uv1za
File No. 70-10294
UNITED STATES SECURITIES AND EXCHANGE COMMISSION
WASHINGTON, D.C. 20549
FORM U-1/A
AMENDMENT NO. 3
TO THE
APPLICATION-DECLARATION
UNDER
THE PUBLIC UTILITY HOLDING COMPANY ACT OF 1935
|
|
|
Exelon Corporation
|
|
Public Service |
(and the Subsidiaries listed on the
|
|
Enterprise Group Incorporated |
Signature Page hereto)
|
|
(on behalf of the Subsidiaries listed |
10 South Dearborn Street
|
|
on the Signature Page hereto) |
37th Floor
|
|
80 Park Plaza |
Chicago, IL 60603
|
|
Newark, New Jersey 07102 |
(Name of companies filing this statement and address of principal executive office)
Exelon Corporation
(Name of top registered holding company)
|
|
|
Randall E. Mehrberg
|
|
R. Edwin Selover |
Executive Vice President and
|
|
Senior Vice President and |
General Counsel
|
|
General Counsel |
Exelon Corporation
|
|
Public Service Enterprise |
10 South Dearborn Street
|
|
Group Incorporated |
37th Floor
|
|
80 Park Plaza |
Chicago, IL 60603
|
|
Newark, New Jersey 07102 |
(Name and address of agent for service)
The Commission is requested to send copies of all notices, orders and communications in
connection
with this Application-Declaration to:
|
|
|
Scott N. Peters
|
|
Tamara L. Linde |
Constance W. Reinhard
|
|
Jason A. Lewis |
Exelon Corporation
|
|
PSEG Services Corporation |
10 South Dearborn Street, 35th Floor
|
|
80 Park Plaza |
Chicago, Illinois 60603
|
|
Newark, New Jersey 07101 |
312-394-3604
|
|
973-430-8058 |
|
|
|
Joanne C. Rutkowski
|
|
Timothy M. Toy |
Baker Botts L.L.P.
|
|
Bracewell & Giuliani LLP |
1299 Pennsylvania Ave., NW
|
|
1177 Avenue of the Americas |
Washington, DC 20004
|
|
New York, NY 10036-2714 |
202-639-7785
|
|
212-508-6118 |
|
|
|
William J. Harmon |
|
|
Jones Day |
|
|
77 West Wacker, Suite 3500 |
|
|
Chicago, Illinois 60601 |
|
|
312-782-3939 |
|
|
Applicants hereby incorporate by reference Amendment No. 2 to the application/declaration in
File No. 70-10294 and provide the following supplemental information:
Item 1. Description of Proposed Transaction
A. Introduction
On December 29, 2005, the Securities and Exchange Commission (the Commission or SEC)
issued a notice in File No. 70-10294 under the Public Utility Holding Company Act of 1935 (the
1935 Act or Act), relating to the proposed merger (the Merger) of Exelon Corporation
(Exelon) and Public Service Enterprise Group Incorporated (PSEG and, together with Exelon, the
Applicants). The return date on the notice is January 23, 2006.
Applicants are hereby asking the Commission to take such action as it may deem necessary to
make findings under Section 11(b) of the Act in connection with the required asset divestiture
(Divestiture) described more fully in Item 3(b) (Section 11(e) Plan). In the Commissions
discretion, such findings could be incorporated in an order approving the Merger and related
transactions. In the alternative, the Commission could make the requested findings in an order
approving the Applicants Section 11(e) Plan. Such findings are necessary to preserve for
Applicants the ability to qualify for certain tax relief in connection with the Divestiture.
Applicants believe that the net present value of the relief would exceed $100 million.
Applicants understand that the Commission could choose not to act, given the pendency of
repeal and the press of other
business.1
They believe, however, that the
better course would be for the Commission to make the requested findings, which are consistent with
the facts and the law, and leave to the Internal Revenue Service the application of tax law to
those findings. In support of their request, Applicants note the following:
The Commission Staff has indicated
that it has no substantive problems with the Merger as
such. The record in this matter is largely complete and Applicants believe that the Commission
could properly issue an order at the completion of the notice period, approving the Merger and
related transactions.2 Rather than press for the issuance of a comprehensive
order, Applicants instead suggest that the Commission might focus on the one aspect of its
authorization that will have continuing effect post-repeal, namely, findings in connection with the
very substantial divestiture of generation that will form the predicate for tax relief under
section 1081 of the Internal Revenue Code of 1986, as amended (Code).
|
§
|
|
Section 1081 is one of a series of tax provisions intended to mitigate the economic
consequences of certain government-compelled actions. |
|
|
|
1 |
|
On Monday, August 8, 2005, the Energy Policy
Act of 2005 (H.R. 6, 109th Cong.) was signed by the President and became law,
Pub.L. 109-58. Title XII of the Energy Policy Act is the Electricity
Modernization Act of 2005 (the Modernization Act). Subtitle F of the
Modernization Act, the Public Utility Holding Company Act of 2005 (PUHCA
2005) repeals the 1935 Act, effective six months after the date of enactment
(February 8, 2006 or the Effective Date). |
|
2 |
|
Applicants have not yet received an order
from the New Jersey Board of Public Utilities. While the Commission typically
waits until all state approvals have been received, where circumstances
warrant, the Commission has issued merger orders, the effectiveness of which is
conditioned upon receipt of a subsequent state approval. See Northeast
Utilities, Holding Co. Act Release No. 25221 (Dec. 21, 1990) (Pursuant
to rule 24(c)(2), when an issue under state law is raised, we may approve the
transaction under section 10, subject to compliance with state law.),
citing Central and South West Corporation, Holding Co. Act Release No. 22635
(Sept. 16, 1982). |
1
|
§
|
|
Of interest here, section 1081 permits a party to defer recognition of gain on
transactions that have been found to be necessary or appropriate to effectuate the
provisions of Section 11(b) of the 1935 Act. |
|
|
§
|
|
Further, a partys ability to avail itself of the benefits of section 1081 survives
repeal of the Act. See section 1271(c) of the Energy Policy Act of 2005, which expressly
provides that: Tax treatment under section 1081 of the [Code] as a result of transactions
ordered in compliance with the [Act] shall not be affected in any manner due to the repeal
of that Act and the enactment of the Public Utility Holding Company Act of
2005.3 |
The Commission can make the requested findings on the basis of the record before it,
regardless of whether it ultimately passes on the Merger as a whole. The predicate for the Section
11(b) finding exists in the form of the approvals that have already been granted by the Federal
Energy Regulatory Commission (FERC).
|
§
|
|
In its July 1, 2005 order approving the Merger, the FERC determined that a very
substantial divestiture of generation, including the divestiture by sale of 4,000 MW of
generating capacity, was necessary to address potential anticompetitive consequences of
the Merger.4 |
|
|
§
|
|
In the ordinary course of its review, the Commission would watchfully defer to the
FERCs action, including the need for divestiture, for purposes of its findings under
Section 10(b)(1) of the 1935 Act that the Merger not result in a concentration of control
of public-utility companies, of a kind or to an extent detrimental to the public interest
or the interest of investors or consumers.5 |
|
|
|
3 |
|
In addition, Congress has passed
legislation (HR 4440) that includes technical corrections that, among other
things, repeal Section 1081 prospectively. The technical explanation of the
Senate bill contains the following description regarding the technical
correction dealing with the 1935 Act and Section 1081 repeal: |
|
|
|
Repeal of the Public Utility Holding Company Act of 1935 (Act
sec. 1263).-The provision repeals sections 1081-1083 of the Code
(relating to exchanges in obedience to SEC orders) to conform to
the repeal of the Public Utility Holding Company Act of 1935. The
repeal does not apply to any exchange, expenditure, investment,
distribution, or sale made in obedience to an order of the
Securities and Exchange Commission. |
|
|
|
Id. at p. 75. |
|
4 |
|
At the time they announced their Transaction,
Applicants noted that, absent divestiture, the Merger could create significant
market power concerns. To that end, Applicants proposed, and the FERC
accepted, a mitigation plan (the Mitigation Plan) to address FERC
requirements for competitive markets. A substantial part of the Mitigation
Pan is the proposed very substantial divestiture of generation.
See Order Authorizing Merger under Section 203 of the Federal Power Act, 112
FERC 61,011 (July 1, 2005) (the FERC Merger Order). In December,
2005, the FERC affirmed its decision. In addressing the arguments raised on
rehearing, the FERC emphasized that the proposed merger included mitigation
measures to curb any competitive harm that might arise from the
utilities merger through substantial divestiture of generation
and several compliance filings. |
|
5 |
|
The Commission has long believed, and
the courts have agreed, that it is appropriate for the Commission to
look to or watchfully defer to the expertise of the
FERC in matters such as these, involving the operation and regulation of
competitive energy markets. See Madison Gas & Electric Co. v. SEC, 168 F.3d
1337, 1341-42 (D.C. 1999) (when the SEC and another regulatory agency
both have jurisdiction over a particular transaction, the SEC may
watchfully defer[] to the proceedings held before and the
result reached by that other agency), citing City of Holyoke Gas &
Electric Department v. SEC, 972 F.2d 358 (D.C. Cir. 1992). |
In so doing, the Commission would incorporate by reference the conditions
of the FERC order, including the divestiture requirement . Thus, even if the
Commission did not expressly order divestiture, it would incorporate by
reference the FERC requirement.
