize adjustments over multiple effective periods
with interest. Staff objected, arguing that the only Commission should determine the amortization
period. ComEd states that Staffs position assumes, however, that all possible Factor A
adjustments will be litigated to a final Order in front of the Commission, a proposition with which
ComEd does not agree. ComEd believes its proposed language should be approved, unless the
Commission determines that the sole method of dealing with such disputed issues should be a
contested case before the Commission.
ComEd asserts that Staffs Initial Brief did not expressly address the second substantive
dispute relating to Factor A, whether Factor A should permit ComEd to amortize adjustments over
multiple effective periods with interest (interest is included because Staff proposed it).
According to ComEd, Staff presumably agrees, however, that Factor A should permit such, if the
Commission approves ComEds position on allowing informal as well as formal dispute resolution.
According to ComEd, the disagreement over the name of Factor A / Factor O reflects the
underlying substantive dispute regarding whether the sole method of dealing with Factor A
adjustments should be a contested case before the Commission. Staff prefers Factor O because O
stands for ordered, and opposes Factor A because it is a term in 83 Illinois Administrative Code
Part 525, Section 525.50, relating to purchase gas adjustment (PGA) clauses. ComEd disagrees
with the former, and does not believe there is any actual likelihood of confusing it with a gas
utility with a PGA clause. ComEd believes that A for adjustment makes the most sense, but is
willing to accommodate Staff by using another letter if there truly is a confusion concern,
provided
192
05-0159
Proposed Order
that it should not be O unless the Commission approves Staffs underlying substantive
position on resolving all such matters through Commission Orders.
In its reply brief, ComEd says that with respect to Factor A in the AAM part, Staff
mistakenly listed conditional agreements on language as unconditional agreements on the underlying
substantive issues.
ComEd states that if the Commission agrees that informal as well as formal resolution of
issues relating to possible Factor A adjustments are appropriate, then the Commission also should
approve ComEds position that the interest component of Factor A should run from when the erroneous
AAF was applied through when it was corrected. ComEd claims that Staffs position, that interest
should run only from the date of the Commission Order through the correction of the AAF assumes
Staffs view regarding the sole method of dispute resolution here and, also, would seem to be
inconsistent with the rationale for an interest component.
ComEd recommends that the Commission approve Staffs and ComEds final revised proposal
regarding review of Supply Charges and AAFs, which involves proposed language for the CPP Timeline
section of the Competitive Procurement Process part of Rider CPP, on Original Sheet No. 269.
Staffs and ComEds proposed language permits, among other things, Commission review of
calculations of Supply Charges and AAFs and of whether ComEd has included only those costs
authorized to be included by the Commissions Order in this Docket, and also permits appropriate
relief, including refunds, as stated more specifically in that language. ComEd says Staffs
witness confirmed that the final proposed language is appropriate.
ComEd also recommends that the Commission approve Staffs and ComEds final revised proposal
regarding review in certain contingent scenarios. According to ComEd, the additional language,
which is found in ComEd Cross Ex. 11, requires ComEd to provide reports to Staff, and provides an
opportunity to review, informally and, on the Commissions own motion or upon complaint, formally,
actions and omissions taken by ComEd, when ComEd procures full requirements electric supply under
the Limitations and Contingencies part, when not due to an under subscription or a volume
reduction, as stated more specifically in that language. The additional language addresses the
concerns raised by Staff and provides for more expansive reporting and Commission review than ComEd
originally proposed and also than ComEd proposed in its rebuttal testimony.
b. Staffs Position
Staff witness Selvaggio made various proposals regarding the tariff language for the Accuracy
Assurance Mechanisms proposed by the Company in its Proposed ILL. C. C. No. 4, Original Sheet No.
291; the formula to calculate the CDU Factor for the CPP Auction-Blended Segment and the CPP
Auction-Annual Segment (Proposed ILL. C. C. No. 4, Original Sheet Nos. 291 and 292); the
calculation of the CDU Factor for the CPP-H Auction Segment (Proposed ILL. C. C. No. 4, Original
Sheet No. 292); and the
193
05-0159
Proposed Order
formula for the Contingency Factor (CF) (Proposed ILL. C. C. No. 4, Original Sheet No. 293)
in direct testimony. Staffs brief identifies those proposals that ComEd accepted.
When a contingency circumstance or the lack of a CPP-H auction requires ComEd to procure
contingent energy on the spot market and incur ancillary service transmission expenses, Staff
agreed that it would be appropriate for ancillary service transmission expenses and recorded in
Account 566, Miscellaneous Transmission Expenses, to be recovered through the AAF as indicated on
ComEd Exhibit 13.2 Revised rather than through Rider TS CPP as had been originally proposed by
Staff.
After ComEd filed its surrebuttal testimony, Staff and ComEd reached a mutual agreement on
acceptable language for Original Sheet No. 269, which was admitted into evidence without objection
as Joint Ex. 1. As a result, Staff recommends that the Commission adopt the language concerning
Commission oversight in Original Sheet No. 269 as agreed to by Staff and ComEd as set forth in
Joint Ex. 1.
ComEd proposed that its monthly AAF informational filings and supporting workpapers be filed
at least three business days prior to the start of the monthly billing period to which they are
applied. Staff claims that the complexity of the information in the filings and the possibility of
errors forms the basis for its opposition to the three business day filing date proposal. Staff
believes that a three day review period would not provide sufficient time for Staff to complete its
review and for the Company to resubmit its filing if an error was detected. Staff proposed that
ComEds monthly AAF filings be postmarked by the 20th day of the filing month. Staff further
proposed that any filings postmarked after the 20th of the filing month be accepted only if
submitted as a special permission filing under the provision of Section 9-201(a) of the Act and 83
Ill. Adm. Code 255.
With respect to the filing date dilemma, Staff believes it has proposed a sensible solution to
ComEds problems. Staff suggested that ComEd use a three month lag rather than a two month lag in
using data for the AAF computation. Staff says Rider CPP as filed provides that for any filing
month, ComEds AAF calculation would be based on actual cost data for the second preceding month.
For example, under ComEds proposal, an AAF filing for the monthly rate to be billed in April 2007
(i.e., filing made at the end of March 2007) would be based on actual costs for February 2007.
Under Staffs 20th day of the filing month proposal, the April billing rate would be filed on March
20, 2007. Staff states that under ComEds proposal, the April billing rate would be filed no
earlier than March 28, 2007. Since ComEd is stating that the twentieth of the month does not allow
sufficient time to perform the AAF calculation, change its billing system and make the required
filing with the Commission, the appropriate solution to address Staffs concerns and ComEds
concerns would be for ComEd to use a three-month lag in the data for its AAF computation. Staff
says in the above example, this means ComEd would use data from the third prior month, or January
2007, for the April 2007 AAF filing. Staff contends that a three-month lag would
194
05-0159
Proposed Order
allow ComEd additional time to gather the necessary data, test its billing system and make the
required Commission filing.
Staff takes exception to ComEds assertion that Staffs position, if it were adopted, would
cause serious practical problems for customers as well as the utility. Staff asserts that ComEds
overbroad argument must be read critically. Staff claims the problem with this purported fact
which is the basis for ComEds position is that ComEd has failed to substantiate it in the
record. Staff contends that ComEd has yet to identify or discuss any of those serious practical
problems it claims will result from the Staff proposal.
According to Staff, it is curious that ComEd continues to oppose Staffs recommendations, when
such proposal would resolve the problems that would, according to ComEd, prevent it from filing on
the 20th day of the filing month. Staff asserts that during cross-examination, the ComEd witness
agreed that the use of Staffs proposed three month lag of actual data in performing the monthly
AAF calculation would provide the following benefits: allow additional time to complete its
accounting close; allow additional time to obtain the components of the monthly AAF calculation;
and allow additional time to extensively test its billing system.
Staff complains that ComEd has failed to offer any alternative proposal to address the
concerns expressed. Staff argues that because ComEd has provided no legitimate reason for opposing
Staffs solution, the only conclusion to be drawn is that ComEd is opposed to any review or
verification, by any party, at any time, of the charges billed and recoveries received under Rider
CPP. Staff says such a conclusion would be consistent with ComEds opposition to an annual
docketed reconciliation proceeding. Staff suggests ComEd does not want any review of its
competitive auction process charges and recoveries. In Staffs view, ComEd believes its charges,
its AAF computation, and its reconciliation should be accepted on its face.
Staff asserts that four Illinois gas utilities, Illinois Gas Company, Ameren IP, Interstate
Power Company and South Beloit Water Gas and Electric Company in their monthly PGA filings used a
three-month lag in incorporating actual data. Staff further argues that a three-month lag would
allow ComEd additional time to complete its accounting close processes and would provide ComEd
additional time so that the components of the calculation were readily available. Finally, Staff
claims a three-month lag would provide additional time for ComEd to extensively test its billing
system.
Staff claims that Ameren, in its companion procurement dockets (05-0160/0161/0162 (consol.)),
has agreed to file the required monthly informational filings by the 20th day of the filing month.
Staff recommends that the Commission require ComEd to modify its Rider CPP so that its monthly AFF
informational filing are filed no later than the 20th day of the filing month.
Under Staffs proposal, any AAF filings postmarked after the 20th of the filing month but
prior to the first day of the effective month would be accepted only if its
195
05-0159
Proposed Order
purpose is to correct an error or errors from a previous filing for the same effective month.
Any other filings postmarked after that date would be accepted only if submitted as a special
permission filing under Section 9-201 of the Act and the notice requirements pursuant to 83 Ill.
Adm. Code 255.
ComEd opposed Staffs proposed late AAF filing requirements, in part, because it believes such
requirements are inconsistent with the informational process approved for other formula rates, such
as Rider PPO-MI, because ComEd does not need specific Commission approval to file its monthly AAF
filing past the due date, and because Staffs proposal is potentially burdensome on both the
Commission and ComEd.
Staff says it is not aware of any language in Rider PPO-MI that waives any requirement of the
Act, including Section 9-201(a), for ComEd. Second, regardless of whether it may be a potential
burden or not, Staff argues that it and ComEd have a duty to comply with the provisions of the Act.
Lastly, Staff claims that eliminating Commission approval in this instance would be inconsistent
with the Commissions practice with respect to the current operations of other riders, i.e., the
Fuel Adjustment Clause (FAC) and Purchased Gas Adjustment Clause (PGA). According to Staff,
any utility that submits its monthly FAC or PGA filing after the due date can only bill a
late-filed-rate after it makes a Section 9-201(a) request and receives Commission approval.
It is Staffs position that the Commissions order in this proceeding should require ComEd to
modify Rider CPP so that any monthly informational AAF filing postmarked after the 20th day of the
filing month will be accepted only if it corrects an error (or errors) from a previous filing for
the same effective month. Staff proposes that any other filings postmarked after the 20th day of
the filing month would be accepted only if submitted as a special permission filing under Section
9-201(a) of the Act.
According to Staff, if the Commission does not approve the recommendation for the Commission
to initiate annual proceedings to reconcile the cost of full requirements electric supply purchased
with revenues recorded, Rider CPP should be modified to give the Commission authority to determine
the revenue and cost sub-accounts that are to be included as components of the AAF Rate.
In Staffs view, the procedure is necessary in order for the Commission and all interested
parties to know what revenues and costs are supposed to constitute the components of the AAF
calculation. Staff believes that unless there is an automatic annual reconciliation proceeding,
the Commission may not have the opportunity to review the revenue and cost components that
formulate the AAF rate each year. With the knowledge of what costs ComEd intends to recover as its
true costs, the Commission is assured that ComEd is recovering no more and no less of its true
costs through the accuracy assurance mechanism.
ComEd implies that the identification of costs to be recoverable through the AAF will be
readily apparent and without issue as ComEd intends to track the cost
196
05-0159
Proposed Order
components of the AAF Algorithms by supplier, and perhaps by tranche, in sufficient detail as
to be readily auditable by Staff. However, Staff maintains that the identification of costs to be
recoverable through the AAF is not readily apparent as more than just the cost of power supply will
be recovered through the AAF.
As an alternative to Staffs proposed procedure, ComEd has offered to meet with Staff when the
necessary information is available and ComEd has determined the appropriate sub-accounts in order
to facilitate Staffs understanding and review of the decisions that ComEd made in setting up such
accounts. However, Staff believes ComEds proposal does not provide Staff or the Commission any
process by which to contest the future decisions that ComEd makes in determining the appropriate
sub-accounts to flow through the AAF mechanism. Staff maintains that ComEds process is informal,
vague and insufficient to provide Staff and other parties assurance that ComEd would be recovering
no more and no less than the procurement costs through Rider CPP.
In Staffs view, ComEds Initial Brief and draft order are somewhat misleading to the extent
they represent that Staff no longer disputes ComEds identification of the particular expense and
revenue accounts within the Uniform System of Accounts that should be used to record the components
of the AAF calculations. Staff is puzzled by ComEd in this regard, as the transcript reference
provided (Tr., pp. 1123-1129) does not support the claim intended.
Staff states that in rebuttal testimony, Staff witness Selvaggio maintained her position that
tariff language should be modified to give the Commission authority to determine the revenue and
cost accounts that are to be used to calculate the AAF. Staff adds that during cross examination,
Ms. Selvaggio did not change her position. She testified as having some difficulty understanding
how some of the accounts identified by ComEd on ComEd Ex. 13.2 Revised were appropriate, but that
she was unaware of any accounts that should be listed that was not included on ComEd Ex. 13.2
Revised. Staff states that when asked whether she agreed that ComEd had limited the number of
accounts under the USOA to be considered in the calculation from hundreds down to 16, Ms. Selvaggio
expressed concern that two of the accounts listed, Account 232 Accounts Payable and Account 234
Accounts Payable to Associated Companies, do not limit the expenses and cash disbursements that
would be eligible to flow through the AAF Factor as all expenses of the Company run through those
accounts including those costs that would be unrelated to the auction. (Staff reply brief at 82,
citing Tr. 1124-1126) Staff contends that the only thing to which Ms. Selvaggio did agree was that
Account 566 Miscellaneous Transmission Expenses seems to be appropriately listed on ComEd Exhibit
13.2.
Staff continues to dispute the identification of particular expense and revenue accounts
within the USOA that should be used to record the components of the AAF calculations. Staff argues
that absent an automatic annual reconciliation of costs and revenues included in the AAF, the
Commission must have the authority to review the
197
05-0159
Proposed Order
cost and revenue accounts that ComEd proposes to be considered in the AAF calculation.
Staff says ComEd complains that sub-Accounts cannot be created prematurely as Staff proposes.
Staff asserts, however, that it never proposed that the sub-Accounts should be created before the
Auction. Staff agrees that it is best to create the accounts after the Auction has occurred and
has proposed tariff language that provides for ComEd to make a compliance filing in Docket No.
05-0159, with notice to all parties on the service list, within 30 days after the first auction is
completed. According to Staff, the compliance filing would include the list of sub-accounts and
sub-account descriptions to be used to record such billings and costs.
Staff agrees with ComEd that its proposal for further hearings that would allow the Commission
to review the accounts that should be included in the AAF calculations may be unprecedented, but
Staff contends Rider CPP is also unprecedented. Staff argues that without its proposal, the
Commission will be ignorant as to the costs and revenues ComEd intends to include in the AAF
mechanism to be recovered from helpless ratepayers.
To better reflect Staffs position, Staff provided specific language changes that it believes
should be made to the description of Staffs position as reflected in ComEds draft order.
Staff recommended that the Companys Factor A component of the CDU and CF Formulas be renamed
Factor O to avoid confusion as to the representation of Factor A. Staff agrees that the
designation for the Adjustment Factor is dependent on whether the Commission accepts the
recommendation for an automatic annual reconciliation.
Staff states that ComEd agreed to file annual reports and perform internal audits consistent
with Staff recommendations.
In its reply brief, Staff states that ComEd would like Factor A/O to include adjustments that
the Company deems to be appropriate without having to obtain Commission approval. In contrast,
Staff advocates that Factor A/O should be limited to adjustments made pursuant to a Commission
order. According to Staff, ComEd complains that to require all adjustments to be made pursuant to
a Commission order would be unnecessary, overly litigious, and administratively burdensome.
However, Staff maintains that it is imperative that only adjustments ordered by the Commission be
allowed to impact the rate in order to preserve the integrity of the AAF mechanism. Staff argues
that if ComEd is allowed to inject unknown variables into the calculation, the AAF rates will be
dubious. In Staffs view, only a Commission order provides the documentation that an adjustment
was evaluated sufficiently to warrant recognition in the AAF rate. It appears to Staff that ComEd
would prefer the Commission not to be involved whatsoever in reviewing the costs and revenues that
are included in the AAF mechanism.
198
05-0159
Proposed Order
Also in its reply brief, Staff states that ComEd proposes to amortize adjustments
included in Factor A/O as it sees fit. Staff recommends that the Commission reject this proposal.
It is Staffs position that the Commission should make that determination in its order that
authorizes the adjustment based on the particular circumstances of the adjustment.
|
c. |
|
Commissions Analysis and Conclusions |
The Commission directs ComEd to annually conduct an internal audit of costs and
recoveries under Rider CPP and to provide a copy of the report to the Manager of the Accounting
Department and the Director of the Financial Analysis Division by April 30th of each
year. Additionally, the Commission directs ComEd to annually prepare a report that summarizes the
operation of the AAM for the previous year and to provide a copy of the report to the Manager of
the Accounting Department and the Director of the Financial Analysis Division by April
30th of each year. The other areas of agreement between Staff and ComEd, as identified
in Staffs initial brief at pages 165-170, are also approved.
ComEd cites the substantial amounts of money at issue in support of its proposal to file the
AAF informational statement three business days before the monthly billing period. The Commission,
however, believes that the magnitude of dollars at issue justifies not only providing ComEd with
adequate time to prepare its informational filing but also for Staff to review the filing. In
executing its obligation to protect ratepayers, the Commission finds that to ensure the accuracy of
AAF an appropriate review process must be in place. The Commission concludes that Staffs proposal
is superior to ComEds and provides proper protections to ratepayers.
While it is unquestioned that a certain amount of work will be necessary for ComEd to prepare
the AAF informational filings, it is also true that a certain, though lesser, amount of work will
be necessary to review the filings. Stated simply, the Commission does not believe ComEds
proposal strikes a reasonable balance. While it may be in ComEds best interest to allocate
virtually all of the available time to preparing the AAF informational report, the Commission
believes it is the public interest to ensure adequate time is available for the Staff to review
ComEds filing.
While it is not determinative on this point, the Commission observes that in Docket 05-0160 et
al, the Ameren Companies do not object to making filings substantively similar to the ones at issue
here by the twentieth business day of each month. The Commission finds it difficult to accept that
the Ameren Companies are vastly more efficient, technically more competent or in possession of
vastly more resources than ComEd. The Commission rejects ComEds proposal and is convinced ComEd,
like the Ameren Companies, will be able to effectively and efficiently prepare the informational
filings by the twentieth day of each month. Thus, having reviewed the arguments of the parties,
the Commission concludes that ComEd will be required to make its monthly AAF informational filings
by the twentieth day of the month.
199
05-0159
Proposed Order
Because the Commission has adopted Staffs primary proposal, a ruling on the merits of Staffs
alternative proposal is not necessary.
The Commission turns next to whether informational filings that are postmarked after the
twentieth day of the month must be submitted as informational filings. The Commission finds little
if any support for Staffs position in Part 255 or Part 425. Staff did not identify any specific
provision in these rules in support of its proposal and the Commission finds none. Part 524, the
rules governing the PGA clause, however, is a different matter. Section 525.10(c) essentially
mirrors Staffs proposal in this case. It requires filings to be postmarked by the twentieth day
of the filing month, states that a filing postmarked after the twentieth will only be accepted if
it corrects an error or errors from a timely filed report and requires other reports postmarked
after the twentieth day to be filed as a special permission request.
Staff, again, does not cite specific language in Section 9-201 of the Act in support of its
proposal and ComEd asserts there is none. However, the first sentence states, Unless the
Commission otherwise orders, and except as otherwise provided in this Section, no change shall be
made by any public utility in any rate or other charge or classification, or in any rule,
regulation, practice or contract relating to or
affecting any rate or other charge, classification or service, or in any privilege or
facility, except after 45 days notice to the Commission and to the public as herein provided.
The Act goes on to state, The Commission, for good cause shown, may allow changes without
requiring the 45 days notice herein provided for, by an order specifying the changes so to be made
and the time when they shall take effect and the manner in which they shall be filed and
published.
Thus, the Act specifically contemplates what is proposed here. That is, ComEd would be
permitted, on less than 45 days notice, to change its charges for electric service as provided for
in this order. In the Commissions view, either ComEds proposal or Staffs proposal could be
adopted depending upon which is more just and reasonable and which is in the public interest.
Even though this Order adopts Staffs proposal that AAF informational statements bear a
postmark of the twentieth day or earlier, in the absence of Staffs special permission filing
proposal, there would be no enforcement measure for late filings. The idea that ComEd could simply
miss the filing date adopted in this Order and still change its rates based upon a late filed AAF
informational statement, which could have extremely limited review, is troubling to the Commission.
As the Commission understands ComEds proposal, while not what ComEd plans, this is exactly what
could happen. As previously stated, the Commission believes that to ensure the accuracy of AAF an
appropriate review process and mechanism must be in place. The Commission concludes that any
monthly AAF report postmarked after the twentieth of the month but prior to the first day of the
effective month will be accepted only if it corrects an error or errors from a timely filed report
for the same effective month. Any other report postmarked after that date will be accepted only if
submitted as a special permission request under the provisions of Section 9-201(a) of the Act.
200
05-0159
Proposed Order
The record supports a finding that it is premature to identify the revenue and cost
sub-accounts that are to be included in the AAF. The Commission appreciates Staffs concerns that
only proper revenue and costs should be included in the AAF. As a result, regardless of whether
annual reconciliation proceedings are needed, the Commission believes Staffs recommendation for a
compliance filing is sound. To improve the benefits derived from such a filing, the Commission
directs ComEd to meet informally with Staff before it makes the compliance filing in an effort to
mutually establish the proper revenue and cost sub-accounts that should be included in the AAF.
The Commission directs ComEd to make the compliance filings, as proposed by Staff, within 60 days
after the first auction is completed. In the Commissions view, this should provide ComEd
sufficient time to identify the appropriate sub-accounts, meet with Staff and prepare the
compliance filing. The Commission does not believe it is necessary, at this time, to require a
docketed proceeding to establish the list of sub-accounts. In the event Staff or any other party
is not satisfied with the content of ComEds compliance filing, the Commission would be willing to
reconsider the need for a docketed proceeding at that time.
While the Commission appreciates Staffs desire for the Commission to maintain control over
Factor A/O and the accounting for procurement costs and revenues, the Commission believes it is
reasonable for Factor A/O to accommodate both Commission ordered adjustments as well as adjustments
agreed to by Staff and ComEd. The Commission concludes this is an appropriate process by which the
CDU and CF formulas track costs and revenues as accurately as possible. To the extent Staff does
not agree with a Factor A/O adjustment proposed by ComEd, such a proposal would not be resolved and
should not be reflected in the CDU or CF formulas. The Commission notes that elsewhere in this
Order, the Commission has determined that annual docketed reconciliations are appropriate to ensure
procurement costs and revenues are properly accounted for. This annual process will serve to
ensure that ComEd does not abuse the discretion granted here with respect to Factor A/O.
Consistent with this conclusion, the Commission adopts ComEds proposed name for Factor A.
ComEd and Staff are in disagreement over whether ComEd should be permitted to amortize
adjustments included in Factor A over multiple periods in the absence of a Commission order
establishing an appropriate amortization period. In the Commissions view, Staffs position on
this issue stems in largely, if not entirely, from its position that only Commission ordered
adjustments are appropriate. Immediately above the Commission has rejected Staffs arguments in
favor of Commission only ordered adjustments. Similarly, the Commission believes it is appropriate
to allow ComEd the discretion to
amortize adjustments included in Factor A over multiple periods. The Commission believes such
a result will contribute to rate stability and is in the best interests of ratepayers.
ComEd and Staff also disagree about the starting point for calculating interest resulting from
an incorrect AAF. Again, this issue seems, at least to some extent, derivative from previous
issues. The Commission concludes that the interest
201
05-0159
Proposed Order
component of Factor A should run from when the
erroneous AAF was applied through when it was corrected. The Commission believes this result is
fair to both ComEd and ratepayers regardless of the direction of the error. In fact, the
Commission believes that any other application of interest would be inherently unfair and would
improperly penalize either ComEd or ratepayers, depending on the direction of the error.
|
13. |
|
Alternative Proposals re Service to Self-Generation Customers |
According to IIEC, ComEd proposes to serve self-generation customers with hourly price
service. Under ComEds proposal, self-generation customers would include non-residential customers
with generation capacity on their premises of 100 kW or greater utilizing such generation for any
purposes other than emergency purposes, including independent power producers and Qualifying
Facilities. ComEd has indicated that in its delivery service rate case filing, demand charges for
hourly pricing customers, including self-generation customers, will be applied for each month in
which a customer is receiving capacity through the CPP-H auction. The charge will be a per kW-month
charge based on each customers load as established during the previous summer. Under ComEds
proposal, hourly pricing customers per kW-month charges are set during the five highest peaks in
PJM during the previous summer.
IIEC states that Qualifying Facilities under the Public Utilities Regulatory Policies Act of
1978 (PURPA) are considered self-generation customers under ComEds proposal. IIEC says under
ComEds proposal they would be assessed monthly charges based on their demand at the time of the
five highest peaks in PJM for the previous summer.
IIEC asserts that self-generating customers generally have a very low load factor. IIEC
claims they generally only draw energy from the utility during limited periods of the year, which
are mostly confined to maintenance outages taken during off-peak times of the year. It is IIECs
position that capacity charges for self-generation customers should reflect their ability to
schedule generation maintenance during off-peak periods of the year and the low probability of
outages during peak system load conditions or simultaneous with other self-generators outages.
IIEC claims that ComEds existing Rate 18 Standby Service is an example of a rate that is
intended to reflect these PURPA principles.
IIEC recommends the Commission require ComEd to modify its proposed Rider CPP provisions for
hourly pricing customers to either: a) bill self-generating customers taking hourly pricing service
for capacity on a per kW-day basis on those days energy is actually taken from ComEd; or b) adjust
self-generating customer capacity charges through a rate translation process to reflect the low
likelihood that all such customers will experience generation outages at the same time, at the time
of system peak, or both, and their ability to commit to performing generation maintenance during
off-peak periods of the year.
202
05-0159
Proposed Order
IIEC states that under the per kW-day approach, self-generation customers only pay for
capacity on days on which they draw energy from the utility. IIEC claims this properly avoids
having these customers pay for capacity when they are not placing a demand on the system. IIEC
further asserts that this is consistent with the fact that it is unlikely forced outages for one
standby customer will occur at the same time as forced outages for other standby customers or at
the system peak, or both.
According to IIEC, the hourly pricing of energy for these customers acts as a very strong
incentive for self-generating customers to adequately maintain their self-generation facilities to
minimize the risk of
forced outages when demand for capacity is high and to perform maintenance outages during
periods when the demand for capacity is low. IIEC says this incentive derives from the fact the
hourly energy prices will be based on PJM Locational Marginal Prices (LMP) that can be $1,000 per
MWh (i.e., $1 per kWh) or higher, during periods when capacity is in great demand. IIEC states
that the per kW-day capacity charge approach is consistent with that proposed by the Ameren
Companies in Docket Nos. 05-0160, 05 0161 and 05-0162 for their self-generating customers.
IIEC states that the self-generation customers demand charge under ComEds proposal would not
be based on the calculated probability of that self-generation customer experiencing an outage
during a particular period. IIEC claims that ComEds proposal basically exposes self-generation
customers to exorbitant capacity charges if they have the misfortune of having a forced outage
during one of the five hours that are used to determine capacity responsibilities within PJM. In
IIECs view, ComEds proposal fails to recognize self-generating customers as a group are very
unlikely to simultaneously experience outages during the system peak. IIEC argues that individual
customers under the ComEd proposal are not given the benefit of group diversity. According to
IIEC, a just and reasonable capacity charge for these customers would recognize the costs of
covering the risk of a forced outage by any one of them during the period capacity obligations are
set.