2
|
§
|
|
The findings and remedies under Section 10(b)(1) of the Act are intended to ensure,
among other things, that the resulting electric utility system is not so large as to
impair . . . the effectiveness of regulation under Section 11(b)(1) of the Act (by
reference to Section 2(a)(29) of the Act). |
Further, the interrelation of the FERC and SEC findings, on the one hand, and Sections
10(b)(1) and 11(b)(1) of the 1935 Act, on the other, are well established.
|
§
|
|
Concerning the FERC and SEC findings, the Federal Power Act and the 1935 Act are
coordinate titles of the Public Utility Act of 1935. Responsibility, sometimes
overlapping, was allocated between the two agencies with the goal of ensuring effective
public regulation of the utility industry. See Sections 1(b) and 1(c) of the 1935 Act.
The legislative history makes clear that the purpose of Section 11 of the Act is simply
to provide a mechanism to create conditions under which effective Federal and State
regulation will be possible. S. Rep. No. 621, 74th Cong., 1st Sess. 11 (1935) (Report of
Senator Wheeler from the Committee on Interstate Commerce). |
|
|
§
|
|
Findings under Sections 10 and 11 of the 1935 Act are even more closely linked. Simply
stated, Sections 9 and 10 are preventive in purpose. Their essential function is to avoid
recreating, by acquisition, what Section 11(b) was designed to undo or eliminate. Public
Service Company of Oklahoma, Holding Co. Act Release 19090 (July 17, 1975); see also
American Electric Power Company, Inc., Holding Co. Act Release No. 20633 (July 21, 1978)
(footnotes omitted) (noting that Section 10, in particular was intended to prevent
acquisitions which would be attended by the evils which have featured the past growth of
holding companies.). |
Finally, Section 11(e) of the Act provides a mechanism by which the Commission can address the
Section 11(b) issues in isolation, reserving jurisdiction over Applicants other requests.
|
§
|
|
As the United States Supreme Court has explained: Section 11(e) merely permits the
holding companies to formulate their own programs for compliance with § 11(b)(1) or to
submit plans in conformity with prior Commission orders under § 11(b), . . . . American
Power Co. v. SEC, 329 U.S. 90, 119 (1946). |
In this matter, the standards for approval of a plan, that it be both necessary to effectuate the
provisions of Section 11(b), and fair and equitable to the persons affected by such plan, are
met.
|
§
|
|
The Commission has declared that [a] plan is necessary within the meaning of section
11(e), . . . if it accomplishes the objectives required by section 11(b) in an appropriate
manner. Midland Utilities, 24 S.E.C. 463, 475 (1946). It thus seems clear that Section
11(e) permits a company to propose particular transactions which under our ordinary
practice we would not, or perhaps could not, specifically require by order under Section
11(b). See also Mission Oil Co., 35 S.E.C. 540 (1954) (in which the Commission
authorized a Section 11(e) plan to enable applicant to obtain tax relief). |
|
|
§
|
|
Consistent with Commission precedent, Applicants Divestiture plan is necessary to
ensure that the resulting electric-utility system is not so large as to impair . . . the
effectiveness of regulation (Section 11(b)(1) by reference to Section 2(a)(29)). |
|
|
§
|
|
The Divestiture plan is also fair and equitable to the public interest and the
interest of investors and consumers, the protected interests under the Act. |
3
|
°
|
|
If, for some reason, the Merger does not close, the order approving
the Section 11(e) Plan will be of no effect, other than for tax relief
purposes.6 |
|
|
°
|
|
If, however, as Applicants anticipate, the Merger does close in the
first half of 2006, the tax deferrals will contribute to the financial health of
the merged company and so be in the public interest for purposes of the Act. |
|
|
°
|
|
Similarly, although the 1935 Act does not provide extra protection
for shareholders of registered holding companies, the tax deferrals will clearly
be beneficial to the interest of investors and, by bolstering the financial health
of the merged company, similarly beneficial to the interests of consumers |
|
|
°
|
|
Moreoever, the 1935 Act is still effective through February 8, 2006
and the Applicants are requesting relief under the currently effective 1935 Act.
While effective, the Commission should affirmatively act and should not, through
procedural or other delays, disregard the Applicants rights to obtain a fair
determination under the 1935 Act. |
Applicants submit that the circumstances a major merger involving an unprecedented amount
of divesture and legislation that offers significant potential relief in connection with that
divestiture clearly warrant Commission action. The sole operative effect of the requested order
would be to enable Applicants to qualify for tax relief. Even with the Commissions order, there
is no guarantee that the Internal Revenue Service will agree that they are entitled to the relief.
Absent such an order, however, Applicants will have no basis for seeking such relief and the
potential tax savings with net present value in excess of $100 million will be irrevocably
lost to the very interests the Act was intended to protect. Accordingly, Applicants urge the
Commission to issue an order making the necessary findings prior to February 8, 2006, the effective
date of repeal.
B. Exelon Generation Restructuring
After obtaining any appropriate third-party consents, including consents of certain PSEG Power
debt holders to certain amendments of PSEG Power debt agreements, the Applicants will undertake the
Exelon Generation Restructuring such that PSEG Power and its direct subsidiaries PSEG Nuclear, PSEG
Fossil and PSEG ER&T will all cease to exist as separate entities and will become part of Exelon
Generation. The business functions of these former PSEG entities will become a part of their
respective Exelon Generation business unit. The subsidiaries owned by these PSEG entities will be
retained as direct subsidiaries of Exelon Generation, which will continue to be an electric utility
company for purposes of the Act. It is contemplated that the Exelon Generation Restructuring will
take place contemporaneously with the closing of the Merger. See Exhibits G-1, G-2 and G-3 hereto
for diagrams of the pre-Merger and post-Merger corporate structures.
It is anticipated that the current subsidiaries of PSEG Fossil that own and/or operate
electric generation facilities will remain subsidiaries of Exelon Generation as exempt wholesale
generators (EWGs). The Exelon Generation Restructuring will not result in any new public
utility subsidiary of Exelon Generation.
|
|
|
6 |
|
Applicants acknowledge that the proposed
Section 11(e) plan is forward-looking and contingent on events that may take
place, if at all, only after the effective date of repeal They believe,
however, that there are two important points in this regard: (i) Section
1271(c) of the Energy Policy Act of 2005 expressly contemplates that parties
will be able to rely post-repeal on Commission orders that have been issued
prior to the effective date of repeal; and (ii) the Commission routinely issues
forward-looking orders; financing orders, for example, routinely authorize a
wide range of transactions that may or may not occur in the future. |
4
Applicants seek such approval as may be required for the Exelon Generation
Restructuring.7
C. Generation Transactions
1. Generation Divestiture Overview
The proposed Merger will increase the total capacity of generation resources owned or
controlled by Exelon. To ensure that the combined company does not have market power in any
relevant market, Exelon and PSEG have proposed the Mitigation Plan designed to address in full the
FERCs requirements for competitive markets. As part of the plan, the companies have proposed a
divestiture as further described in this Item 1(C) (the Generation Divestiture) to divest a
number of coal, mid-merit, and peaking generating plants. The Mitigation Plan also provides for
the transfer of control of the output of a portion of their baseload nuclear generating capacity.
The final divestiture proposal made by Applicants and approved by the FERC in the FERC Merger
Order will result in Applicants divesting 6,600 MW of electric generating capacity. Of this, 4,000
MW will be physically divested fossil generation. Under the FERC Merger Order, Applicants are
required to make a compliance filing to the FERC within 30 days of the completion of their physical
divestiture, providing an analysis of the Mergers effect on competition in energy and capacity
markets, given actual plants and assets divested and the actual acquirers of the divested assets.
If the analysis shows that the Mergers harm to competition has not been sufficiently mitigated,
Applicants must propose additional mitigation at that time. The divestiture of the 4,000 MW
contemplated in the FERC Merger Order plus any subsequent physical divestiture ordered by the FERC
as necessary additional mitigation is referred to herein as the Generation Divestiture.
Rather than divest their nuclear baseload units, the Applicants have proposed, and the FERC
has accepted, a virtual divestiture whereby they will divest, through sales of long-term firm
energy rights, 2,600 MW of nuclear generating capacity in PJM East. Such virtual divestiture
will take the form of the FERC jurisdictional wholesale power transactions and will not constitute
the disposition of utility assets within the meaning of the Act, therefore, no approval by the
Commission is required for the virtual divestiture.
Exhibit G-4 to the Application previously filed herein is a listing of generation facilities
subject to divestiture as initially proposed by Exelon and PSEG (1,000 MW of peaking capacity and a
total of 1,900 MW of mid-merit capacity of which 550 MW would be coal-fired). Subsequent to filing
the Application, the proposed Generation Divestiture was expanded by an additional 1,100 MW for the
total divestiture as approved in the FERC Merger Order of 6,600 MW as noted above and certain other
generation facilities were added to the list subject to divestiture. See Exhibit G-4.1 for the
final list of the facilities that may be subject to the Generation Divestiture.
The FERC Merger Order requires Applicants to execute sales agreements and make appropriate
filings at the FERC within twelve (12) months of the closing of the Merger in order to implement
the Generation Divestiture. The Applicants intend to commence the divestiture process more
quickly, but 12
|
|
|
7 |
|
As explained more fully herein, the FERC has
granted the necessary approvals related to the Exelon Generation Restructuring.
The New Jersey Department of Environmental Protection (NJDEP) has determined
that the Industrial Site Recovery Act (ISRA) does not apply to the Merger and
its related corporate reorganizations including the Generation Restructuring.
Filings have also been made with the Connecticut Siting Council (the Siting
Counsel) and the Connecticut Department of Environmental Protection (CDEP)
with respect to the implications of the Merger and the Generation Restructuring
to the generating stations located in Connecticut and owned by a subsidiary of
PSEG Fossil. The Siting Counsel has approved the Merger and CDEP approval will
be sought closer to the expected time of the Merger (CDEP approvals are valid
only for ninety days). |
5
months may be necessary to conduct a sales process, negotiate all necessary agreements and
file for all necessary regulatory approvals.
As explained more fully herein, the FERC has approved the Merger based upon, among other
things, the Mitigation Plan and Applicants are asking the Commission to make the necessary findings
to support relief pursuant to section 1081 of the Code with respect to the Generation Transactions.
None of the proposed mitigation, including the Generation Divestiture, would adversely affect the
integration of the combined electric utility operations for purposes of the Act.
Applicants propose to effect the Generation Divestiture pursuant to a voluntary plan under
Section 11(e) of the Act. The Commission has consistently held that a plan under Section 11(e) of
the Act may be found necessary if it provides an appropriate means to achieving results required
by Section 11(b) of the Act. See, e.g., Northeast Utilities, Holding Co. Act Release No. 24908
(June 22, 1989) (approving a Section 11(e) plan to dispose of gas distribution system assets via a
spin-off of common stock of a newly constituted holding company system). Under Section 11(e) of
the Act, the Commission shall approve a plan if it finds that:
|
|
|
the plan is fair and equitable to persons affected by the plan; and |
|
|
|
|
the plan is necessary to carry out the provisions of Section 11(b) of the Act. |
In this matter, the Generation Divestiture has been found by the FERC to be necessary and in the
public interest as the fundamental underpinning of the FERC Merger Order. Generation Divestiture
has or will be an essential aspect of the effective performance by the FERC, of its regulatory
role. The reduction in the size of the combined companys generation fleet to reduce market power
and so provide for the effectiveness of regulation is at the core of the Acts Section 11(b)
integrated public-utility system mandate. Since the Generation Divestiture will be an essential
aspect of the exercise of non-Commission regulatory oversight of the Merger, the Generation
Divestiture has become an appropriate means of achieving the Acts Section 11(b) mandate.
2. Generation Transactions Background
Exelon Generation owns or controls all of the Exelon systems generating assets including the
electric generating units that are subject to being divested as part of the Generation Divestiture.
PSEG Fossil is an EWG under Section 32 of the Act and a wholly-owned subsidiary of PSEG Power.
PSEG Fossil owns directly the electric generating units that are subject to being divested as part
of the Generation Divestiture.
3. Exelon Generation Restructuring
After obtaining necessary approvals and third party consents, PSEG Power and PSEG Fossil will
cease to exist as separate entities and will become part of Exelon Generation. Accordingly, the
Generation Transactions will be specified in this Application on the assumption that the Exelon
Generation Restructuring will precede the Generation Divestiture Restructuring and the Generation
Divestiture.
4. Divestiture Generation Restructuring
In order to maximize the amount a buyer would be willing to pay for the Subject Assets,
defined below, the Applicants are considering alternative options for effecting the disposition by
sale of the electric generating assets listed in Exhibit G-10 (the Subject Assets), as required
by the Generation Divestiture.8 Subsequent to the Merger but prior to the
implementation of any of the options set forth below, Exelon
|
|
|
8 |
|
Exhibit G-11 reflects Subject Assets owned by
PSEG Fossil and Exhibit G-12 reflects the Subject Assets owned by Exelon
Generation prior to the Consolidating Transfers. |
6
would cause the assets listed in Exhibit G-11 owned by PSEG Fossil to be transferred to Exelon
Generation, which currently owns the assets listed in Exhibit G-12 (the Consolidating Transfers).
Pursuant to Option 2 described below, an internal restructuring would occur immediately prior to
the disposition of the Subject Assets to the buyer that would change the ownership structure of the
Subject Assets. The particular tax characteristics of the sale of a generating unit, including the
buyers desired business and tax structures, would determine which option would be utilized.
Because there are likely to be multiple buyers of the Subject Assets (each such buyer a Third
Party), the Applicants may utilize either of the disposition options to effectuate the sale of the
Subject Assets to each Third Party (the disposition to each such Third Party is referred to herein
as a Divestiture Transaction). Each of the Subject Assets would be acquired pursuant to each
Divestiture Transaction in exchange for cash and/or notes (the Transfer Consideration).
|
|
Option 1: Exelon Generation would sell each of the assets listed in Exhibit G-13
to a Third Party pursuant to the Divestiture Transaction in exchange for the Transfer
Consideration. Exelon Generation may distribute to Exelon (via Ventures) the Transfer
Consideration received. |
|
|
|
Option 2: Exelon Generation would sell, in exchange for an amount of cash equal to
the Transfer Consideration, each of the assets listed in Exhibit G-14 to the corporation
wholly-owned by Ventures that is listed as the Acquiring Sub next to that asset in
Exhibit G-14. Exelon Generation may distribute to Exelon (via Ventures) the cash received.
Ventures would then sell all of the interests in the Acquiring Sub to the Third Party in
exchange for the Transfer Consideration. |
The particulars of the option selected for each Divestiture Transaction would be specified in
the applicable post-Merger FERC compliance filing. Each of the steps outlined in Option 2 above
could occur simultaneously.
5. Summary of Relevant Provisions of the Internal Revenue Code
Code section 1081(b)(1) provides for the nonrecognition of gain or loss from a sale or
exchange of property made in obedience to a Commission order; however, gain will not be recognized
only to the extent that it can be (and is) applied to reduce the basis of the transferors
remaining assets as provided in Code section 1082(a)(2). In the event that the transferor receives
nonexempt property in the exchange,9 Code section 1081(b)(2) mandates that
gain be recognized unless, within 24 months of the exchange, the transferor uses the nonexempt
property to acquire property other than nonexempt property or invests the nonexempt property in
accordance with that paragraph, and an order of the Commission recites that such expenditure or
investment is necessary or appropriate to the integration or simplification of the transferors
holding company system.
Code section 1081(d) provides for the nonrecognition of gain or loss from certain intercompany
transactions between members of the same system group if such transactions are made in obedience to
a Commission order. System group is defined in Code section 1083(d) to include, as a general
matter, corporations connected by common ownership with at least 90 percent of each class of stock
of the corporations owned by other members of the system group.
6. Section 1081 Recitals
|
|
|
9 |
|
The term nonexempt property is defined in
Code section 1083(e) to include, among other things, cash and indebtedness of
the transferor that is cancelled or assumed by the purchaser in the exchange. |
7
It is requested that the order of the Commission on this Application: (i) recite that the sale
or disposition of generating units as part of the Generation Transactions is necessary or
appropriate to the integration or simplification of the post-Merger Exelon holding company system
and to effectuate the provisions of Section 11(b) of the Act; and (ii) require post-Merger Exelon
to take appropriate actions to cause its direct and indirect subsidiaries, as the case may be, to
complete the Generation Divestiture as required in order to comply with the FERC Merger
Order.10
In particular, the Applicants request that the Commission include the following in its
order:
The transfer of the assets listed in Exhibit G-11 from PSEG Fossil to PSEG Power, followed by
the transfer of the interests in PSEG Power by Exelon to Ventures and then by Ventures to Exelon
Generation, followed by the transfer of the assets listed in Exhibit G-11 by PSEG Power to Exelon
Generation, are found to be necessary or appropriate to the integration or simplification of the
post-Merger Exelon holding company system and to effectuate the provisions of Section 11(b) of the
Act; and Exelon shall cause PSEG Fossil to transfer to PSEG Power the assets listed in Exhibit
G-11, followed by the transfer of the interests in PSEG Power by Exelon to Ventures and then by
Ventures to Exelon Generation, followed by the transfer of the assets listed in Exhibit G-11 from
PSEG Power to Exelon Generation, in exchange for cash and/or notes (the notes referred to as the
Consolidation Notes) in accordance with section 1081(d) of the Code.
Each sale of the assets listed in Exhibit G-13 from Exelon Generation to a Third Party is
found to be necessary or appropriate to the integration or simplification of the post-Merger Exelon
holding company system and to effectuate the provisions of Section 11(b) of the Act; each sale of
the assets listed in Exhibit G-13 by Exelon Generation shall be made to the Third Party in exchange
for cash and/or notes in accordance with section 1081(b)(1) of the Code; and to the extent
that the cash and/or notes received in such sale constitutes nonexempt property, Exelon shall
cause such proceeds to be reinvested within 24 months of the divestiture date in a manner that
complies with section 1081(b)(2) of the Code, which includes the satisfaction by Exelon Generation
of the Consolidation Notes.
Each sale of the assets listed in Exhibit G-14 from Exelon Generation to the corporation
wholly-owned by Ventures that is listed as the Acquiring Sub next to that specific asset in
Exhibit G-14, followed by each sale of such Acquiring Sub stock by Ventures to a Third Party, are
found to be necessary or appropriate to the integration or simplification of the post-Merger Exelon
holding company system and to effectuate the provisions of Section 11(b) of the Act; each sale of
the assets listed in Exhibit G-14 by Exelon Generation shall be to the corporation wholly-owned by
Ventures that is listed as the Acquiring Sub next to that specific asset in Exhibit G-14 in
exchange for cash in accordance with section 1081(d) of the Code, and shall be followed by the sale
of such Acquiring Sub stock by Ventures to a Third Party in exchange for cash and/or notes in
accordance with section 1081(b) of the Code; and to the extent that the cash and/or notes
received in the sale of the Acquiring Sub stock to the Third Party constitutes nonexempt
property, Exelon shall cause such proceeds to be reinvested within 24 months of the divestiture
date in a manner that complies with section 1081(b)(2) of the Code, which includes the satisfaction
by Exelon Generation of the Consolidation Notes.