In response to ComEd, IIEC says it has not relied on mistaken interpretations and assumptions.
IIEC asserts that Mr. Dauphinais rebuttal testimony made it clear that ComEds clarifications in
rebuttal testimony did not fully address the unjustness and unreasonableness of applying a
customers load established during the previous summer as its billing units under ComEds proposed
Rider CPP per kW-month charge. IIEC also claims it has not neglected the potential effect of using
five of the summer peak hours of the previous summer rather than just a single hour.
IIEC maintains that it considered any possible mitigating effect of the other four peak summer
hours. IIEC also maintains that ComEd has ignored FERC requirements for those self-generation
customers that are designated as Qualifying Facilities under PURPA in regard to sales of backup
power or maintenance power.
203
05-0159
Proposed Order
IIEC argues that its proposal is one that is consistent with federal law and regulation. IIEC
believes ComEd should be required to adopt a per kW-day billing approach for demand for hourly
pricing customers, including self-generation customers as Ameren has done in Docket No. 05-0160, et
al. If the Commission chooses not to adopt that approach, IIEC wants the Commission to require
ComEd to adjust self-generating customer capacity charges through a rate translation process to
reflect the low likelihood that all such customers will experience generation outages at the same
time, at the time of system peak, or both; and the ability of such customers to commit to
performing generation maintenance during off-peak periods of the year.
ComEd recommends that the Commission reject IIECs recommendation that ComEd either (1)
charge self-generating customers on a dollars and cents per kilowatt-day basis or (2) create a new
translation process for self-generating customers.
ComEd argues that its approach is consistent with the determination of the auction suppliers
capacity obligations for each of ComEds bundled service customers under PJM and, in turn, ComEds
financial responsibilities under the CPP-H Supplier Forward Contract.
ComEd describes as deficient IIECs concern about the impact of a customers experiencing a
single forced outage under peak load conditions, while ignoring the fact that in the wholesale
markets administered by PJM, the impact of any single outage on one of the five peak days would be
mitigated by good performance on the other four days, and IIECs proposing to socialize the total
capacity cost of self-generating customers amongst all self-generating customers, including forcing
it on independent power producers, by allocating the aggregate capacity obligation for the group on
a pro rata basis to each
individual customer, which is tantamount to a self-insurance scheme, a scheme that such
customers could voluntarily enter into if they choose, but which should not be imposed on them by
Commission fiat.
According to ComEd, IIEC implies that 18 C.F.R. § 295.305(c) requires or supports its position
or its alternative position, but IIEC never explains or shows how ComEds proposal is inconsistent
with the cited legal provision.
ComEd states that while IIEC emphasizes the ability of some self generating customers to
schedule generation maintenance during off peak periods and the low probability of outages during
system peaks or simultaneous with other self generating customers outages, under ComEds proposal,
such customers demands are determined based on five different peak days of the previous year, not
a single peak. ComEd claims this is consistent with the costs those customers will cause ComEd to
incur from wholesale suppliers. ComEd also contends that it appears to be consistent with the
legal provision IIEC cites.
204
05-0159
Proposed Order
|
c. |
|
Commissions Analysis and Conclusions |
The Commission rejects IIECs proposal to bill self-generating customers on a per kW-day
basis on those days energy is actually taken from ComEd. The record shows, contrary to IIECs
arguments, that this proposal would result in charges that bear no relationship to costs imposed on
the system. IIECs proposal for a translation process must be rejected for similar reasons; it
would result in movement away from a system under which those who impose costs on the system bear
those costs. ComEds proposal is reasonable and is hereby adopted.
|
14. |
|
Alternative Proposals re Interruptible Service (ALM and Non-ALM Demand Response) |
According to IIEC, ComEds auction does not explicitly provide for demand response
through interruptible electric service. Instead, ComEd apparently intends to simply continue its
existing Rider CLR Capacity-Based Load Response and System Reliability Program. IIEC asserts
that demand response is critical for mitigating very high market prices and maintaining supply
adequacy during periods when supply adequacy is very tight.
IIEC says that PJM offers an Active Load Management (ALM) Credit Program, an Emergency Load
Response Program and an Economic Load Response Program (the latter two collectively being the
non-ALM Programs). IIEC claims that the ALM Credit Program is best applied in the context of
hourly pricing where capacity and energy can be clearly separated. According to IIEC, non-ALM
Programs are better applied to customers taking service at a fixed price, since these customers are
generally shielded from real-time locational marginal prices.
IIEC asserts that Rider CLR is inefficient in that it requires customers first to purchase
unneeded capacity, and then only provides a credit based on the most recent PJM-operated capacity
credit auction. In IIECs view, it would be much more efficient to simply forego acquiring
capacity for that portion of customer load covered by a PJM ALM credit in the first instance.
IIEC claims there are two problems with the Rider CLR approach proposed by ComEd. First,
customers are compelled to buy capacity they do not require. Second, there is a risk that Rider
CPP capacity charges paid upfront (less ancillary service and other PJM charges) will not be equal
to the refund customers receive back under Rider CLR. Additionally, IIEC suggests there is no way
to quantify the difference between the Rider CLR credit and the cost included in the CPP-H price.
Initially, IIEC recommended that ComEd modify the CPP-H supplier contract such that only the
portion of customer load not covered by ALM capacity credits would be treated as firm load subject
to capacity charges. IIEC asserts that because neither
205
05-0159
Proposed Order
ComEd nor the CPP-H suppliers would be
required to carry any capacity for the portion of customer load covered by the ALM capacity credit,
the portion of customer load covered by the ALM credit would not have a capacity charge associated
with it and would be interruptible by PJM pursuant to the ALM program. IIEC says any PJM penalties
incurred due to the failure of a customer to interrupt service when notified would be directly
assignable to the customer.
In response to ComEds assertion that because CPP-H demand charges include ancillary services
and other PJM charges in addition to capacity charges, the ALM credits would not offset the CPP-H
capacity charges, IIEC says it simplified its proposal. IIEC now recommends that ComEd procure all
energy and ancillary services, for the ALM credited portion of customer load, directly from PJM
since capacity is not required to serve this portion of customer load. IIEC says ComEd would
simply pass on to the customer the charges PJM assesses to serve this customer, including any PJM
penalties associated with the customer failing to interrupt when called upon to do so by PJM.
Under IIECs modified proposal, the customer would have to designate in advance the ALM credited
load as first through the meter, last through the meter or a percentage of total customer load
consistent with the split load designation options already provided for under ComEds existing Rate
RCDS.
IIEC claims its modified proposal parallels ComEds post-PJM RPM proposal for hourly pricing
service. IIEC states that under that proposal, after the implementation of the PJM RPM, ComEd
would procure all hourly pricing customer needs from PJM directly. IIECs modified proposal also
eliminates the need for ComEd to procure and then resell capacity that was not needed in the first
place. In IIECs view, the Commission should require ComEd to modify its proposal to conform with
IIECs recommended approach for ALM demand response for hourly pricing customers.
In its reply brief, IIEC says ComEd has incorrectly characterized IIECs proposal as adding
greater complexity. IIEC believes its proposal brings simplicity. Specifically, IIEC claims its
proposal eliminates ComEds inefficient, unnecessary step of procuring (through the CPP-H auction)
capacity for load covered by ALM capacity credits.
In addition, IIEC argues that its ALM proposal is necessary. IIEC says that ComEd witness Mr.
McNeil did not dispute that the cost of capacity under the CPP-H rate of ComEds proposal for load
covered by ALM capacity credits may or may not be equal to the dollar credit that is returned
through Rider CLR for that load. IIEC asserts that Mr. McNeil testified he knows of no way to
quantify the difference between the Rider CLR dollar credit and the capacity costs included in the
CPP-H price. IIEC contends that its proposal would eliminate the possibility of such a difference
occurring by avoiding in the first instance the purchase of superfluous capacity for hourly pricing
customer load covered by ALM capacity credits. IIEC believes the Commission should require ComEd
to modify its proposal to conform to IIECs recommended modified approach for ALM Demand Response
for hourly pricing customers.
206
05-0159
Proposed Order
IIEC states that in addition to the ALM credit program, PJM has an emergency load response
program and an economic load response program. It is IIECs primary recommendation that customers
with demands of 3 MW and higher, taking fixed price bundled service, be allowed to participate
directly in load response and economic load response programs through PJM members or a PJM
Curtailment Service Provider. IIEC asserts that these programs are better applied to customers
taking the fixed price service since these customers are protected from real-time locational
marginal prices.
According to IIEC, the economic load response program allows load participating in the program
to reduce demand in return for receiving the applicable locational marginal price for the demand
reduction. IIEC states that during a PJM emergency, the emergency load response program pays to
loads nominated in advance the higher of the applicable locational marginal price or $500 per MWh,
whichever is greater.
IIEC contends that demand response is critical for mitigating very high market prices and
maintaining supply when supply adequacy is tight. Ordinarily, there is no incentive for these
customers to curtail demand. IIEC claims the PJM economic response program provides these
customers with the incentive to curtail demand when it is needed. In IIECs view, this benefits
all customers purchasing
power at market prices including ComEds hourly price customers. IIEC argues that all 3 MW
and over customers taking bundled service from ComEd should be given the opportunity to participate
directly in the PJM emergency load response program and the economic response program. Allowing
customers to directly participate in the PJM economic response program would be consistent with the
Commissions recent expression of interest in energy efficiency and demand response programs. (See
IIEC Resolution Dkt. 05-0437, RE: Governors Sustainable Energy Plan, July 19, 2005)
IIEC witness James Dauphinais recommends that ComEd provide an active load management
(ALM) credit to the capacity billing units for hourly pricing customers who meet PJM ALM
requirements. ComEd says his proposal would address the issue by splitting supply procurement for
CPP-H load into two segmentsALM and non-ALM supply. ComEd believes there is no need to introduce
the complexity that such an approach would involve because ComEds proposal already assures that
customers who participate in PJM active load management will receive full credit for doing so.
ComEd asserts that Rider CLR compensates customers directly for curtailable capacity credit, making
the modification suggested by Mr. Dauphinais unnecessary.
ComEd asserts that Rider CLR compensates customers participating in PJM active load management
in full with a curtailable capacity credit, making the modification suggested by IIEC unnecessary.
ComEd contends that the only incremental value created by ALM load is on the capacity component,
and ComEds proposal compensates customers in full for that value.
207
05-0159
Proposed Order
ComEd also asserts that IIECs proposal would also be complicated to implement because ComEd
would have to perform direct acquisition for individual customers for a portion of their hourly
load at the same time it is providing CPP-H service for the other portion of the customers load.
In ComEds view, there is no need to introduce this complexity when Rider CLR already provides the
full appropriate credit.
IIEC also argues that all 3 MW and over customers taking bundled service from ComEd should be
given the opportunity to participate directly in the PJM emergency load response program and the
economic response program. ComEd claims IIECs argument is moot and not relevant to this Docket
because (1) the opportunity to participate in the PJM emergency load program is already provided to
all non-residential customers through existing Rider VLR Voluntary Load Response & System
Reliability program regardless of whether or not the customer is over 3 MW or receiving supply
from a RES and (2) over 3 MW customers subject to the competitive declaration are not eligible
for a fixed-price full requirements product from ComEd. ComEd contends that IIEC has offered no
evidence that RESs are not offering such customers the opportunity to participate in ComEds PJMs
economic response program.
|
c. |
|
Commissions Analysis and Conclusions |
The record shows that ComEds proposal is simpler and less costly for it but, more
complicated and potentially more costly for customers. In contrast, it appears that IIECs
proposal is simpler and potentially less costly for customers but, may be more complicated and more
costly for ComEd. Thus, while the disagreement between ComEd and IIEC is easily understood the
Commissions decision will likely satisfy only one of the parties.
In this instance, the Commission believes the public interest would be best served by adopting
IIECs proposal. As discussed above, the Commission understands why ComEd would prefer its
proposal over IIECs. Nevertheless, the Commission believes that it is appropriate to provide
customers the type of utility service they desire so long as ComEd is allowed to recover the costs
it incurs in providing that service. Thus, ComEd is directed to file tariffs implementing IIEC
recommendation regarding ALM demand response for hourly pricing customers.
IIECs second proposal is for customers with demand of 3 MW and higher, taking fixed price
bundled service to be allowed to participate directly in load response and economic lad response
programs through PJM members or a PJM Curtailment Service Provider. The Commission rejects IIECs
proposal because customers with demand of 3 MW and higher will not be taking fixed-price bundled
service from ComEd.
208
05-0159
Proposed Order
ComEd says that it and Staff have agreed on revised clarifying tariff language relating
to the Supply Charges in Rider PPO-MVM. ComEd believes that language is supported by the evidence
in the record, is just and reasonable, and should be approved.
According to ComEd, Staff raised the question of whether the Supply Charges adjustment for
supply-related uncollectibles costs should be moved from the Supply Charges into a new charge or
into the Supply Administration Charges. Staffs concerns were based primarily on a
misunderstanding that ComEd was proposing that those costs would flow through the AAFs, a
misunderstanding that ComEd claims has been dispelled. Thus, ComEd believes there is no need for
Staffs proposal. Staffs witness confirmed that, with that cleared up, he thought it might be
helpful, but it is not essential, to break out these costs in a separate charge. ComEd does not
believe that any tangible benefit has been identified that would warrant creating a new, separate
charge.
The revised clarifying tariff language related to the Supply Charges in Rider PPO-MVM, to
which Staff and ComEd agreed, is hereby approved. Additionally, ComEd will not be required to
separately state the charge for supply-related uncollecibles at this time. The Commission does not
believe there has been a showing that such a requirement would be beneficial to customers.
|
2. |
|
Supply Administration Charge |
According to ComEd, it and Staff have agreed on revised clarifying tariff language
relating to the Supply Administration Charges in Rider PPO MVM and ComEd recommends that language
be approved.
ComEd says that CES and CUB/CCSAO have made various general recommendations regarding how the
Supply Administration Charges should be calculated and assessed. In ComEds view, those proposals
are premature, and they should not be approved. ComEd says the language regarding these charges in
Rider PPO-MVM is placeholder language, because the actual charges are to be determined in ComEds
rate case, which now is pending as Docket 05-0597; and, thus, the issues sought to be raised by CES
and CUB/CCSAO are appropriately dealt with in that Docket, not here.