Each distribution by Exelon Generation to Ventures, followed by each distribution by Ventures
to Exelon, of the cash and/or notes received by Exelon Generation on the sale of the assets listed
in Exhibit G-13 to a Third Party or the assets listed in Exhibit G-14 to an Acquiring Sub, and each
distribution from
|
|
|
10 |
|
The Commission has issued a number of orders
making similar Section 1081-related tax recitals in connection with other
divestitures in compliance with orders under Section 11(b)(1) of the Act in
furtherance of voluntary Section 11(e) plans. See, e.g., Ameren Corp., Holding
Company Act Release No. 27645 (January 29, 2003); KeySpan Corp., Holding
Company Act Release No. 27541 (June 19, 2002); NiSource, Inc., Holding Company
Act Release No. 27525 (April 29, 2002) and Progress Energy, Inc., Holding
Company Act Release No. 27444 (Sept. 26, 2001). |
8
Ventures to Exelon of the cash and/or notes received on the sale of the stock of Acquiring Sub
to a Third Party, are found to be necessary or appropriate to the integration or simplification of
the post-Merger Exelon holding company system and to effectuate the provisions of Section 11(b) of
the Act; and each distribution by Exelon Generation of the cash and/or notes received by Exelon
Generation on the sale of the assets listed in Exhibit G-13 to a Third Party or the assets listed
in Exhibit G-14 to an Acquiring Sub shall be made to Ventures in accordance with section 1081(d) of
the Code, each distribution by Ventures of such cash and/or notes shall be made to Exelon in
accordance with section 1081(d) of the Code, and each distribution by Ventures of the cash and/or
notes received on the sale of the Acquiring Sub stock to a Third Party shall be made to Exelon in
accordance with section 1081(d) of the Code.
The foregoing request for Code section 1081 recitals is subject to possible modification (to
be detailed in an amendment to this Application) so that the subject Divestiture Transaction
encompasses all physical assets being disposed of by the Applicants in connection with obtaining
Merger-related approvals.
Item 2. Fees, Commissions And Expenses.
The fees, commissions and expenses to be paid or incurred, directly or indirectly, in
connection with the Merger, including the solicitation of proxies, registration of securities of
Exelon under the Securities Act of 1933, and other related matters, are estimated to be
approximately $70 million.
Item 3. Applicable Statutory Provisions.
A. Applicable Provisions.
Sections 6(a), 7, 8, 9, 10, 11(b)(1), 11(e), 12, 13, 32 and 33 of the Act and the rules
thereunder are considered applicable to the Merger and the proposed transactions. Sections 10 and
11 of the Act are applicable to the proposed Divestiture.
To the extent that the proposed transactions are considered by the Commission to require
authorizations, exemption or approval under any section of the Act or the rules and regulations
thereunder other than those set forth above, request for such authorization, exemption or approval
is hereby made.
B. Analysis of Section 11(e) Plan
Applicants propose to effect the Generation Divestiture pursuant to a voluntary plan under
Section 11(e) of the Act. To approve a Section 11(e) plan, the Commission must determine, after
notice and opportunity for hearing, that the plan is both necessary to effectuate the provisions
of Section 11(b), and fair and equitable to the persons affected by such plan. Northeast
Utilities, Holding Co. Act Release No. 24908 (June 22, 1989), citing Valley Gas Co., 40 S.E.C. 162,
167 (Aug. 10, 1960).
Simply stated, Section 11(e) of the Act provides a voluntary means for complying with Section
11(b) of the Act. There is nothing novel about Applicants use of a Section 11(e) plan. Voluntary
divestiture plans have long been used by public utility holding companies to identify and divest
non-compliant interests. Joel Seligman, in The Transformation of Wall Street 252 (Third Edition),
described the Commissions historical reliance on voluntary plans under Section 11(e) as a means of
achieving compliance with the policies and principles of the Act:
The essence of the Commissions enforcement strategy after 1940 involved creating
incentives (and removing disincentives) so that the utilities themselves would
offer acceptable divestiture and simplification plans. This was known as the
11(e) strategy, since the Holding Company Act authorized enforcement under
Subsection 11(b) under either Subsection 11(d), which empowered the SEC to seek a
federal district court order requiring compliance with a Commission reorganization
plan, or Subsection 11(e), which authorized the SEC to approve and, if necessary,
seek court approval of a reorganization
9
plan offered by a utility. Although the threat of imposing the more draconian
Subsection 11(d) was deemed indispensable to the enforcement of the Act by the
Commission, it was employed only once in the 1940-1952 period.
Id. (footnotes omitted). Accord Hawes, Utility Holding Companies 2-20 (Usually, . . . companies
complied voluntarily by submitting a plan under Section 11(e).). The submission of a Section
11(e) plan does not in any way limit or reduce the Commissions authority. Rather, as explained
below, the Commission must make a Section 11(b) determination in considering whether to approve a
Section 11(e) plan.
The United States Supreme Court, in American Power Co. v. SEC, 329 U.S. 90, 119 (1946), noted
that: Section 11(e) merely permits the holding companies to formulate their own programs for
compliance with § 11(b)(1) or to submit plans in conformity with prior Commission orders under §
11(b), . . . . In this regard, the Divestiture, which has been accepted by the FERC as an
appropriate means of market power mitigation, fits squarely within the stated goals of Section
11(b) by ensuring that a utility system not be so large as to impair . . . the effectiveness of
regulation.
Applicants suggestion that the Commission consider the Section 11(e) Plan on a stand-alone
basis is dictated by the exigencies of the circumstances, namely, that the Act is repealed
effective February 8, 2006. If the Act had not been repealed, Applicants would have asked the
Commission to make the Divestiture findings as part of a comprehensive order approving the Merger.
As noted previously, Applicants believe the Commission could, in fact, issue such an order.
Nonetheless, they recognize that a Section 11(e) plan may be the preferred approach because the
Section 10(f) of the Act concerns that may prevent the Commission from issuing a Merger Order prior
to the effective date of repeal do not apply to the proposed Section 11(e) Plan.
Applicants acknowledge that the proposed Section 11(e) Plan is forward-looking and contingent
on events that may take place, if at all, only after the effective date of repeal They believe,
however, that there are two important points in this regard: (i) Section 1271(c) of the Energy
Policy Act of 2005 expressly contemplates that parties will be able to rely post-repeal on
Commission orders that have been issued prior to the effective date of repeal; and (ii) the
Commission routinely issues forward-looking orders; financing orders, for example, routinely
authorize a wide range of transactions that may or may not occur in the future.
As noted above, Applicants believe the circumstances of this matter a major merger
involving an unprecedented amount of divesture and legislation that offers significant potential
relief in connection with that divestiture warrant Commission action. Applicants are asking the
Commission to issue an order approving the Section 11(e) Divestiture plan before February 8, 2006.
Commission inaction in this matter means that these benefits are irreparably lost.
(a) Necessity for Plan
As noted above, the proposed Divestiture is intended to address market power concerns under
both the Federal Power Act and the 1935 Act and so, to enable the electric utility company
operations of Exelon post-Merger to meet the standards of an integrated electric public-utility
system.
There does not appear to be any serious dispute that, but for repeal, the Commission would
have watchfully deferred to the FERCs findings concerning market power when reviewing the Merger
under the standards of Section 10(b)(1) of the Act. Regardless of whether the Commission
determines to issue a comprehensive Merger Order or instead focus on the Section 11(e) Plan and
reserve jurisdiction over Applicants other requests, there is already a sufficient basis in the
record to enable the Commission to conclude that the proposed Divestiture is necessary for
purposes of mitigating market power concerns that might otherwise be associated with the Merger.
10
Based on the FERCs determinations, the Commission can similarly conclude that the Divestiture
is necessary to ensure that the post-Merger
electric-utility system is not so large as to impair... the effectiveness of regulation. As explained previously, the determination in this regard
requires expertise in operational issues. The Commission has long recognized, and the courts have
agreed, that it is appropriate for the Commission to look to or watchfully defer to the
expertise of the FERC in matters such as these, involving the operation and regulation of
competitive energy markets. See Madison Gas & Electric Co. v. SEC, 168 F.3d 1337, 1341-42 (D.C.
1999) (when the SEC and another regulatory agency both have jurisdiction over a particular
transaction, the SEC may watchfully defer[] to the proceedings held before and the result
reached by that other agency), citing City of Holyoke Gas & Electric Department v. SEC, 972 F.2d
358 (D.C. Cir. 1992). Consistent with its precedent, the Commission therefore can properly rely on
the FERC Merger Order in concluding that the proposed Divestiture is necessary or appropriate to
effectuate the provisions of Section 11(b) of the 1935 Act.
The Commissions ability to rely on the FERCs findings for purposes of anticompetitive
concerns under Section 10(b)(1) is also relevant to its determinations under Section 11(b)(1). The
relationship between the standards of Section 10 and 11 has been summarized in the Commissions
long-standing position that a company cannot acquire what it cannot retain. As the Commission,
in Public Service Company of Oklahoma, Holding Co. Act Release 19090 (July 17, 1975), explained,
the requirements of the two sections are integrally linked and, indeed, the purpose of Section 10
review is to avoid acquisition that would create issues for purposes of Section 11:
Sections 9 and 10 are preventive in purpose. Their essential function is to avoid
recreating, by acquisition, what Section 11(b) was designed to undo or eliminate,
and this statutory link is explicitly recognized in Section 10(c)(1) which
prescribes that we not approve an acquisition that is detrimental to the carrying
out of the provisions of Section 11. These reticulated provisions should be
applied so as to effect their common purpose.
Although Public Service of Oklahoma involved nonutility interests, the principle applies to utility
holdings as well. The Commission, in a 1978 decision, discussed this interplay at length:
The Act . . . focused on the elimination of the perceived abuses and excesses
against which it was directed.
The key provision is Section 11(b) which requires the Commission, with narrow
exceptions, to limit each holding company system to a single integrated
public-utility system as defined in Section 2(a)(29). This provision has been
referred to by the Supreme Court as the heart of the Act, and its implementation
was a principal activity of the Commission during the early years of the Acts
history.
Various other provisions of the Act were designed . . . to prevent a recurrence of
the practices which gave rise to the Act. * * * * * Section 10, in particular was
intended to prevent acquisitions which would be attended by the evils which have
featured the past growth of holding companies.
American Electric Power Company, Inc., Holding Co. Act Release No. 20633 (July 21, 1978) (footnotes
omitted) (the 1978 Decision).
The 1978 Decision highlights the interrelation of the size standards of Sections 10(b)(1)
and 11(b)(1) as means to a common end:
In the 1946 proceeding, AEP had applied for permission to acquire the stock of
CSOE. There our predecessors, in a 2-1 decision, rejected AEPs application on
the basis that it did not satisfy the acquisition standards of the Act. The
majoritys rationale was that the
11
substantially
enlarged group of properties that would result from the acquisition . . . cannot be found to be not so large as to impair. . . the advantages of
localized management and the effectiveness of regulation. The opinion . . .
emphasized that an essential part of the spirit of the Act was the desire to avert
the process of concentration of power which had characterized the growth of
holding companies.
Emphasis added. While the Commission in the 1978 Decision did approve the CSOE acquisition, it did
not abandon its long-standing position that a company cannot acquire what it cannot retain.
Rather, the Commission focused on changed circumstances, including changes in the state of the
art.11 So, too, in this matter, would changes in the state of the art, in
particular, the development of competitive wholesale energy markets under the stewardship of the
FERC represent an important reason why market power as well as geographic expanse is an
important factor in determining whether an electric-utility system is, in fact, so large as to
impair the effectiveness of regulation. In this regard, the Divestiture that is necessary and
appropriate to avert the process of concentration of power for purposes of Section 10(b)(1) is
similarly necessary and appropriate to ensure that the acquisition that is the subject of the
Section 10 review does not result in a system that is so large . . . as to impair the
effectiveness of regulation for purposes of Section 11(b).
The
Commission has declared that [a] plan is necessary within the meaning of section 11(e), . . . if it accomplishes the objectives required by section 11(b) in an appropriate manner.
Midland Utilities, 24 S.E.C. 463, 475 (1946). It thus seems clear that section 11(e) permits a
company to propose particular transactions which under our ordinary practice we would not, or
perhaps could not, specifically require by order under Section 11(b). See also Mission Oil Co.,
35 S.E.C. 540 (1954) (in which the Commission authorized a Section 11(e) plan to enable applicant
to obtain tax relief). As explained in Northeast Utilities, supra, The Commission has
consistently held that a plan under Section 11(e) of the Act may be found necessary if it
provides an appropriate means for achieving results required by Section 11(b) of the Act, although
a different method may have been chosen, or though further action may be required to effectuate
compliance with the standards of section 11(b). Id. (footnotes omitted). The Applicants submit
that the proposed Plan is a suitable means of accomplishing the required objective of assuring that
the resulting system is not so large as to impair the effectiveness of regulation, and thus it
meets the necessity standard of Section 11(e) of the Act.
(b) Fairness
Finally, there is no harm to the protected interests in the requested relief. If, for some
reason, the Merger does not close, the order approving the Section 11(e) Plan will be of no effect.
If, however, as Applicants anticipate, the Merger does close in the first half of 2006, the tax
deferrals will contribute to the financial health of the merged company and so be in the public
interest for purposes of the Act. Similarly, although the 1935 Act does not provide extra
protection for shareholders of registered holding companies, the tax deferrals will clearly be
beneficial to the interest of investors and, by bolstering the financial health of the merged
company, similarly beneficial to the interests of consumers.
|
|
|
11 |
|
. In a footnote in the 1978 Decision,
the Commission explained that:
|
|
|
|
change in the state of the art would serve to distinguish the
1946 Decision even if we were disposed, which we are not, to
apply concepts such as res judicata or stare decisis to the
essentially regulatory and policy determinations called for in a
Holding Company Act case such as this. See Union Electric
Company, Holding Co. Act Release No. 18368 (April 10, 1974), 4 SEC
Docket 89, 100 n. 52, affd sum nom. City of Cape Girardeau
v. SEC, 521 F.2d 324 (C.A.D.C., 1975). |
American Electric Power, supra, n. 26.
12
Item 4. Regulatory Approvals
New Jersey Board of Public Utilities (NJBPU)
As a utility in the State of New Jersey, PSE&G is subject to the jurisdiction of the NJBPU.
Under Section 48:2-51.1 of New Jerseys public utility law, the NJBPUs approval is required in
connection with the indirect transfer of the capital stock of PSE&G resulting from the Merger. In
considering the Merger, the NJBPU is required to evaluate the impact of the Merger in four areas:
competition, the rates of ratepayers affected by the Merger, the employees of the affected public
utility, and the provision of safe and adequate utility service at just and reasonable rates.
On February 4, 2005, Exelon and PSE&G made the initial filing of their joint application with
the NJBPU for approval of the indirect transfer of the capital stock of PSE&G resulting from the
Merger. While New Jersey law does not specify a timetable for completion of the NJBPUs review,
Exelon and PSE&G expect the proceeding to be concluded in the first half of 2006.
In addition, while not required by law to complete the Merger, Exelon and PSEG have made it a
condition to the Merger that PSE&G receive an order from the NJBPU allowing PSE&G to defer certain
pension and other post-retirement benefit expenses that will be recognized in connection with the
purchase accounting treatment of the Merger, and providing that PSE&Gs rate recovery of pension
and other post-retirement benefits will be calculated consistently with recovery of such amounts in
the absence of the Merger.12 On February 4, 2005, Exelon and PSE&G made the initial
filing of their joint application with the NJBPU to obtain the order.13
New Jersey Department of Environmental Protection (NJDEP)
Subsidiaries of PSEG own facilities in New Jersey that are industrial establishments as
defined in ISRA. The parties have already filed their application with NJDEP and have received a
letter of non-applicability under ISRA with respect to the Merger, the Generation Restructuring and
Merger related corporate restructurings during the first quarter of 2005.14
New York Public Service Commission (NYPSC)
As an owner of generation facilities in the State of New York, a subsidiary of PSEG Power is
subject to the jurisdiction of the NYPSC. Under Section 70 of the New York Public Service Law, the
NYPSCs written consent is required in connection with the indirect transfer of ownership interests
in such subsidiary of PSEG Power in connection with the Merger. Under Section 70 of the New York
Public Service Law, the NYPSC must determine whether the Merger is in the public interest. The
parties have already filed their application and have received approval with the
NYPSC.15
Pennsylvania Public Utility Commission (PAPUC)
|
|
|
12 |
|
For a description of this matter, see Risk
FactorsRisks Relating to the MergerThe combined company may be
unable to obtain permission from the NJBPU to recover PSE&Gs pension and other
post-retirement benefit expenses, which could have an adverse effect on its
cash flow and results of operations in the Registration Statement on Form S-4
filed as Exhibit C hereto. |
|
13 |
|
See Exhibit D-2 hereto. |
|
14 |
|
See Exhibit D-5 hereto. |
|
15 |
|
See Exhibit D-6 hereto. |
13
PECO and PSE&G are subject to the jurisdiction of the PAPUC. The issuance to each of PECO and
PSE&G of a certificate of public convenience and necessity by the PAPUC may be required as a result
of the indirect transfer of the capital stock of PSE&G in connection with the Merger under Chapters
11, 22 and 28 of the Public Utility Code of Pennsylvania. The standard for approval is whether the
transaction is necessary and proper for the service, accommodation, convenience or safety of the
public. This standard has been applied by the PAPUC to require that applicants demonstrate that
the transaction will affirmatively promote the service, accommodation, convenience or safety of the
public in some substantial way. In addition, under provisions enacted as part of Pennsylvanias
electric and natural gas restructuring legislation, the PAPUC must consider:
|
|
|
whether a proposed transaction is likely to result in anticompetitive or
discriminatory conduct, including the unlawful exercise of market power, which would
prevent retail electric or natural gas customers in Pennsylvania from obtaining the
benefits of a properly functioning and workable competitive retail electric or natural
gas market; and |
|
|
|
|
the effect of the proposed transaction on the natural gas distribution company
employees and authorized collective bargaining agreement. |
On February 4, 2005, PECO and PSE&G made the initial filing of their joint application for
approval by the PAPUC under the Public Utility Code of Pennsylvania or a determination that
Chapters 11, 22 and 28 are not applicable to the Merger.16
On September 13, 2005, PECO announced that it had filed with the PAPUC a settlement of most
issues raised in Pennsylvanias review of the
Merger.17
If the settlement is
approved, PECO would provide $120 million over four years in rate discounts for customers and cap
its rates through the end of 2010. The settlement also provides substantial funding for
alternative energy and environmental projects, economic development, expanded outreach and
assistance for low-income customers, and various corporate safeguards. The PAPUS administrative
law judge has approved the settlement, and the matter is currently on the PAPUC agenda for January
27, 2006.