ComEd states that CES argues that the Commission should determine the types of costs that
should be included in the charge, and the allocation method, and the manner in which the charge
will be set, in the instant Docket. ComEd describes CES argument as superficial and says it is
unconvincing. ComEd claims there is no good
209
05-0159
Proposed Order
reason to set the charges here or to make the
determinations that CES seeks. ComEd asserts that there is not anything close to a sufficient
evidentiary record to do so, and, in any event, the appropriate Docket for those issues is Docket
05-0597.
ComEd contends that CES proposal that the Commission order ComEd to implement an appropriate
methodology for the proper allocation of uncollectible expenses is inappropriate in this Docket.
ComEd believes the determination of that component of the Supply Charges should be addressed in
Docket 05-0597, ComEds pending rate case, where the adjustment will be determined.
CES complains about the lack of specifics in ComEds proposal regarding the amount and
methodology for determining the Supply Administration Charge. CES also identifies additional costs
it believes ComEd may not have considered. CES contended that ComEd did not specify what costs
should be included in the SAC, nor had the Company proposed a reasonable allocation methodology for
these costs.
According to CES, all ComEd has stated in the instant proceeding is that the actual value of
the SAC will be set in the rate case and that it is only seeking that the Commission approve this
placeholder language regarding the Supply Administration Charge. Although CES acknowledged that
setting the actual rates within the context of a complete rate case is appropriate, CES insists
that ComEd failed to meaningfully describe the parameters of this placeholder. Furthermore,
according to CES, ComEds proposed allocation method improperly placed an inappropriate number of
the SAC costs onto the residential and smaller commercial classes.
CES asserts that assigning costs to cost-causers benefits retail customers and contributes to
the overall fairness of rates. According to CES, this approach is consistent with the structure
outlined in the Act. CES requests that the Commission direct ComEd to equitably allocate the SAC
costs so that the costs are assigned to the cost-causers.
CES asserts that all direct and indirect costs associated with the service of arranging for
the supply of electric energy supplied by the utility should be allocated taking into consideration
the relevant characteristics of the customers demands on the electric utilitys system. CES wants
the Commission to assure that generation supply costs are not allocated to delivery services for
collection. CES is concerned that an improper allocation of costs will distort the true generation
supply costs, distort the market, create false price signals, and act to frustrate customer choice
and competition.
According to the CES, ComEd should allocate all costs associated with procurement to the
energy component of customers bills. According to the CES, all of the direct and indirect costs
and expenses associated with this new procurement model should be distributed among the appropriate
capital and non-capital cost categories and
210
05-0159
Proposed Order
allocated an appropriate administrative overhead cost
proportion; the combination of all of these types of costs should be included in the SAC.
CES asserts that the SAC should be allocated evenly per kWh rather than by a fixed-dollar
amount per account, per month. CES also argues that the SAC should be tracked in the AAF to ensure
that ComEd neither over nor under-collects for this expense. According to CES, the per-kWh
allocation approach properly takes into account the fact that the average non-residential customer
account uses more kWh than the average residential account, and that more of ComEds own internal
resources and indirect supply administration costs under the proposed auction methodology will be
directed toward the non-residential classes in administering the tariffs. CES avers that this
allocation method produced a more accurate allocation of these costs consistent with the
requirements of the Act and is consistent with the method ComEd proposed for the application of the
AAF.
CES states that while the Commission should set the actual charge and the actual allocation in
ComEds pending rate case, the Commission also should ensure that a placeholder is properly
designed within the instant proceeding. According to CES, ComEd failed to appropriately describe
the parameters of such a placeholder and the Commission should address the types of costs which
should be included in the SAC as well as the proper allocation method, and the manner in which the
SAC is to be set in this proceeding.
Staff recommends that the Commission reject the CES proposal to track the Supply
Administration Charge and the Adjustment for Supply-Related Uncollectible Expenses through the AAF.
It is Staffs position that tracking the Supply Administration Charge and the adjustment for
supply-related uncollectible costs would not accomplish this goal. Staff claims that to accomplish
the kind of true-up intended by CES proposal, one must reconcile costs incurred in a particular
period with recoveries for that same period. Instead, CES proposal would reconcile recoveries for
the month being reconciled with the absolute dollar amounts from the test year in the last rate
case, resulting in a mismatch of costs and recoveries from two different periods that likely would
reflect different levels of sales and different levels of costs. In Staffs view, this kind of
mismatch would not accomplish the true-up of costs and recoveries CES desires.
Staff argues that a true-up like the one proposed by CES is not necessary for the Supply
Administration Charge and the adjustment for supply-related uncollectible costs, which will be set
in rate cases. According to Staff, when a rate is set in a rate case, that rate reflects a
relationship between a given level of service and the cost to provide that level of service. Staff
asserts that so long as the relationship between costs and level of service reflected in that rate
remains within appropriate parameters, appropriate cost recovery occurs even when the level of
service varies over different periods of time.
211
05-0159
Proposed Order
Staff believes ComEd is correct that this matter would be better addressed in the rate case.
Staff says the rate case would present a more comprehensive set of facts and analysis upon which to
base decisions about this matter. Further, Staff claims the rate case would provide the context in
which to review the costs of both the delivery and procurement segments and assign them
appropriately.
Staffs initial brief lays out the language for the Supply Administration Charge subsection of
Rider PPO-MVM Staff and ComEd agree upon.
|
d. |
|
Commissions Analysis and Conclusions |
The record of this proceeding is inadequate to make informed decisions regarding the
specifics of the SAC. Additionally, it is simply not necessary to make any such decisions at this
point in time. As a result, the Commission rejects the proposals of CES at this time and concludes
that Docket 05-0597 is one appropriate forum in which to make specific decisions regarding the SAC.
|
3. |
|
Retention of a Market Index Tariff Such as Those Currently Effective or a
Neutral Fact Finder Tariff, in Addition to the Auction-Based Determination of
Market Value |
In Section VIII.B of its initial and reply briefs, BOMA addresses the legality of Rider
PPO-MVM.
ComEd
claims that its proposed Rider PPOMVM implements the PPO required under Sections
16-110(c) and 16-112(a) of the Public Utilities Act. (ComEd Ex. 17.0 at 30) In ComEds proposed
Rider PPO-MVM, ComEd uses the electricity supply price determined by the auction process as the
tariffs market value. (ComEd Ex. 7.0 at 20) ComEds proposed Rider PPO-MVM violates Section
16-112(a) of the Act because this market value is not a function of an exchange or other market
traded index, options or future contract or contracts applicable to the market in which the utility
sells, and the customers in its service area buy, electric power and energy. (220 ILCS
5/16-112(a))
The phrase exchange traded or other market traded futures contracts as used in Section
16-112(a) has a plain and obvious meaning, and this meaning does not encompass the Supplier Forward
Contracts (SFCs) that will be executed as a result of the auction process as ComEd witness Ms.
Juracek has contended in this proceeding. (ComEd Ex. 9.0 at 52) BOMA witness Dr. Laffer testified
that a futures contract is an obligation to make delivery or take delivery of a specific quantity
of a commodity at a particular price at a specific future date or in a stipulated future month.
Because the Supplier Forward Contracts require the supplier to deliver a tranche, or vertical
slice, of ComEds full requirements for electricity supply, they are necessarily indefinite with
respect to quantity. (ComEd Ex. 3.0 at 21) Dr. Laffer testified that the
212
05-0159
Proposed Order
indefinite quantity term
of the Supplier Forward Contracts would make it impossible to trade these contracts on any exchange
or market on which futures contracts are traded. (BOMA Ex. 3.0 at 24) CES witness Dr. OConnor
and Commission Staff witness Mr. Zuraski agreed with Dr. Laffer that the Supplier Forward Contracts
are not futures contracts.
In her attempt to argue that ComEds proposed Rider PPO-MVM does comply with Section
16112(a), ComEd witness Ms. Juracek also argued that the auction closing price is an exchange
traded or market traded index within the meaning of
Section 16112(a) of the Act. (ComEd Ex. 9.0 at
51, 53-54) It strains credulity to believe the General Assembly, when it used the words exchange
traded or market traded index in Section 16-112(a), contemplated a single price determined in a
single auction held once per year, yet Mr. Juraceks characterization of the auction price as an
index would require such an interpretation of the statute. As Commission Staff witness Mr. Zuraski
testified, the price determined by the auction is not an exchange traded or other market traded
index.
In sum, since the Suppliers Forward Contracts resulting from the auction are not exchange
traded or other market traded futures contracts and the auction price is not an exchange traded or
other market traded index, ComEds proposed Rider PPO-MVM does not determine market value in a
manner which meets the requirements of Section 16-112(a) of the Public Utilities Act. Therefore,
the Commission should find that ComEds proposed Rider PPO-MVM does not comply with Section
16-112(a) and order ComEd to offer its current Rider PPO-MI or alternatively a PPO determined by a
neutral fact finder post-2006 in order to comply with Section 16-112(a) of the PUA.
Review of ComEds initial brief reveals that it actually includes no argument whatsoever as to
why its proposed Rider PPO-MVM complies with the Public Utilities Act. This is not surprising
because ComEds proposed Rider PPO-MVM and ComEds proposed bundled rates include the same proposed
charges. If the legislature had intended that charges under ComEds bundled rates and PPO rates to
be the same, it would not have enacted a statute which requires ComEd to offer both bundled rates
and PPO rates to its customers. (BOMA reply brief at 18, citing 220 ILCS 5/16-103(a), 16-110(c) and
(d))
ComEd argues that BOMAs proposal that Rider PPO-MI should not be replaced by Rider
PPO-MVM, and that ComEd should be required to continue to offer Rider PPO MI or an equivalent
rider based on the neutral fact finder (NFF) methodology is without merit. In ComEds view,
BOMAs proposal is unjustified and detrimental, contrary to the evidence in the record, and should
not be approved.
ComEd asserts that BOMAs witnesses were uncertain on key aspects of the proposal and
alternative and admitted lacking knowledge of the specifics of why the Commission rejected the NFF
methodology in favor of the market index approach.
213
05-0159
Proposed Order
According to ComEd, BOMAs Initial Brief argues for its proposal and alternative, but it
focuses entirely on legal issues, ignoring the extensive evidence showing its proposal and
alternative are unwarranted and undesirable on their merits.
In its reply brief, Section VIII.B, Legality of Rider PPO-MVM, ComEd responds to arguments
made in BOMAs brief.
BOMA relies on Dr. Laffers testimony to support its arguments, but Dr. Laffer offers nothing
to support his opinions. He has no familiarity with the market in which ComEd sells and the
customers in its service area buy electric power and energy and no experience with futures
contracts.
Market value is defined in Section 16-112(a). That provision establishes that the
Commission may determine market value pursuant to a tariff that . . . provides for a
determination of the market value for electric power and energy as a function of an exchange
traded or other market traded index,
options or futures contract or contracts applicable to the market in which the utility sells, and
the customers in its service area buy, electric power and energy. The tariffs for the competitive
auction process proposed by ComEd fit squarely within the criteria for establishing the market
value for electric power and energy under Section 16-112(a).
Section 16-112 of the Act sets forth a broad array of methods to determine market value,
including but not limited to, methods based on futures contracts. The SFCs and the products and
prices they represent are within the market-value determination methods permitted by Section
16-112. The Commission has also interpreted Section 16-112 in prior proceedings to recognize that
market value can be determined as proposed in Rider PPO-MVM. As Ms. Juracek pointed out in her
testimony: the auction constitutes a competitive market; the SFCs are standardized contracts that
provide for the procurement of market-traded products for future delivery; the auction will result
in a published index for electricity applicable to ComEds service territory; the SFCs are
contracts that are directly related to the market in which ComEd sells, and its customers buy,
electric power and energy; and the SFCs allow for assignment thereby permitting a secondary market
to develop opening the opportunity for the SFCs to trade in that market.
The procurement method embodied in Rider CPP an auction for the resources required to
provide the very product to be used by retail customers produces a direct and precise assessment
of market value, as called for by the 1997 Restructuring Law. Moreover, it would be illogical for
the Legislature to prohibit the most objective, fair and straight forward determinant of market
value a competitive auction that results in an index price for the very product being valued.
Staff is in agreement. Staff witness Zuraski testified that a Commission approved auction provides
the market value called for in Section 16-112 of the Act because the auction would produce
contracts applicable to the market in which the utility sells, and the customers in its service
area buy, electric power and energy.
214
05-0159
Proposed Order
Staff opposes the BOMA proposal to either retain the type of administratively-determined
Rider PPO-MI tariff that is currently in effect, or in reinstitute the neutral fact-finder
process, as described in Section 16-112 of the Act. Staff asserts that this proposal is fraught
with problems and additional unnecessary costs.
In Section VIII.B of its reply brief, Staff responds to arguments by BOMA on this issue.
Regarding BOMA, that party argues, . . . since the Supplier Forwards Contract resulting from
the auction are not exchange traded or other market traded futures contracts and the auction price
is not an exchange traded or other market traded index, ComEd proposed Rider PPO-MVM does not
determine market value in a manner which meets the requirements of Section 16-112(a) of the Public
Utilities Act.
In Staffs view, when interpreting a statute, one must first look to the plain language.
(Davis v. Toshiba, 186 Ill. 2d 181, 184-85 (1999)) The plain language of 16-112(a) provides that
market value, if it is not the result of the neutral fact finder process (Section 16-112(a)(ii)),
must meet three requirements.
The first requirement is that the market value must be the function of one of three
alternatives. Market value must be the function of either: (1) an index; or (2) an options or
futures contracts; or (3) contracts. The second requirement is that the index, or options or
futures contracts, or contracts must be a function of exchange trading or market trading. The
third and final requirement is that the index or the options or futures contract or the contracts
must be applicable to the market in which the utility sells, and the customers in its service area
buy, electric power and energy.
With respect to the first requirement, the Commission in the past has interpreted function
of in a broad sense. The Commission in its order on reopening in ICC Docket Nos. 00-0259,
00-0395, and 00-0461 (Consolidated) rejected the IIECs argument that the use of bids and offers
was inconsistent with the 16-112. The Commission found the use of bids and offers would produce a
market value that was a
function of a market index. (ICC Docket Nos. 00-0259, 00-0395, and 00-0461 (Consolidated), Order
on Reopening at 162)
Based upon the plain language of Section 16-112 and the Commissions prior orders concerning
market value, ComEds proposed Rider PPO-MVM meets the three requirements.