Illinois Commerce Commission (ICC) ComEd has filed a notice with respect to the
Merger with the ICC. Formal approval of the Merger by the ICC is not required.18
Connecticut As the owner of generation stations in the State of Connecticut,
PSEG Power Connecticut LLC, an indirect subsidiary of PSEG Power, is subject to the jurisdiction of
the Connecticut Siting Council (CSC) under Connecticut public utility laws and the Connecticut
Department of Environmental Protection (CDEP) under Connecticut environmental law. The indirect
transfer of the ownership interests in these entities may require the approval of the CDEP and will
require the approval of the CSC. The parties filed their application with the CSC on March 3, 2005
and received their approval. The parties intend to file their application for approval with the
CDEP during the first quarter of 2005.19
Nuclear Regulatory Commission (NRC)
PSEG Power holds a NRC operating license for its Salem and Hope Creek nuclear generating
facilities. This license authorizes PSEG Power to own and/or operate its nuclear generating
facilities. The
|
|
|
16 |
|
See Exhibit D-4 hereto. |
|
17 |
|
See Exhibit D-12 hereto. |
|
18 |
|
See Exhibit D-3 hereto. |
|
19 |
|
See Exhibit D-7 hereto. |
14
Atomic Energy Act provides that a license may not be transferred or, in any manner disposed
of, directly or indirectly, through transfer of control of any license unless the NRC finds that
the transfer complies with the Atomic Energy Act and consents to the transfer. Therefore, the
consent of the NRC is required for the transfer of control pursuant to the Merger of the license
held by PSEG Power. The NRC will consent to the transfer if it determines that:
|
|
|
the proposed transferee is qualified to be the holder of the license; and |
|
|
|
|
the transfer of the license is otherwise consistent with applicable provisions of
laws, regulations and orders of the NRC. |
The parties have filed applications with the NRC,20 and currently expect
approval in the first quarter of 2006.
Federal Energy Regulatory Commission
On July 1, 2005, the FERC issued the FERC Merger Order.21 The changed
merger review provision implemented by the Energy Policy Act of 2005 are not applicable to the
Merger. In December of 2005, the FERC issued its order on rehearing, reaffirming approval of the
Transaction, as described in Item 1. Certain parties have filed notices of appeal.
In addition Exelon and PSEG are required by the FERC order to make appropriate filings under
Section 205 of the Federal Power Act to implement the transaction.
Antitrust
Under the provisions of the Hart-Scott-Rodino Antitrust Improvements Act of 1976, as amended,
(the H-S-R Act), the Merger cannot be completed until both Exelon and PSEG file a notification of
the proposed transaction with the Antitrust Division of the United States Department of Justice
(the Antitrust Division) and the Federal Trade Commission (FTC) and the specified waiting
periods have expired or been terminated. The parties have been informed that the Antitrust
Division will review the case and the FTC will not.
The parties received a second request for information from the Antitrust Division and have
certified substantial compliance with such request. The waiting period mandated by the H-S-R Act
expired September 1, 2005. The Antitrust Division review continues notwithstanding such expiration
but the parties do not expect a delay in closing will result.
At any time before the Merger is completed, the Antitrust Division could challenge or seek to
block the Merger under the antitrust laws, as it deems necessary or desirable in the public
interest. Other competition promoting agencies with jurisdiction over the Merger could also
initiate action to challenge or block the Merger. In addition, in some jurisdictions, a
competitor, customer or other third party could initiate a private action under the antitrust laws
challenging or seeking to enjoin the Merger, before or after it is completed. Based upon an
examination of information available relating to the businesses in which the companies are engaged,
Exelon and PSEG believe, with the market concentration mitigation plan they have proposed, that
completion of the Merger will not violate United States or applicable foreign antitrust laws.
The Merger may also be subject to review by the governmental authorities of various other
jurisdictions under the antitrust laws of those jurisdictions.
|
|
|
20 |
|
See Exhibits D-8, D-9 and D-10 hereto. |
|
21 |
|
See Exhibits D-11 hereto. |
15
Federal Communications Commission
The Federal Communications Commission (FCC) must approve the transfer of control of
telecommunications permits or licenses. The Communications Act of 1934 prohibits the transfer,
assignment or disposal in any manner of any license, or any rights thereunder, to any person
without authorization from the FCC. PSEGs subsidiaries hold telecommunications licenses and,
together with the appropriate subsidiaries of Exelon, will seek the necessary approvals from the
FCC for the assignment of or transfer of control over such licenses in connection with the Merger.
Under the Communications Act, the FCC will approve a transfer of control if it serves the public
interest, convenience, and necessity.
Private Letter Ruling of the Internal Revenue Service
Exelon and PSEG have received a ruling from the Internal Revenue Service (IRS) confirming
that no gain or loss will be recognized for United States federal income tax purposes with respect
to the transfer of PSEGs nuclear decommissioning trust funds as a result of the Merger.
Exelon will request that the IRS issue a private letter ruling confirming section 1081 tax
treatment in respect of the Generation Transactions as and to the extent that Exelon will seek to
utilize such tax treatment in respect of the divestiture of a particular generating unit. It is
possible that the IRS may require Exelon to modify aspects of the structure of the Generation
Transactions to obtain the private letter ruling. The Generation Transactions are deemed to
include any such modifications to the extent such modifications allow Exelon to comply with the
order of the Commission on the Applications and is otherwise acceptable to Exelon.
Except as stated above, no state or federal regulatory agency other than the Commission under
the Act has jurisdiction over the proposed Merger.
NJBPU Approval Regarding PSE&G Securities Issuances
The NJBPU has authority under N.J.S.A. 48:3-7, N.J.S.A. 48:3-9 and N.J.S.A. 14:1-5,9 to
approve the issuance of securities by PSE&G. PSE&G, a New Jersey corporation, obtains approval
from the NJBPU for all of its securities issuances, including both long-term and short-term debt
securities. Its existing approvals include authority to issue up to $750 million of short-term
debt through January 2, 2007 (Order of Approval, Docket No. EF04101117 (December 2, 2004)).
Further, PSE&G has authority to issue various long-term debt securities in an amount not to exceed
$525 million through December 31, 2005. (Order of Approval, Docket No. EF03121003 (April 28,
2004)). Accordingly, PSE&G is not seeking any approval from the Commission for the issuance of
exempt securities, but will rely on Rule 52(a).
Item 5. Procedure.
The Applicants request that the Commissions order be issued as soon as the rules allow, and
that there should not be a 30-day waiting period between issuance of the Commissions order and the
date on which the order is to become effective. The Applicants hereby waive a recommended decision
by a hearing officer or any other responsible officer of the Commission and consent that the
Division of Investment Management may assist in the preparation of the Commissions decision and/or
order, unless the Division opposes the matters proposed herein.
Item 6. Exhibits And Financial Statements.
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
A.
|
|
Exhibits. |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
A-1
|
|
Amended and Restated Articles of Incorporation of Exelon (incorporated by |
16
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
reference to Exhibit 3.1 to Exelons Registration Statement on Form S-4, filed May
15, 2000 (File No. 333-37082)) |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
A-2
|
|
Amendment to Amended and Restated Articles of Incorporation of Exelon (incorporated
by reference to Exhibit 3.1 to Exelons Quarterly Report on Form 10-Q for the
quarter ended June 30, 2004, filed July 28, 2004 (File No. 001-16169)) |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
A-3
|
|
Form of Amendment to Amended and Restated Articles of Incorporation of Exelon,
(incorporated by reference to Exhibit 4.1 to Exelons Registration Statement on
Form S-4, filed February 10, 2005 (File No. 333-122074)) |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
B-1
|
|
Agreement and Plan of Merger between Exelon and PSEG, dated as of December 20, 2004
(incorporated by reference to Exhibit 2.1 to Current Report on Form 8-K, filed
December 21, 2004 (File No. 001-16169)) |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
B-2
|
|
Exelon Indenture (incorporated by reference to Exhibit 4.1 to Exelons
Registration Statement on Form S-3, filed March 27, 2001 (File No. 333-57540)) |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
B-3
|
|
Exelon Generation Indenture (incorporated by reference to Exhibit 4.1 to
Exelons Registration Statement on Form S-4, filed April 4, 2002 (File No.
333-85496)) |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
B-4
|
|
Form of PSEG Mutual Services Agreement (to be filed by amendment) |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
B-5
|
|
Description of Exelon Service Providers and existing agreements under State
approved affiliated interest requirements (incorporated by reference to Exhibit
B-3.3 to Exelons Application on Form U-1, filed October 18, 2000 (File No.