With respect to the first requirement, Rider PPO-MVM refers to the SFC which is the standard
contract to which ComEd would enter into binding wholesale contracts with suppliers for the
procurement of full requirements electric supply from suppliers for ComEds customers. (Ill.C.C.
No. 4, Original Sheet No. 248) Therefore, there should be
215
05-0159
Proposed Order
no dispute that the SFCs are contracts.
BOMAs argument that the SFCs are not futures contracts and its argument that the auction closing
price is not an exchange traded or market traded index is not determinative. Section 16-112(a)
provides that Market value must be the function of either: (1) an index; or (2) an options or
futures contracts; or (3) contracts.
With respect to the second requirement that the contract be a function of exchange trading or
market trading, ComEd witness Juracek pointed out that ...the auction is itself a market in which
wholesale energy suppliers vie with each other to sell energy to the procuring utility. The
winning bid, or market-clearing price, is the lowest price generated by this competitive market
trading process. (ComEd Ex. 9.0 at 52) Staff witness Zuraski also testified that auction prices
which result from a competitive procurement process would be the result of a market. (Staff
Exhibit 3.0 at 6) Further, it logically follows that if the use of bids and offers produce a
market value that was a function of a market then bids and offers that result in contracts, such
as SFCs, will most certainly produce a market value that is a function of a market.
Finally, with respect to the third requirement that the contract be applicable to the market
in which the utility sells, since the SFCs are the contracts that will set forth the terms for the
acquisition of electric power and energy supplied to ComEds customers, there can be no dispute
that the SFC contracts are applicable to the market in which the utility sells, and the customers
in its service area buy, electric power and energy (220 ILCS 5/16-112(a)(i)) With respect to
contingency purchases, i.e., those purchases in the PJM-administered markets (ILL. C. C. No. 4,
Original Sheet No. 273), those purchases undoubtedly would produce a market value which meets the
three requirements of 16-112(a) since the PJM purchases would result in contracts which are a
function of market trading and the power and energy purchases would be for ComEds customers.
Thus, Staff recommends that the Commission should find that Rider PPO-MVM complies with
Section 16-112(a) of the Act.
|
d. |
|
Commissions Analysis and Conclusions |
BOMA argues that since the Suppliers Forward Contracts resulting from the auction are
not exchange traded or other market traded futures contracts and the auction price is not an
exchange traded or other market traded index, ComEds proposed Rider PPO-MVM does not determine
market value in a manner which meets the requirements of Section 16-112(a) of the Public Utilities
Act. BOMA wants the Commission to order ComEd to offer its current Rider PPO-MI or alternatively
a PPO determined by a neutral fact finder post-2006 in order to comply with Section 16-112(a) of
the Act.
Both ComEd and Staff object to BOMAs recommendation and argue that the proposed auction will
produce market values that are consistent with the requirements of Section 16-112(a) of the Act.
216
05-0159
Proposed Order
Section 16-112(a) of the Act states in part:
The market value to be used in the calculation of transition charges as defined in
Section 16-102 shall be determined in accordance with either (i) a tariff that has
been filed by the electric utility with the Commission pursuant to Article IX of
this Act and that provides for a determination of the market value for electric
power and energy as a function of an exchange traded or other market traded index,
options or futures contract or contracts
applicable to the market in which the utility sells, and the customers in its
service area buy, electric power and energy, or (ii) in the event no such tariff has
been placed into effect for the electric utility, or in the event such tariff does
not establish market values for each of the years specified in the neutral
fact-finder process described in subsections (b) through (h) of this Section, a
tariff incorporating the market values resulting from the neutral fact-finder
process set forth in subsections (b) through (h) of this Section.
The Commission has previously utilized the neutral fact finder provisions of the Act as well
as the market value index provisions to establish the market value for power and energy as called
for in Section 16-112(a) of the Act. Under the neutral fact finder provisions, the market value
determination was based upon contracts actually entered into by electric utilities and ARES. The
market value index tariffs previous approved, as the name suggests, established market values on
the basis of one or market traded index for power and energy.
The neutral fact finder provisions of Section 16-112 provide for determining market value
using contracts entered into in the past; actual contracts. Alternatively, the market value
tariff provisions of Section 16-112, rather than relying on historical instruments, rely upon
future instruments to establish market value. These future instruments consist of: 1) an exchange
traded or other market traded index, 2) options or 3) futures contract or contracts.
Under Section 16-112(a) any index providing the basis for market value must be either
exchange or market traded. However, the Commission does not believe that the phrase exchange
traded or other market traded modifies options, or futures contract or contracts. Thus, the
very basis for BOMAs position is faulty.
In this instance, the Commission concludes that the auction process approved herein will
involve futures contract or contracts applicable to the market in which the utility sells, and the
customers in its service area buy, electric power and energy. As previously stated, the
Commission rejects BOMAs suggestion that such futures contract or contracts must be exchange or
market traded. The statute simply does not contain such a requirement.
217
05-0159
Proposed Order
Given the current structure of the wholesale electric market in the United States, the
Commission finds that ComEds proposed auction process, as modified in this Order and reflected in
the modifications to ComEds tariffs approved in this proceeding, is consistent the Act. Contrary
to BOMAs assertion, the Act does not state that a futures contract or contracts is an obligation
to make delivery or take delivery of a specific quantity of a commodity at a particular price at a
specific future date or in a stipulated future month. The wholesale electric market in the United
States is currently evolving and is different than the markets for financial instruments and some
commodities to which BOMA attempts to draw parallels. However, this fact is recognized in the Act
by reference to the market in which the utility sells and the customers in the service area buy
electric power and energy. In this context, the auction process approved in this Order meets the
requirements of Section 16-112(a) of the Act.
As the discussed above, the Commission has previously used the neutral fact finder and
subsequently approved market value index tariffs for determining market value under Section 16-112
of the Act. The Commission is convinced that the approved market value index tariffs represented
an improvement over the neutral fact finder process. The Commission is similarly convinced that
it is very likely that the auction process approved herein will represent a substantial
improvement over the market value index tariffs previously approved. The Commission simply cannot
accept, as BOMAs arguments suggest, that the General Assembly intended to tie the hands of the
Commission and force it to reject a superior method for determining the market value of power and
energy and instead rely on a process that in all likelihood would produce inferior estimates of
the market value of power and energy in ComEds service territory.
The Commission rejects BOMAs proposal to continue with Rider PPO-MI or the neutral fact
finder process. The Commission has several years of experience with these processes and both, to
different degrees, have shortcomings. The Commission does not believe any possible benefits
associated with BOMAs proposal outweigh the very significant costs. Additionally, given the
structure of wholesale electric markets, the Commission is convinced that the auction process
approved herein is consistent with the requirements of Section 16-112(a) of the Act.
|
1. |
|
Staffs Rate Increase Mitigation Proposal |
Staff proposes a rate mitigation plan to prevent what it describes as undue bill impacts
arising from the auction process. Staff claims that without its plan, customer classes will be
left to the vagaries of the auction process whose results will not be known for a number of months.
Staff states that the potential exists for individual classes to receive inordinate increases
relative to other classes. Staff believes its
218
05-0159
Proposed Order
proposal is essential to mitigate against any
excessive increase in power costs individual classes may receive.
The Staff proposal would apply only to the blended (CPP-B) auction whose customers have the
fewest alternatives to bundled power. Staffs proposal would limit overall bill increases for
these customers to the greater of the following: 20% or 150% of the overall CPP-B auction average.
If the overall bill increase for customers within that auction is 13.33% or less, the maximum
increase for any group of customers within the auction would be 20%. For an overall increase
greater than 13.33%, the 150% of auction average limit would apply.
According to Staff, utility bills can be a significant cost for ratepayers, both residential
and non-residential. Staff says that significant increases in utility bills can have a disruptive
effect on ratepayers budgets. If the changes are sudden, ratepayers may not have sufficient time
to make changes in their behaviors to absorb the higher cost. Thus, Staff claims it may be
necessary to limit those increases to give affected customers the opportunity to adjust to the new
paradigm by introducing rate changes on a gradual basis.
It is Staffs position that bill impacts are a key regulatory issue in the current regulatory
environment. Staff claims they were a central component of the Restructuring Act which enacted a
rate freeze for non-residential customers and actual rate reductions of 5-20% for residential
customers. Staff notes that by the time that new rates go into effect in 2007, this rate freeze
and reduction will have been in effect for nine years. Staff further asserts that the Commission
has a long history of considering rate impacts in designing rates.
According to Staff, there are two reasons why bill impacts should play a central role in this
case. One is the lack of information about Post 2006 rate levels. ComEds proposed Rider CPP
contains formulas but no hard numbers; therefore, the actual power costs that customers will pay in
the Post-2006 environment will depend on the input of future data into those formulas. Staff
argues that this uncertainty also makes it difficult to develop proposals for mitigating bill
impacts. In Staffs view, any remedy in this area must be prospective and designed to address
potential scenarios that may or may not come to pass.
Staff also argues that ComEds proposed realignment of rate classes, by itself, can raise
bills for some customers and lower bills for others independently of the overall increase in
customer bills. Staff says ComEd has performed some preliminary bill analyses for residential
customers which indicate that residential space heating customers may suffer significant adverse
impacts from the Companys proposed realignment of classes. Under one scenario, an average 12.77%
decrease in residential bills would produce an average increase of 13.92% in bills for single
family space heating customers. Staff claims that if residential rates actually rise, the increase
for single family space heating customers would be that much greater.
219
05-0159
Proposed Order
Under Staffs proposal, the maximum of 20% for overall auction increases of 13.33% or less
recognizes that when the overall increase is lower, the relative increase for individual classes
can be greater. Conversely, for overall increases greater than 13.33%, Staffs proposed limit of
150% of the average recognizes that when the increase is greater, it must be distributed more
equally.
Staff states that the adjustment process would take place after all components of the bundled
ratemaking process are complete. Staff says the process would include the current proceeding, the
auction and the delivery service rate case. Then, the overall level of increase for customers
would be used to determine which maximum, 20% or 150% of the CPP-B auction average, should apply.
After that, current and Post-2006 bills for each proposed rate class must be calculated. If the
increase for an individual rate class climbs above the applicable proposed maximum, then the power
price for that class would be set at a level that brings the class back down to the designated
maximum and the resulting revenue shortfall would be allocated on an equal percentage basis to all
remaining classes. If that reallocation served to raise a class above the maximum, then the
maximum would be applied to that class as well and the revenue shortfall would be reallocated again
among classes not subject to the maximum.
The Staff proposal is tied to the conduct of the auction. Under the translation tariff, power
prices will be updated annually (after an initial 17-month period) to incorporate the results of
auctions to replace expiring power contracts. Each time power prices are updated customers within
the auction group would again be subject to the limit of the maximum of 20% or 150% of the average
for the auction group. Staff says this would provide an opportunity to bring the power costs that
customers pay further into line with the power costs they cause suppliers to incur, subject to
these limits. Staff adds that because future auctions will affect only a portion of overall power
costs and not impact delivery services rates, there will be considerable latitude to bring the
power costs that customers pay in line with the costs they cause to be incurred.
Staff proposes that bill impacts be addressed solely within the context of the CPP-B auction.
If total bills were capped for a group of customers, only customers within the CPP-B auction would
be subject to an offsetting increase in power costs. Under Staffs proposal, customers in the
CPP-A auction would not be subject to an increase in power costs to offset a limit on bill
increases for residential customers in the CPP-B auction.
Staff states that its proposal does not extend in any way to the CPP-A auction for larger
customers. Staff claims that auction replaces the concept of a translation prism with a single,
uniform price for power to be paid by all customers. There would be no room for any additional rate
mitigation proposals under the concept of a single auction price for power. Staff argues that it
would not make sense to have customers in one auction subsidize power costs paid by customers in
another auction. Staff believes that could create differences between the overall power costs paid
by customers and power
220
05-0159
Proposed Order
prices received by suppliers within an auction. In Staffs view, that would
add an unneeded level of complexity to the process.
In its reply brief, Staff takes issue with CCGs argument that: (1) there is uncertainty about
the impact of the Staff plan because it must await the implementation of the auction; and (2) there
is no need for such a plan. With regard to the uncertainty issue, Staff states that all aspects of
procurement costs are uncertain before the auction is run. In Staffs view, this uncertainty only
underscores the importance of adopting a plan that limits the adverse impacts that may befall
ratepayers. Staff argues that its proposal limits the potential exposure to rate shock and,
thereby, serves to reduce the uncertainty facing bundled customers. If, as CCG suggests,
uncertainty is a concern, then the Staff rate mitigation addresses that concern by limiting the
uncertainty that ratepayers face.
Staff states that CCGs second argument is a simple, unsupported statement that the Staff plan
is not needed. Staffs response is that it disagrees strongly with this statement.
According to Staff, Dynegy makes a single argument regarding the Staff rate mitigation
proposal. Staff says Dynegy claims that the process of adjusting power costs under the rate
mitigation process
could raise prices for some groups and, thereby, cause them to migrate to alternative service.
Dynegy goes on to claim that this additional switching risk could be regarded by suppliers as an
additional cost and they would be inclined to raise their power cost bids as a result.
Staff contends that this argument amounts to empty speculation by Dynegy. In Staffs view, it
is not clear at this time whose rates will rise and fall as a result of the Staff rate mitigation
plan. Nor is the magnitude of any adjustment evident. According to Staff, its proposal could
serve to either raise or lower the power costs of the customers most susceptible to migrate to
RES-supplied power. Staff asserts that the uncertainty for suppliers could either rise or fall.
Staff states that there is no evidence for Dynegy to assert that the Staff mitigation plan will
increase prices offered by suppliers in the auction process. Staff believes that conclusion is
pure guesswork on Dynegys part. Staff maintains that the benefits of the Staff rate mitigation
plan far outweigh any drawbacks Dynegy might imagine could take place.
ComEd recommends that the Commission approve Staffs rate increase (bill impacts)
mitigation proposal, which relates to the CPP-B auction segment (i.e., to all residential customers
and most commercial and industrial customers), as that proposal has been clarified and revised in
rebuttal testimony.
According to ComEd, Staffs proposal, as clarified and revised in rebuttal testimony, also
includes applying the mitigation criteria to residential space heating customers as a subgroup of
the Residential Customer Supply Group.
221
05-0159
Proposed Order
ComEd states that CCG and Dynegy expressed certain questions / concerns regarding certain
details of Staffs proposal, but ComEd claims it explained how those items can be addressed.
(ComEd brief at 169) ComEd says it recognizes the concerns raised by CCG and Dynegy, but believes
that the better balance is in favor of Staffs proposal.
According to Dynegy, rate impacts are a valid concern, with the decision whether or not
to mitigate rate increases essentially being a policy judgment. Dynegy agrees that as structured,
Staffs proposal would not alter the payment stream to Suppliers because the mechanism merely
spreads any excess rate increase across different classes in the same auction group. Nonetheless,
Dynegy is concerned that if adopted, Staffs proposal could have the perverse effect of raising
prices not lowering them.
Dynegy argues that as the price to different customer classes artificially varies from that
which would be obtained without Staffs proposal, those customers who pay less will have an
incentive to stay with the utility while those who pay more will have an incentive to find an
alternative supply option. Dynegy believes this additional switching risk will need to be factored
in by Suppliers and will likely raise the final, auction-clearing price. In Dynegys view, in
deciding whether to adopt this rate mitigation proposal, the Commission should consider whether
this unintended consequence is one it wishes to have occur.
In its reply brief, Dynegy indicates its agreement with CCG that all winning bidders must be
paid the auction clearing price applicable to the tranches they are selected to provide. Dynegy
says anything less will simply be too risky for Suppliers to accept absent the inclusion of
prohibitive premiums.
Dynegy also disagrees with ComEd that the surrebuttal testimony submitted by Messrs. Alongi
and Crumrine fully addressed its concern. Dynegy agrees that the spreadsheet offered by them is a
step in the right direction and will certainly help Suppliers as they develop their bidding
strategies. Thus, Dynegy supports ComEd providing that spreadsheet in a timely manner. Dynegy
asserts that the spreadsheet, however, does not in any way alter the underlying conundrum that any
mitigation plan could
raise the ultimate auction-clearing price due to the incentives created by artificially
shifting costs between different CPP-B customer classes.
CCGs concern about the proposed mitigation plan is its potential impact on the migration
analysis. CCG states that in preparing their bids, suppliers assess the risk of migration from
bundled service to competitive supply and from competitive supply to bundled service and account
for that risk in their prices. CCG asserts that since there will be uncertainty as to the
mitigation plan until after the auction, the migration analysis
222
05-0159
Proposed Order
cannot be completed before the
auction. CCG contends that this adds an additional level of uncertainty which cannot accurately be
modeled before the auction and thus adds an additional risk premium.
Additionally, CCG believes that there is no need to have a plan to artificially mitigate the
bundled rates of customers after completion of the auction or to soften the impact of any potential
rate shock. According to CCG, the Illinois Auction Proposal is designed to generally ensure that
the proper price signal is developed through the competitive bidding. CCG contends that the
resulting rates would therefore be the actual operating electricity market as it exists at the time
of the auction.
CCG states that should the Commission approve a rate mitigation plan, then CCG requests that
the mitigation plan not be allowed to impact the generation prices. According to CCG, all winning
bidders must be paid the auction clearing price applicable to the tranches they are selected to
provide.
It is CCGs position that any mitigation plan should not create uncertainty for potential and
actual bidding suppliers. CCG argues that uncertainty increases risk which tends to increase
prices. CCG believes that any mitigation plan should thus operate in such a way that the full
retail prices of affected bundled customers can be calculated for various auction generation price
results (i.e. the rate prism is established and fixed) prior to the commencement of the auction
and such prices will not change after completion of the auction.
In its reply brief, CCG says one of its concerns with regard to Staffs Mitigation Proposal is
that the plan might impact suppliers risk assessment of customer migration. ComEd, in responding
to that concern in its testimony, proposed to make the prism mechanics available 105 days prior
to the auction. In addition, ComEd explained that the delivery service case and the thresholds of
the mitigation plan would be established by June 2006. CCG agrees that having the actual data,
including the mechanics of the mitigation plan available well in advance of the auction, should
address the attrition concern. CCG notes, however, that no final decision has been made as to the
auction date and, although CCG does not object to a September Auction, its preference continues to
be a May Auction. CCG states that if a May Auction were approved by the Commission, the risk
assessment of customer migration would continue to be an issue since the rate case would not be
resolved prior to June 2006.
The AG states that Staffs rate increase mitigation highlights the uncertainty resulting
from ComEds proposal in this docket. The AG adds that although bill impacts are a critical public
concern, it is impossible to determine the bill impact of the Companys proposal. The AG argues
that the uncertainty associated with approving a future process, with no history in Illinois or
estimated effect on rates, is compounded by formula rate design, which is dependent on variable
inputs. The AG believes that Staffs attempt to limit the bill impact on consumers is a welcome
attempt to protect
223
05-0159
Proposed Order
consumers from the results of an unorthodox proposal, with unknown bill and rate
impacts.
The AG says Staffs rate mitigation proposal is crucial to protect consumers from rate shock.
The AG argues that rate impact mitigation is a valuable regulatory tool that recognizes the
essential nature of electric service and the statutory and social need to keep it affordable so
that its use by all segments of society is preserved.
The AG says that although it agrees that the final bundled bill will determine what consumers
pay, a mitigation plan that imposes limits on generation costs could send a signal to both
generators and the utility that affordability of essential electric service is a key public policy.
According to the AG, this case does not set a bundled rate, and it may be premature to
establish a rate mitigation plan in this docket when other dockets are pending and costs are
unknown. Although Staff has tried to present a plan to accommodate all of the unknown elements of
future rates, the AG claims that ultimately a bill mitigation plan will change the cost allocations
and rate design substantially, based on factors outside this docket. As a result, the AG asserts
that the Commission should conclude that a rate mitigation plan is appropriate in the event it
approves the Companys proposal, but retain the discretion to set rates that serve the public
interest after all of the currently unknown elements have been established.
The AG says a rate mitigation plan or formula will not be necessary if the Commission rejects
the Companys proposal and requires the Company to submit tariffs with the charges that consumers
will be asked to pay. In that case, the Staff and other parties will be able to assess the actual,
rather than the speculative, effect of the tariff changes, and propose a rate design that can be
assessed both for fairness among customer classes and for bill impact.
In its reply brief, MWGen states that it shares some of CCGs concerns regarding Staffs
or any other rate increase mitigation proposal. MWGen asserts that a rate mitigation plan has
the potential to adversely affect suppliers in two ways: first, through the potential threat that
the price paid to suppliers will be reduced to the extent that ComEd is not allowed to collect the
full price from its customers, and second, through the possibility that a rate mitigation plan may
threaten ComEds financial viability and thus undermine its ability to honor its contracts.
MWGen asserts that Supplier participation in the Illinois auction will occur and be maximized
only if suppliers are convinced that their contracts will be honored and that they will in fact be
paid the price that results from the auction. Accordingly, MWGen contends that any rate mitigation
plan must meet two requirements: first, suppliers must be assured that they will not be compelled
to underwrite any portion of the rate mitigation and that they will be paid the auction clearing
price regardless of the rate
224
05-0159
Proposed Order
ComEd is allowed to recover from its customers; and second, any rate
mitigation plan must be premised upon a reasonable relationship between the auction clearing price
and the rate that ComEd will be allowed to recover, thereby ameliorating the risk of ComEd
insolvency caused by a large disparity between the contract price and the rate recovery. MWGen
argues that if either of these conditions is not met, and the price paid to suppliers is therefore
placed at risk, suppliers will be unlikely to participate at all or will do so only at a
substantial premium to the amount they would otherwise bid. Neither outcome would be desirable for
customers in Illinois.
|
g. |
|
Commissions Analysis and Conclusions |
The Commission understands that adopting a rate mitigation plan could impact the
migration of customers from bundled service to competitive suppliers, which increases uncertainty
for auction bidders and might ultimately increase the prices resulting from an auction.
Nevertheless, the Commission believes that all things considered, Staffs mitigation proposal
offers important protections to ratepayers and must be adopted. The Commission believes it is
appropriate to adopt the rate mitigation proposal here to provide both customers and suppliers as
much advance notice as possible.
Finally, the Commission wishes to assure bidders in the auction that the rate mitigation plan
adopted in this Order simply will simply reallocate revenue responsibility between customers and
will not have any impact on the total revenue collect by ComEd or paid to winning bidders.
|
2. |
|
Non-Residential Space Heating Customers |
BOMA takes the position that if Staffs rate mitigation plan is adopted the Commission
should order ComEd to include a separate subgroup for all nonresidential space heating customers
under 3 megawatts in its implementation of the plan unless the Commission accepts BOMAs proposal
that ComEd exempt nonresidential space heating customers from demand charges in ComEds delivery
service tariffs.
BOMA contends that nonresidential space heating customers will face rate shock from a rate
increase of between 27.2% (at an auction price of 5 cents per kWh) and 46.5% (at an auction price
of 6 cents per kWh) in 2007 if no rate mitigation plan is applied to these customers. BOMA claims
that the rate increase for nonresidential space heating customers would be 10.7% greater than the
increase for nonresidential, non-space heating customers in the absence of rate mitigation.
Additionally, BOMA claims it is possible to set up a separate group for nonresidential space
heating customers in Staffs rate mitigation plan just as ComEd did when it set up a separate
customer transition charge for these customers.
225
05-0159
Proposed Order
BOMA proposes that ComEd exempt nonresidential electric space heating customers from demand
charges in its delivery services tariffs on electricity used for space heating in order to make the
rate increase for nonresidential space heating customers comparable to the increase for
nonresidential non-space heating customers.
BOMA states that ComEds current Rider 25 bundled service rate for nonresidential space
heating customers, which ComEds proposal would eliminate, includes an exemption from demand
changes for electricity used for space heating. BOMA contends that its proposal for nonresidential
space heating customers merely continues the treatment of these customers that was begun nearly
three decades ago when Rider 25 was first instituted.
BOMA states that its proposal would apply to all non-residential space heating customers
regardless of whether they buy their electricity from ComEd or a competitive supplier. BOMA claims
this method ensures that there will be no adverse impact on either the competitive retail electric
market or the auctions results.
In its reply brief, BOMA says ComEd does not challenge, much less rebut, the impending rate
shock facing nonresidential space heating customers post-2006. BOMA says ComEd does not dispute
that these customers will face huge rate increases post-2006 if the Rider 25 electric space heating
tariff is eliminated as is proposed by ComEd. Nevertheless, according to BOMA, ComEd has opposed
any efforts to mitigate this rate shock, including BOMAs proposal that nonresidential space
heating customers be included as a separate subgroup in Staffs rate increase mitigation plan
unless the Commission accepts BOMAs proposal that ComEd exempt nonresidential space heating
customers from demand charges on electricity used for space heating in ComEds delivery service
tariffs.
Moreover, BOMA says Staffs rate mitigation plan should apply to all customers under 3 MW
regardless of which auction product the Commission determines should be offered to the 400 kW 1
MW and 1 MW 3MW customer classes.
In its reply brief, BOMA states that rather than propose any plan to prevent the rate shock
for nonresidential space heating customers, ComEd focuses on urging the Commission to reject BOMAs
proposal on the grounds that it is beyond the scope of this docket because it involves amending or
establishing delivery services tariffs not before the Commission. BOMA believes that consideration
of its nonresidential space heating proposal in this proceeding not only is appropriate but also is
advisable. BOMA asserts that should the Commission decide to take action to lessen the rate
increases for nonresidential space heating customers, the Commission has two methods by which it
can accomplish this goal: it can modify either ComEds rates for electricity supply or ComEds rates for
electricity delivery. BOMA maintains that it will be too late for the Commission to weigh both
options during ComEds currently pending delivery services rate case because ComEds rates for
electricity supply will have already been decided in this case. In BOMAs view, this proceeding is
the only opportunity for the
226
05-0159
Proposed Order
Commission to compare its two available options for lessening the
massive rate shock for nonresidential space heating customers.
ComEd states that BOMAs proposal, especially in terms of the relief that BOMA seeks,
which involves amending or establishing delivery services tariffs, is not before the Commission, is
beyond the scope of this Docket, and, in any event, is without merit and inappropriate, for several
reasons, and that BOMAs alternative proposal also was without merit for multiple reasons. ComEd
argues that it is inappropriate to deal with supply-related rate impacts by adjusting the delivery
rates for any customer or group of customers. In addition, ComEd states that Rider 25 was created
under the previous vertically integrated utility structure and was designed based on facts that are
no longer relevant. ComEd adds that in the post transition period, because ComEd owns no
generation, ComEd, as the distribution utility, no longer has an internal cost structure associated
with the generation of electricity using its own assets. ComEd also maintains that BOMAs proposal
would result in an inaccurate price signal regarding the cost of distribution capacity, effectively
providing this group of customers with free delivery service for eight months each year. ComEd
believes it is inappropriate to provide free delivery to any customer group. ComEd states that
Rider 25 customers are not a separate rate and instead are served under multiple rates.