70-09645)) |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
C
|
|
Definitive joint proxy statement/prospectus, filed pursuant to rule 424(b)(3) on
June 3, 2005 (File No. 333-122074) (incorporated by reference) |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
D-1
|
|
Joint Application of Exelon and PSEG to the FERC regarding Merger, filed February
4, 2005 (excluding exhibits and testimony, which Applicant will supply upon request
of the Commission.) (to be filed by amendment) |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
D-2
|
|
Joint Petition of Exelon and PSE&G to the NJBPU for Approval of a Change in Control
of PSE&G, and Related Authorizations, filed February 4, 2005 (excluding exhibits
and testimony, which Applicants will supply upon request of the Commission) (to be
filed by amendment) |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
D-3
|
|
ComEds Notice of Holding Company Merger to the ICC, filed February 4, 2005
(excluding exhibits and attachments, which Applicants will supply upon request of
the Commission) (to be filed by amendment) |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
D-4
|
|
Joint Application of PECO and PSE&G to PAPUC for Approval of the Merger of PSEG
with and into Exelon, filed February 4, 2005 (excluding exhibits and testimony,
which Applicants will supply upon request of the Commission) (to be filed by
amendment) |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
D-5
|
|
Joint Application of Exelon and PSEG with NJDEP for Letter of Non-Applicability
under ISRA (to be filed by amendment) |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
D-6
|
|
Joint Application of Exelon and PSEG to NYPSC for Approval of Indirect Transfer of
Ownership Interests (to be filed by amendment) |
17
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
D-7
|
|
Joint Request of PSEG Power Connecticut, LLC and Exelon Corporation to CSC for
Approval of Transfer of Certificate of Environmental Compatibility and Public Need,
filed March 3, 2005 (excluding exhibits and testimony, which Applicants will supply
upon request of the Commission) (to be filed by amendment) |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
D-8
|
|
Application of PSEG Nuclear LLC to NRC for Proposed License Transfer and Conforming
License Amendments Relating to the Merger of PSEG and Exelon (excluding exhibits
and testimony, which Applicants will supply upon request of the Commission) (to be
filed by amendment) |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
D-9
|
|
Application of Exelon Generation to NRC for Approval of License Transfers
(excluding exhibits and testimony, which Applicants will supply upon request of the
Commission) (to be filed by amendment) |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
D-10
|
|
Application of AmerGen to NRC for Approval of Indirect License Transfers (excluding
exhibits and testimony, which Applicants will supply upon request of the
Commission) (to be filed by amendment) |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
D-11
|
|
Order of the Federal Energy Regulatory Commission of July 1, 2005, Order
Authorizing Merger Under Section 203 of the Federal Power Act. |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
D-11.1
|
|
Federal Energy Regulatory Commission Order on Rehearing |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
D-12
|
|
Joint Petition for Settlement (PAPUC) (to be filed by amendment) |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
E-1
|
|
Map of combined transmission systems of Exelon and PSEG (to be filed by amendment) |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
E-2
|
|
Map of combined gas service territory of Exelon and PSEG (to be filed by amendment) |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
F
|
|
Opinions of counsel (to be filed by amendment) |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
G-1
|
|
Diagram of Exelons Post-Merger Corporate Structure (to be filed by amendment) |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
G-2
|
|
Diagram of Existing Corporate Structure of Exelon System (to be filed by
amendment) |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
G-3
|
|
Diagram of Existing Corporate Structure of PSEG System (to be filed by
amendment) |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
G-4
|
|
List of Generation Facilities Subject to Divestiture (to be filed by amendment) |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
G-4-1
|
|
Subject Assets: Divestiture via Sale (previously filed) |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
G-5
|
|
Description of all outstanding indebtedness and obligations of PSEG (to be
filed by amendment) |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
G-6
|
|
Description of all inter-company guaranties in PSEG system (to be filed by
amendment) |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
G-7
|
|
Analysis of Non-Utility Interests of PSEG (previously filed) |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
G-8
|
|
Analysis of the Economic Impact of a Divestiture of the Gas Operations of PECO
Energy Company (incorporated by reference to Exhibit J-1 to Exelons |
18
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Application on
Form U-1, filed March 16, 2000 (File No. 70-09645)) |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
G-9
|
|
Analysis of the Economic Impact of a Divestiture of the Gas Operations of PECO and
PSE&G |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
G-10
|
|
Additional information in connection with proposed Generational Divestiture (previously filed) |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
G-11
|
|
Additional information in connection with proposed Generational Divestiture (previously filed) |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
G-12
|
|
Additional information in connection with proposed Generational Divestiture (previously filed) |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
G-13
|
|
Additional information in connection with proposed Generational Divestiture (previously filed) |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
G-14
|
|
Additional information in connection with proposed Generational Divestiture (previously filed) |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
H
|
|
Proposed Form of Notice (to be filed by amendment) |
B. Financial Statements.
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
FS-1
|
|
Consolidated Balance Sheet of Exelon as of December
31, 2004 (incorporated by reference to Exelons Annual
Report on Form 10-K for the year ended December 31,
2004, filed February 23, 2005 (File No. 1-16169)) |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
FS-2
|
|
Consolidated Statement of Income of Exelon for the
year ended December 31, 2004 (incorporated by reference
to Exelons Annual Report on Form 10-K for the year
ended December 31, 2004, filed February 23, 2005 (File
No. 1-16169)) |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
FS-3
|
|
Consolidated Balance Sheet of PSEG as of December 31,
2004 (incorporated by reference to PSEGs Annual Report
on Form 10-K for the year ended December 31, 2004, filed
February 28, 2005 (File No. 1-09120)) |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
FS-4
|
|
Consolidated Statement of Operations of PSEG for the
year ended December 31, 2004 (incorporated by reference
to PSEGs Annual Report on Form 10-K for the year ended
December 31, 2004, filed February 28, 2005 (File No.
1-09120)) |
Item 7. Information as to Environmental Effects
The proposed transaction involves neither a major federal action nor significantly affects
the quality of the human environment as those terms are used in Section 102(2)(C) of the National
Environmental Policy Act, 42 U.S.C. Sec. 4321 et seq. No federal agency is preparing an
environmental impact statement with respect to this matter.
Item 8. Implementation of Section 1271(c) of the Energy Policy Act of 2005
Repeal of the Act will become effective on the Effective Date. Notwithstanding such
effectiveness, Section 1271(c) of the Energy Policy Act of 2005 provides that tax treatment under
section 1081 of the Code as a result of transactions ordered in compliance with the Act shall not
be affected in any manner due to repeal of the Act or enactment of PUHCA 2005.
In order more fully to secure for the Applicants and their subsidiaries the benefits of tax
treatment under section 1081, the Applicants undertake the following:
(i) notwithstanding the effectiveness of repeal of the Act, from and after the Effective
Date, to comply with the Commissions order to divest control, securities or other assets
and for other
19
action by a company and/or subsidiary company thereof for the purpose of
enabling the company or any subsidiary company thereof to comply with the provisions of
subsections (b) and (e) of Section 11 of the Act (an Implementation Order) as to
each and every condition ordered in the Implementation Order to the extent, but only to the
extent, that such conditions also remain required pursuant to an order of the FERC or an
order of any State or other Federal commission or an order of any State or Federal court;
and
(ii) to submit to the authority of the FERC, from and after the Effective Date, in respect
of such aspects of the Implementation Order that remain in force and effect (including, but
without limitation, full power and authority to amend or change the surviving provisions of
the Implementation Order as the FERC may deem necessary or appropriate in the
circumstances).
The Applicants consent and agree that consummation by them of the Merger shall constitute
their acceptance of the survival of the Implementation Order as contemplated in this Item 8
notwithstanding the effectiveness of the repeal of the Act.
20
SIGNATURES
Pursuant to the requirements of the Public Utility Holding Company Act of 1935, each of the
undersigned companies has duly caused this amended Application/Declaration to be signed on its
behalf by the undersigned thereunto duly authorized.
Date: January 20, 2006
|
|
|
|
|
Public Service Enterprise Group Incorporated |
|
Exelon Corporation |
|
|
|
|
|
Public Service Electric and Gas Company* |
|
Exelon Energy Delivery Company, LLC* |
PSEG Power LLC* |
|
Exelon Business Services Company* |
PSEG Energy Holdings L.L.C.* |
|
Exelon Ventures, LLC* |
PSEG Service Corporation |
|
|
|
10 South Dearborn Street |
80 Park Plaza |
|
|
|
37th Floor |
Newark, New Jersey 07102 |
|
|
|
Chicago, Illinois 60603 |
|
|
PECO Energy Company* |
* Including one or more subsidiaries
|
|
|
|
2301 Market Street |
|
|
|
|
Philadelphia, Pennsylvania 19101 |
|
|
Exelon Generation Company, LLC* |
|
|
|
|
300 Exelon Way |
|
|
|
|
Kennett Square, Pennsylvania 19348 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
* Including one or more subsidiaries |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
By Public Service Enterprise Group
Incorporated |
|
By Exelon Corporation |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
By:
|
|
/s/ R. Edwin Selover
|
|
By:
|
|
/s/ Elizabeth A. Moler |
Name:
|
|
R. Edwin Selover
|
|
Name:
|
|
Elizabeth A. Moler |
Title:
|
|
Senior Vice President and General
|
|
Title:
|
|
Executive Vice President |
|
|
Counsel
|
|
|
|
Government and Environmental Affairs |
|
|
Public Service Enterprise Group
|
|
|
|
and Public Policy |
|
|
Incorporated
|
|
|
|
Exelon Corporation |
|
|
80 Park Plaza
|
|
|
|
101 Constitution Avenue, NW |
|
|
Newark, New Jersey 07102
|
|
|
|
Suite 400 East |
|
|
|
|
|
|
Washington, DC 20001 |
|
|
|
|
|
Commonwealth Edison Company* |
|
|
10 South Dearborn Street |
|
|
|
|
37th Floor |
|
|
Chicago, Illinois 60603 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
By Commonwealth Edison Company |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
By:
|
|
/s/ J. Barry Mitchell |
|
|
|
|
Name:
|
|
J. Barry Mitchell |
|
|
|
|
Title:
|
|
President |
|
|
|
|
|
|
One Financial Place |
|
|
|
|
|
|
440 South LaSalle |
|
|
|
|
|
|
Suite 3300 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
Chicago, Illinois 60605 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
21
exv99wd11
EXHIBIT D-11
112 FERC ¶ 61,011
UNITED STATES OF AMERICA
FEDERAL ENERGY REGULATORY COMMISSION
|
|
|
Before Commissioners:
|
|
Pat Wood, III, Chairman; |
|
|
Nora Mead Brownell, Joseph T. Kelliher, |
|
|
and Suedeen G. Kelly. |
|
|
|
Exelon Corporation
|
|
Docket No. EC05-43-000 |
Public Service Enterprise Corporation, Inc. |
|
|
ORDER AUTHORIZING MERGER UNDER SECTION 203 OF THE FEDERAL POWER ACT
(Issued July 1, 2005)
1. In this order, the Commission authorizes the merger of Exelon Corporation (Exelon) and Public
Service Enterprise Group Incorporated (PSEG Holdings) (collectively, Applicants) to form Exelon
Electric & Gas Corporation (EE&G). This order benefits customers because it ensures that the
transaction, which includes mitigation of market effects through very substantial divestiture of
generation, is consistent with the public interest, as required by section 203 of the Federal Power
Act1 (FPA).