Dynegy states that BOMAs proposed rate mitigation proposal focuses more on the delivery
rate charge for those customers than directly on the commodity charge. To the extent that BOMAs
proposed a rate mitigation plan for non-residential space heating customers has no effect on
migration risk, either of non-residential space heating customers or other classes of customers
(e.g., by altering the commodity-related charges they have to pay in light of the BOMA proposal),
Dynegy agrees that this proposal would not have the same unintended consequence that Staffs would
have. However, to the extent that BOMAs proposal would alter the commodity-related charges for
any group of customers, then Dynegy claims the same unintended consequence could arise, even though
BOMAs proposal is structured differently. If that were so, then once again Dynegy urges the
Commission to determine if it wishes that unintended consequence as a part of deciding whether to
adopt the BOMA proposal.
|
d. |
|
Commissions Analysis and Conclusions |
The Commission concludes that this is not an appropriate forum for considering changes to
ComEds delivery services tariffs. As a result, BOMAs proposal to exempt certain customers from
demand charges associated with delivery services is rejected. However, BOMAs alternative
proposal, to create a separate subgroup for nonresidential space heat customers in the context of
the rate mitigation plan is essentially unopposed. Additionally, the Commission believes that for
the same reasons the rate mitigation plan was previously adopted in this order, it is appropriate
to
227
05-0159
Proposed Order
protect nonresidential space heat customers under 3 MW from unreasonably large rate increases,
BOMAs alternative proposal should therefore be adopted.
|
3. |
|
Elimination of Rider ISS |
BOMA wants the Commission to request that ComEd continue to offer ComEds Rider Interim
Supply Service ISS tariff (Rider ISS) after the end of the mandatory transition period. BOMA
claims that Rider ISS has been an indispensable part of ComEds toolbox to encourage customers to
make proper electricity supply purchasing decisions and that it has been instrumental in the
development of a competitive electricity market during the competitive transition period. BOMA
states that none of the tariffs proposed by ComEd for use post-2006 provide Rider ISS important
three months of time to purchase from ComEd at a stable price and then choose another competitive
supplier. BOMA contends that many customers are uneasy with the hourly product of the CPP-H
auction which can be volatile by nature. BOMA concludes that the CPP-H auction does not provide an
attractive safe haven for these customers and customers may be forced into an unwise procurement
choice by rushing their decision with only CPP-H as a temporary fallback.
BOMA argues that since ComEd has made it clear that it does not intend to offer Rider ISS
post-2006, it is not beyond the scope of this docket for the Commission to determine based on the
record in this proceeding whether Rider ISS should continue in 2007.
BOMA maintains that none of the tariffs mentioned by ComEd provide the important three months
of time to purchase from ComEd at a stable price and then choose a competitive supplier. BOMA
contends that ComEd has not provided any proof that its post-2006 bundled rates will adequately
replace the important function that Rider ISS provides to consumers. BOMA maintains that the
Commission should request that ComEd continue to offer Rider ISS post-2006.
ComEd objects to BOMAs request that the Commission order ComEd to continue to offer
service under Rider ISS as a separate service after the end of the transition period. ComEd argues
that BOMAs proposal is beyond the scope of this Docket, but, in any event, it is without merit and
is inappropriate.
Although ComEd maintains that BOMAs proposal is not proper for consideration in this Docket,
ComEd also claims that Rider ISS will no longer be needed or appropriate in the post 2006 period.
ComEd states that Rider ISS, as it has been structured during the transition period, is a service
that is being voluntarily provided by the utilities. ComEd is not willing to provide that service
in the same manner that it has in the past. In addition, ComEd argues that a separately structured
Rider ISS is no
228
05-0159
Proposed Order
longer necessary or appropriate because the post 2006 bundled electric service
rates will provide the necessary service that Rider ISS provides today.
In addition, ComEd claims the retail customer switching rules as proposed in Rider CPP,
provide an exception to the twelve month hold on bundled electric service related to the CPP-B
Auction Segment in the circumstance that a customer is switched from delivery service to such
bundled service as a direct result of the customers RES ceasing to do business as a RES in ComEds
service territory. ComEd asserts that all customers may elect bundled electric service related to
the CPP-H Auction that provides termination provisions that effectively provide for a much shorter
term of service.
ComEd also contends that the Commission lacks the jurisdiction and authority to require ComEd
to continue to offer Rider ISS, a voluntary service, as a separate service in the post transition
period.
According to ComEd, BOMAs Initial Brief pursues its proposal in a cursory manner, ignoring
the legal issue, ignoring the point that the issue is beyond the scope of this Docket, and focusing
on the claim that Rider ISS has contributed to the development of a competitive retail market.
ComEd argues that BOMAs position is confused. ComEd says it is not stating that there will
be no default service, rather, for all eligible customers the bundled electric service tariffs will
serve as default service. ComEd opposes the request that it be required to continue to offer Rider
ISS as a separately priced service. ComEd says it is unwilling to offer this voluntary service as
a separately priced service. ComEd contends there is no basis in the law or the evidence for such
a requirement and BOMAs proposal should be rejected.
|
c. |
|
Commissions Analysis and Conclusions |
The Commission rejects BOMAs proposal because after the conclusion of the mandatory
transition period ComEd has no legal obligation to provide Rider ISS.
|
4. |
|
DASR Procedures in Anticipation of Serving New Customer Facilities |
CES requested that ComEd clarify the RES DASR procedures for a RES to enroll a new
customer account in anticipation of serving their load requirements when the account and meter
numbers are not yet assigned.
CES argues that the Commission should require ComEd to formalize the methodology by which it
intends to treat new customer facilities under its proposal. CES requests that the Commission
require specific procedures to be provided to RESs
229
05-0159
Proposed Order
that indicate how a RES may have new customers
assigned to it when those customers account and meter numbers are not yet known.
According to CES, ComEd has indicated that in its rate case it will propose a RES DASR
procedure for purposes of serving new facilities so that a new customer need not take bundled
service prior to transitioning to delivery service. Apparently, ComEds DASR procedure would
enable a RES to DASR a customer account in anticipation of serving its load requirements in advance
of the time that an official account number and meter number(s) are assigned. CES complains,
however, that it is unclear what specific procedure RESs are to follow in order to have these
accounts assigned. CES requests that ComEd be required to provide these RES procedures in writing
as a part of the instant proceeding.
CES asked that ComEd clarify the procedures for a RES to DASR a new customer account in
anticipation of serving their load requirements when the account and meter numbers are not yet
assigned. In response, ComEd says it is committed to fully specifying its proposal in Docket
05-0597, such that RESs will have a full understanding of the DASR rules and processes well in
advance of the first auction. ComEd claims the Commission does not have any open issue before it
on this subject.
ComEd states that CES now requests that the Commission order ComEd to provide those DASR
procedures in writing in the instant Docket. ComEd claims that CES request is inappropriate in
this Docket, is not supported by the evidence and should not be approved.
|
c. |
|
Commissions Analysis and Conclusions |
The Commission believes that while CES has raised an interesting and perhaps legitimate
concern, it is too late to be substantively resolved in this proceeding. The Commissions decision
must be based on the record in this proceeding and there is simply no substantive record on this
issue. Nevertheless, the Commission is hopeful that this issue will be substantively address in
the record of 05-0597, or some other appropriate proceeding, and to the extent it is, the
Commission can then make a decision.
|
5. |
|
Recategorizing Certain Condominium Customers as Non Residential Customers |
According to the CES, as a result of tariffs approved many years ago, a large number of
condominium buildings currently are classified as residential rather than commercial for purposes
of serving such common area needs as lobby and hallway lighting and heating. CES avers that, going
forward, this approach fails to recognize the
230
05-0159
Proposed Order
reality that these common areas have all of the
characteristics of commercial load. Accordingly, CES proposes that ComEd reclassify these
customers, from residential to commercial, in order to recognize that these common areas have all
of the characteristics of commercial load. CES asserts such re-categorization would not represent
any downside for such customers, since it likely would enhance such customers opportunities for
choice.
CES states that, while ComEd did not oppose the CES recategorization, ComEd neglected to
describe how the Company intended to formally do so. According to CES, ComEds recategorization
methodology should be formally recognized in the instant proceeding and then be implemented in
ComEds rate case, which is currently pending as Docket 05-0597.
In its reply brief, CES states that ComEd should provide its recategorization methodology
within ten business days of the final order in this proceeding; and that ComEd should implement
this methodology in the Companys pending rate case.
ComEd did not oppose CES proposed to recategorize certain condominium customers as
non-residential for purposes of the Customer Supply Group definitions in Rider CPP.
In its reply brief, ComEd states that CES now urges the Commission to order ComEd to formally
recognize that the common areas of condominium buildings are to be recategorized under a commercial
rather than a residential classification. In ComEds view, what CES actually is seeking is
somewhat unclear, but it appears that CES now wishes ComEd to provide the methodology by which it
will effectuate the recategorization, to be formally recognized in this Docket and then
implemented in Docket 05-0597. ComEd claims this request is untimely, and ComEd does not see how
it can submit a proposed methodology on this subject at this point here. ComEd says at most, the
Order should reflect that ComEd has agreed to CES proposal and has agreed to effectuate it in
Docket 05-0597. ComEd argues that any methodological issue should be resolved in Docket 05-0597.
|
c. |
|
Commissions Analysis and Conclusions |
The Commission approves the proposal to recategorize certain condominium customers as
nonresidential for purposes of the Customer Supply Group definitions in Rider CPP. This
recommendation is supported by the record and is reasonable.
CES proposal for ComEd to provide its methodology within ten business days of the final order
in this proceeding and to implement this methodology in the Companys pending rate case is
untimely, unworkable and is therefore rejected. ComEd cannot simply provide a methodology in this
proceeding after the final order is entered and
231
05-0159
Proposed Order
implement that methodology in a different
proceeding without Commission approval of this methodology.
|
6. |
|
Treatment of Uncollectibles |
CES claims there is a lack of specific information in ComEds proposal regarding the
amount and methodology for determining the adjustment for supply-related uncollectible costs.
According to CES, ComEd offered no estimates of this cost component, and ComEd failed to propose an
allocation methodology. CES proposes that the Commission order ComEd to account separately for
uncollectible expenses between delivery services related uncollectible expenses and energy
related uncollectible expenses, and to charge customers accordingly.
CES states that although the proposed supply-related uncollectible expenses should be
established in the ComEd rate case, the instant proceeding is the appropriate place to ensure that
uncollectible expenses are recovered accurately and fairly. CES claims no party provided any
convincing reason for deferring discussion of this issue until the DST case.
CES asks the Commission to clarify in the instant proceeding that ComEds commodity customers,
and not its delivery service customers, are to pay energy-related uncollectible expenses.
Furthermore, CES asks the Commission to mandate in the instant proceeding that ComEd allocate these
costs evenly per kWh into the energy supply charges of the CPP-A (PPO-MVM), CPP-B and CPP-H
tariffs. Lastly, CES asks the Commission to order in the instant proceeding, that ComEd track
these supply-related uncollectible expenses in ComEds AAF, in order to ensure that the Company
neither over-collects nor under-collects these costs.
Staff says that CES notes the lack of specifics in ComEds proposal regarding the amount
and methodology for determining the adjustment for supply-related uncollectible costs. Staff
believes ComEd is correct that this matter would be better addressed in the rate case. Staff
contends that the rate case would present a more comprehensive set of facts and analysis upon which
to base decisions about this matter. Further, the rate case would provide the context in which to
review the costs of both the delivery and procurement segments and assign them appropriately.
Staff indicates that it and ComEd agree on the tariff language for the adjustment for
supply-related uncollectible costs. Staffs brief describes the initial misunderstanding between
Staff and ComEd on this issue and explains how it was ultimately resolved.
232
05-0159
Proposed Order
In its brief, ComEd stated its belief that there is no contested issue with regard to
uncollectibles.
In its reply brief, ComEd states with regard to whether supply related uncollectibles expenses
should be tracked in the AAF calculation, CES Initial Brief disagrees, in one sentence, with Staff
and ComEd. ComEd asserts that CES position is without merit.
ComEd describes CES proposal as a rather vague proposal that the Commission order ComEd to
implement an appropriate methodology for the proper allocation of uncollectible expenses. ComEd
argues that CES proposal is inappropriate in this Docket. ComEd believes the determination of
that component of the Supply Charges should be addressed in Docket 05-0597 where the adjustment
will be determined.
|
d. |
|
Commissions Analysis and Conclusions |
In the Commissions view, while CES has raised a valid concern, it is not necessary to
specify in this Order how uncollectibles will be allocated and tracked. The principle underlying
CES concern, that cost causers should pay, is legitimate. However, the record of this proceeding
is inadequate to make an informed decision regarding uncollectibles. Given that there is no
urgency to make a decision, the Commission defers its decision on this issue to Docket 05-0597, or
some other appropriate proceeding, with the hope and expectation that the record in that proceeding
will be sufficient.
|
7. |
|
Credit Risk and other Administrative Costs |
CES requests that the Commission order ComEd to implement a revised methodology for
allocating expenses that will be incurred as a result of ComEd providing service under Rate CPP-H.
According to CES, ComEds proposed rate structure does not properly allocate credit risk and
administrative costs to customers taking service under ComEds proposed CPP-H product. CES argues
that the hourly energy product, as currently proposed by ComEd, would not fully recover the costs
associated with providing that service to customers. CES claims that ComEds proposed CPP-H
product was meant to serve: (1) non-residential customers whose service has been declared
competitive; (2) self-generating customers; and (3) any other customers who voluntarily elect
hourly energy rates.
CES claims that additional costs exist that are associated with charging customers a rate that
changes on an hourly basis compared to a rate that is reset annually. According to CES, customers
taking Rate CPP-H will be exposed to
233
05-0159
Proposed Order
potentially wide variability in hourly prices. CES contends
that these customers will be exposed to a more volatile price and incur more significant risks.
CES asserts that this uncertainty in the prices to be charged to these customers increased the risk
that ComEd will have uncollectibles for customers taking service under this rate that well exceed
levels incurred by ComEd in providing service under its annual and multi-year blended rates.
According to CES, ComEds uncollectibles risk associated with providing service under an
hourly rate will be much greater under ComEds proposed post-transition rate structure. CES
further asserts that serving hourly customers likely will cost more than serving customers
receiving the Rate CPP-A and CPP-B products. CES contends that: (1) hourly products require more
intervention which, in turn, increased costs to serve (e.g., acquiring, scrubbing, and inputting
hourly data will take additional time to process); (2) hourly customers likely would have more
questions about their bills, especially when prices are high; and (3) there is a much higher
probability that Rate CPP-H bills would be delayed due to a lack of data, resulting in increased
working capital expenses. It is CES position that, the direct and indirect costs and related
capital expenditures should be considered in calculating the total cost associated with serving
hourly customers.
CES says that for consistency and for equity purposes, it recommends that these costs should
be allocated evenly per kWh to all customers receiving the hourly product.
ComEd opposes inclusion of a charge for credit risks and other administrative costs at
this time. ComEd states that CES proposal is a premature attempt to address in this Docket what
costs should go into the CPP-H Supply Administration Charges, which will be determined in Docket
05-0597, and, in any event, CES proposal lacks merit.
|
c. |
|
Commissions Analysis and Conclusions |
The Commission believes that, on its surface, CES argument that hourly customers cause
more costs to be incurred than fixed price customers is appealing. However, the record contains no
actual evidence supporting this assertion. As with several other CES recommendations, while the
Commission believes CES has raised legitimate concerns or issues, the record does not support
adopting its recommendation. Additionally, because there is no urgency to do so, the Commission
defers this issue to Docket 05-0597, or some other appropriate proceeding.
234
05-0159
Proposed Order
|
8. |
|
Integrated Distribution Company Issues |
CES recommends that the Commission direct ComEd to initiate a separate and new docketed
proceeding for consideration of new procurement process communication materials, to assist in
providing objective educational materials to the public that are in line with the Commissions
Integrated Distribution Company rules.
CES claims the Commission should be concerned about how ComEd may balance good customer
communications with what may be construed as marketing of its new supply options. CES asserts
that, for example, hosting customer lunches might be viewed by some as simply a forum for
education, while others may view it as marketing.
CES believes that ComEd and other interested parties should have an opportunity in an open
forum to derive an appropriate balance between getting the word out to customers about the supply
choices available from ComEd while ensuring there is no bias that would direct customers toward
necessarily taking those supply options offered by the utility. As a result, CES recommends that
the Commission direct ComEd to initiate a separate docketed proceeding in which such communication
and marketing materials would be reviewed, commented upon, and approved by the Commission. CES
also suggests that related accounting issues should be likewise addressed in these docketed
proceedings.
ComEd objects to CES proposal for a separate formal proceeding for the consideration of
any new ComEd communication materials related to the procurement process because ComEd is an
Integrated Distribution Company (IDC). ComEd states that CES did not cite any experience in the
over three years since ComEd became an IDC that warrants the proposal. As a Commission-approved
IDC, ComEd states that it is fully cognizant of the restrictions regarding marketing and attempts
to retain customers that are imposed upon it and of the strict three-strikes and youre out
provision, which if violated could require ComEd to functionally separate. ComEd claims that it
will continue to take the necessary measures to ensure that its actions comport with the
restrictions set forth in the Commissions rule.
ComEd says it is aware of, and complies with, its obligations as an IDC.
ComEd argues that the fact that some parties might challenge education materials as
advertising does not alter the fact that ComEd has the obligation to communicate with its customers
about its rates. Nor is it an indication, according to ComEd, that the requested proceeding would
be an efficient use of the parties and the Commissions resources.
235
05-0159
Proposed Order
ComEd maintains that a formal Commission proceeding, as proposed by CES, to evaluate, and to
litigate, the contents of proposed communication tools would be burdensome and unworkable. ComEd
argues that CES has not made the case for requiring other stakeholders, ComEd, Staff, and the
Commission to undertake the burdens and costs associated with such a Docket.
|
c. |
|
Commission Analysis and Conclusions |
The record contains no evidence suggesting ComEd is or can reasonably be expected to
become in violation of the Commissions IDC rules, 83 Ill. Adm. Code 452. In the event ComEd
violates the Commissions rules, the Commission would expect such a violation to be promptly
brought to its attention. However, at this time, the Commission rejects CES recommendation.
VIII. |
|
CONCLUSIONS AND MIXED LEGAL/FACTUAL ISSUES |
The legality of Rider CPP is discussed in Section III and other parts of this Order, and
the conclusion is contained therein.
|
B. |
|
Legality of Rider PPO-MVM |
The legality of Rider PPO-MVM is discussed in Section III and other parts of this Order,
and the conclusion is contained therein.
|
C. |
|
Issues Concerning Compliance of Auction Process Details with Illinois Law |
Cook County suggests that there may be provisions of Illinois law that are inconsistent
with the Illinois Auction process or with which the Commission will be unable to comply. A review
of each of the provisions identified by Cook County indicates that there is no such inconsistency.
The Illinois Auction will be conducted in accordance with Illinois law, and the Commission will
comply with all legal requirements.
|
1. |
|
Illinois Open Meetings Act |
The Open Meetings Act requires that [a]ll meetings of public bodies shall be open to the
public unless excepted in subsection (c) and closed in accordance with Section 2a. (5 ILCS
120/2(a)) A meeting is defined as any gathering of a majority of a quorum of the members of a
public body held for the purpose of discussing public business. (5 ILCS 120/1.02)
There is nothing in the Opens Meetings Act that is inconsistent with the Illinois Auction
process and there is no reason to assume that the Commission will fail to comply with the
requirements of that act. The auction is conducted by an independent
236
05-0159
Proposed Order
auction manager in accordance
with a process specified in a tariff approved by the Commission. The Commission does not conduct
the auction. To the extent that the Commission holds any meetings to take any action with respect
to the auction or the results of the auction, it will comply with the provisions of the Open
Meetings Act.
|
2. |
|
The Illinois Ethics Law |
The Illinois Ethics Law defines an ex parte communication as:
any written or oral communication by any person that imparts or requests material
information or makes a material argument regarding potential action concerning
regulatory, quasi-adjudicatory, investment, or licensing matters pending before or
under consideration by the agency.
5 ILCS 430/5-50 (b) (emphasis added)
The Illinois Auction is run by an independent auction manager in accordance with a process
specified in a tariff approved by the Commission. The auction is not a matter pending before or
under consideration by the Commission. In the event that any matters relating to the auction or
its results do become the subject of a regulatory, quasi-adjudicatory, investment, or licensing
matter pending before or under consideration by the Commission, the agency will comply with the
requirements of the Illinois Ethics Law.
|
3. |
|
Regulation of Public Records |
The regulation of public records provision, 220 ILCS 5/10-101, appears under Article X of
the Public Utilities Act entitled: Proceedings Before the Commission and the Courts. Section
10-101 itself begins:
The Commission, or any commissioner or hearing examiner designated by the
Commission, shall have power to hold investigations, inquiries and hearings
concerning any matters covered by the provisions of this Act, or by any other Acts
relating to public utilities subject to such rules and regulations as the Commission
may establish . . . . Complaint cases initiated pursuant to any Section of this
Act, investigative proceedings and ratemaking cases shall be considered contested
cases as defined in Section 1-30 of the Illinois Administrative Procedure Act (5
ILCS 100/1-30).
220 ILCS 5/10-101
The language of 220 ILCS 5/10-101 applies to investigations, inquiries, and hearings. In other
words, it applies to contested cases or other formal proceedings before the Commission.
237
05-0159
Proposed Order
As previously explained, the auction process is managed by an independent auction manager. It
is not an investigation, inquiry or hearing before the Commission. In the event that any matters
relating to the auction or its results do become the subject of an investigation, inquiry or
hearing, the Commission will comply with the regulation of public records provisions of the law.
|
4. |
|
Ex Parte Communications |
The Public Utilities Act states in part that [t]he provisions of Section 10-60 of the
Illinois Administrative Procedure Act shall apply in full to Commission proceedings. 220 ILCS
5/10-103. The Illinois Administrative Procedures Act is limited to contested cases before the
Commission. The relevant portion of the statute states:
Except in the disposition of matters that agencies are authorized by law to
entertain or dispose of on an ex parte basis, agency heads, agency employees, and
administrative law judges shall not, after notice of hearing in a contested case or
licensing to which the procedures of a contested case apply under this Act,
communicate directly or indirectly, in connection with any issue of fact, with any
person or party, or in connection with any other issue with any party or the
representative of any party, except upon notice an opportunity for all parties to
participate.
5 ILCS 100/10-60 (a) (emphasis added)
The Illinois Auction is not a contested case under the Illinois Administrative Procedures Act.
Contested case is defined as follows:
Contested case means an adjudicatory proceeding (not including ratemaking,
rulemaking, or quasi-legislative, informational, or similar proceedings) in which
the individual legal rights, duties, or privileges of a party are required by law to
be determined by an agency only after an opportunity for a hearing.
5 ILCS 100/1-30
The Public Utilities Act expands the definition of contested case to include investigative
proceedings and rate cases (see 220 ILCS 5/10-101). However, the Illinois Auction is not an
investigative proceeding or a rate case. In the event that any matters relating to the auction or
its results do become the subject of an investigative proceeding or a rate case, the Commission
will comply with the requirements of 220 ILCS 10-103.
|
5. |
|
Decisions of the ICC Being Based on Record Evidence |
Cook County also raised the concern that, in proceedings, investigations or hearings
conducted by the Commission, decisions are required to be made on record
238
05-0159
Proposed Order
evidence as defined in
220 ILCS 5/10-103. The Illinois Auction is not a proceeding, investigation or hearing conducted by
the Commission. In the event that any matters relating to the auction or its results do become the
subject of a proceeding, investigation or hearing conducted by the Commission, the Commission will
comply with the record evidence requirement.
|
D. |
|
Other Conclusions and Mixed Legal/Factual Issues |
All conclusions and mixed legal/factual issues are addressed in other parts of this
Order.
ComEd asserts that the eighth consensus attribute identified in the Commissions
Post-2006 Initiative was that the procurement process should be sufficiently flexible to permit
incorporation of renewable resource requirements. ComEd showed that its Illinois Auction Proposal
has this attribute.
Staff opposes CUB-CCSAOs recommendation to make renewable and energy efficiency
purchases through the auction, contending instead that if such resources are to be procured, they
should be so outside the auction. Staff notes that the Commission has recently adopted a policy of
encouraging voluntary participation by electric public utilities in a plan to make greater use of
renewable and energy efficiency resources, and that therefore it is not necessary for the
Commission to make any decisions about purchasing resources in this proceeding.
CUB-CCSAO argues that the Commission should consider Illinois renewable energy goals
when considering ComEds procurement proposal, and even if the Commission adopts the proposal, it
should retain authority and keep its options open regarding renewables and energy efficiency.
The record shows that the Illinois Auction Proposal is sufficiently flexible to permit
incorporation of any renewable resource requirements that might arise at a later time, and thus
meets the eighth consensus attribute of the Post-2006 Initiative. Such issues, therefore, are not
an impediment to the Commissions approval of the Proposal.
239
05-0159
Proposed Order
|
B. |
|
Additional Other Issues |
CUB suggests that testimony from ComEd and Exelon employees who hold stock of Exelon
might not be objective because Exelon might make a profit if it participates in the proposed
auction, and such employees have a personal and professional stake in such potential profit.
ComEd objects to this characterization, pointing to the record to show this suggestion of
possible bias is both unfounded and no reason to reject to discount the testimony. ComEd argues
that nothing in this record or in the witnesses demeanor, suggest that their testimony is anything
but objective, or should
be discounted. Nor has CUB provided any evidence whatsoever that any of these witnesses did
or could have biased his or her testimony.
The Commission observes that a number of witnesses for ComEd hold both ComEd and Exelon
positions/titles. The Commission concludes that parties have not cited to the Commission any
authority that would authorize or require the Commission to assume that those witnesses are
promoting the auction proposal to simply enrich a parent company because they hold concurrent
positions. The Commission finds no reason to discount this testimony.
X. |
|
FINDINGS AND ORDERING PARAGRAPHS |
The Commission, having considered the entire record herein and being fully advised in the
premises, is of the opinion and finds that:
|
(1) |
|
Commonwealth Edison Company is an Illinois corporation engaged in the retail
sale and delivery of electricity to the public in Illinois, and is a public utility
as defined in Section 3-105 of the Public Utilities Act and an electric utility as
defined in Section 16-102 of the Public Utilities Act; |
|
|
(2) |
|
the Commission has jurisdiction over the parties and the subject matter herein; |
|
|
(3) |
|
the recitals of fact and conclusions of law reached in the prefatory portion of
this Order are supported by the evidence of record, and are hereby adopted as findings
of fact and conclusions of law; |
|
|
(4) |
|
the Commission has authority under the Public Utilities Act to establish
reasonable rates and charges for retail service, including Rider CPP and PPO-MVM as
modified in this Order; |
240
05-0159
Proposed Order
|
(5) |
|
the Commission has the authority to approve the competitive procurement process
and the associated tariffs, subject to the conditions imposed for procurement of power
and energy; |
|
|
(6) |
|
the tariff proposed by ComEd in its initial filing, as modified to reflect the
findings herein, are just and reasonable, and ComEd should be authorized to file and
put into effect such tariff sheets, as modified; |
|
|
(7) |
|
the new tariff sheets authorized to be filed by this Order should reflect an
effective date not less than 30 days after the date of filing, with the tariff sheets
to be corrected, if necessary, within that time period, and should reflect an
operational date of no earlier than January 2, 2007; |
|
|
(8) |
|
ComEd should be subject to the annual reconciliation proceedings related to its
power purchases as described and approved in the prefatory portion of this Order; and |
|
|
(9) |
|
ComEd should be required to implement the rate mitigation proposal described
and approved in the prefatory part of this Order. |
IT IS THEREFORE ORDERED by the Illinois Commerce Commission that the proposed tariff sheets to
implement a competitive procurement process by establishing Rider CPP, Rider PPO-MVM, and Rider
TS-CPP and revising Rider PPO-MI, filed by Commonwealth Edison Company on February 25, 2005, are
permanently canceled and annulled.
IT IS FURTHER ORDERED that Commonwealth Edison Company is authorized and directed to file new
tariff sheets with supporting workpapers in accordance with the Findings of this Order, applicable
on and after the effective date of said tariff sheets and operational on and after January 2, 2007.
IT IS FURTHER ORDERED that any motions, petitions, objections, and other matters in this
proceeding that remain unresolved are disposed of consistent with the conclusions herein.
IT IS FURTHER ORDERED that Commonwealth Edison Company shall be subject to the annual
reconciliation proceedings related to its power purchases as described and approved in the
prefatory part of this Order.
IT IS FURTHER ORDERED that Commonwealth Edison Company is directed to file tariffs that
implement the rate mitigation proposal described and approved in the prefatory part of this Order.
241
05-0159
Proposed Order
IT IS FURTHER ORDERED that, subject to the provisions of Section 10-113 of the Public
Utilities Act and 83 Ill. Adm. Code 200.880, this Order is final; it is not subject to the
Administrative Review Law.
DATED: December 5, 2005
ADMINISTRATIVE LAW JUDGE
Briefs on Exceptions due: December 19, 2005
Reply Briefs on Exceptions due: December 27, 2005
242