Background
A. The Parties
2. Exelon is a registered holding company, under the Public Utility Holding Company Act of 1935
(PUHCA)2 that distributes electricity to approximately 5.1 million customers in Illinois
and Pennsylvania through its subsidiaries, mainly Commonwealth Edison (ComEd) and PECO Energy
(PECO). Through ComEd and PECO, it is the Provider of Last Resort (POLR) for customers who do not
or cannot exercise retail choice for their electricity needs in Illinois and Pennsylvania,
respectively. Exelon is also involved in gas distribution through PECO. The PECO gas facilities
are local
distribution facilities that are not interstate facilities and, therefore, are not subject to the
|
|
|
1 |
|
16 U.S.C. § 824(b) (2000). |
|
2 |
|
15 U.S.C § 79 (2000). |
Commissions jurisdiction under the Natural Gas Act.3 Exelon Generation Company, LLC
(Exelon Generation) conducts Exelons generation business. Exelon Generation owns or controls
generation assets throughout the country with a net capacity of approximately 33,000 MWs, including
ownership interests in 11 nuclear generating stations.
3. PSEG Holdings is an exempt public utility holding company, under PUHCA, with four major
subsidiaries, including Public Service Electric and Gas Company (PSE&G), which is a public utility
company engaged in the transmission and distribution of electric energy and gas service to
approximately 3.6 million customers, primarily in New Jersey. PSEG Holdings subsidiaries also
include PSEG Power LLC, the parent company of most of PSEGs United States power production
business, PSEG Services Corporation, and PSEG Energy Holdings LLC, the parent company of PSEGs
other businesses.
4. Both Exelon and PSEG Holdings have transferred control of their transmission systems to the PJM
Interconnection, LLC (PJM), a Commission approved Regional Transmission Organization (RTO). Both
entities sell power under market-based rate authority.4
B. The Proposed Transaction
5. On February 4, 2005,5 Exelon and PSEG Holdings filed, under section 203 of the FPA
and Part 33 of the Commissions Regulations,6 an application for Commission approval of
a transaction that includes: (1) Exelons acquisition of PSEG Holdings and the resulting indirect
merger of Exelons and PSEG Holdings jurisdictional facilities; and (2) the internal restructuring
and consolidation of Exelons and PSEG Holdings subsidiaries to establish an efficient corporate
structure for EE&G.
6. PSEG Holdings would no longer have a separate corporate existence and would merge into Exelon,
forming EE&G. PSEG Holdings shareholders would each receive 1.225 shares of Exelon common stock for each PSEG Holdings share held and cash in
|
|
|
3 |
|
Application at 7. |
|
4 |
|
Exelon Generation Company, LLC, 93 FERC
¶ 61,140 (2000); PSEG Energy Resources & Trade, LLC, Unpublished Letter
Order in Docket Nos. ER99-3151-002 and ER97-837-003 (June 16, 2003). |
|
5 |
|
Applicants submitted an errata to their
application on February 9, 2005. |
|
6 |
|
18 C.F.R. § 33 (2004). |
lieu of any
fraction of an Exelon share that a PSEG shareholder would have otherwise been entitled to receive.
EE&G will remain the ultimate corporate parent of PECO and ComEd and other Exelon subsidiaries and
will become the corporate parent of PSE&G and all other PSEG subsidiaries. EE&G will assume all of
PSEG Holdings outstanding indebtedness.
7. EE&G will be a registered public utility holding company under PUHCA. ComEd, PECO and PSE&G
will continue to operate franchised public utility companies.
8. In addition to merging jurisdictional assets, Applicants intend to revise their corporate
structure. They plan to make PSE&G a direct subsidiary of Exelon Energy Delivery Company LLC and
keep the subsidiaries of PSE&G intact. PSEG Energy Holdings LLC will become a direct subsidiary of
EE&G and the subsidiaries of PSEG Holdings LLC will remain intact. The PSEG Services Corporation
will sell all of its assets to Exelon Business Services Company, making Exelon Business Services
Company the sole service company of EE&G. PSEG Power and its direct subsidiaries, PSEG Nuclear,
PSEG Fossil and PSEG Energy Resources and Trade, would all become part of Exelon Generation, and
their business functions would become part of their respective Exelon Generation business units.
The subsidiaries owned by PSEG Power, PSEG Nuclear, PSEG Fossil and PSEG Energy Resources and
Trade, will either be merged into Exelon Generation or kept as direct subsidiaries of Exelon
Generation. The reorganization will not result in merchant affiliates that have market-based rate
authority being moved back into the regulated companies of EE&G.
9. Applicants state that the proposed merger will benefit the public interest by providing an
increased scale and scope of both energy delivery and generation, improved service and reliability,
and a more balanced generation portfolio to serve over seven million electric customers and two
million gas customers. Applicants further state that the proposed merger will lead to improved
stability, higher capacity utilization rates and lower costs from combining the nuclear operations
under Exelons experienced management.
C. Standard of Review under Section 203
10. Section 203(a) provides that the Commission must approve a merger if it finds that the
consolidation will be consistent with the public interest.7 The Commissions
analysis under the Merger Policy Statement of whether a consolidation is consistent with the public
interest generally involves consideration of three factors: (1) the effect on
competition; (2) the effect on rates; and (3) the effect on regulation.8 As discussed
below, we will approve the proposed merger as consistent with the public interest and find that it
will not adversely affect competition, rates, or regulation.
1. Effect on Competition
a. Applicants Analysis of Horizontal Competitive Issues
11. Exelon retained Dr. William Hieronymus and PSEG Holdings retained Mr. Rodney Frame to analyze
the effect of the merger on competition. Both witnesses identify three relevant products:
non-firm energy, capacity, and ancillary services, across the geographic markets affected by the
merger. Both witnesses conclude that, as mitigated, the merger will not harm competition.
i. Energy Markets
12. Dr. Hieronymus identifies four relevant geographic markets using the approach described by
Appendix A of the Merger Policy Statement: Expanded PJM, PJM Pre-2004, PJM East, and Northern
PSEG.9 In his analysis of non-firm energy markets, Dr. Hieronymus uses economic
capacity and Available Economic Capacity, as defined in the Merger Policy Statement, as proxies to
represent a suppliers ability to participate in the
|
|
|
8 |
|
Inquiry Concerning the
Commissions Merger Policy Under the Federal Power Act: Policy
Statement, Order No. 592, 61 Fed. Reg. 68,595 (1996), FERC Stats. & Regs.,
Regulations Preambles July 1996-December 2000 ¶ 31,044 (1996),
reconsideration denied, Order No. 592-A, 62 Fed. Reg. 33,341 (1997), 79 FERC
¶ 61,321 (1997) (Merger Policy Statement); see also Revised Filing
Requirements Under Part 33 of the Commissions Regulations, Order No.
642, 65 Fed. Reg. 70,984 (2000), FERC Stats. & Regs., Regulations Preambles
July 1996-December 2000 ¶ 31,111 (2000), order on rehg, Order No.
642-A, 66 Fed. Reg. 16,121 (2001), 94 FERC ¶ 61,289 (2001) (Merger
Filings Requirements Rule). |
|
9 |
|
Expanded PJM is all of PJM including
American Electric Power Service Corporation (AEP), Dayton Power and Light, and
ComEd; PJM Pre-2004 is the portion of PJM consisting of the original PJM
members in MAAC plus Allegheny Energy Supply Company, LLC (Allegheny); PJM-East
is that part of PJM east of the Eastern Interface within PJM; and Northern PSEG
is the portion of the PSE&G service territory in northeastern New Jersey.
However, Dr. Hieronymus does not place Northern PSEG on par with the other
three relevant markets. |
market.10 He uses the Delivered Price Test to evaluate the effect on competition in
the relevant markets over 10 separate time periods: Super Peak, Peak and Off-Peak periods for
Summer, Winter and Shoulder seasons, along with an extreme Summer Super Peak. Dr. Hieronymus uses
a range of prices from $20 per megawatt hour (MWh) in the Shoulder Off-Peak to $250 per MWh in the
extreme Summer Super Peak. He considers actual prices in the PJM markets during 2004, fuel prices
in 2004, and forecast fuel prices for 2006, the test year for his analysis.11
13. In his analysis, Dr. Hieronymus presumes simultaneous import limits for imports into each
geographic market based on a study conducted by PSE&Gs transmission engineering group. The
simultaneous import limits in his analysis are 7,300 MW for PJM-East; 4,600 MW for PJM Pre-2004;
and 7,500 MW for Expanded PJM. Dr. Hieronymus allocates scarce transmission availability on a pro
rata basis.
14. Dr. Hieronymus states that Exelon has several long-term contracts that are relevant to the
analysis. Exelon has long-term contracts to purchase the output of two coal-fired generating
plants and approximately 3,600 MW of supply from peaking facilities, all in the ComEd service
territory. Dr. Hieronymus assigns control of that capacity to Exelon. Exelon sells 400 MW of the
output of the Clinton nuclear unit under a long-term contract, and Dr. Hieronymus assigns control
of that capacity to the buyer. He states that PSE&G has sold a substantial amount of energy and
capacity in the New Jersey Basic Generation Service auction. He assigns control of that capacity
to PSE&G. He does, however, consider those commitments as part of PSE&Gs native load deduction in
his analysis of Available Economic Capacity.
15. Without mitigation, Dr. Hieronymus reports failures of the Competitive Analysis
Screen12 for economic capacity in all season/load conditions in PJM East, PJM Pre-2004,
and Expanded PJM. For PJM-East, the screen failures are most severe, with post-merger market
concentrations ranging from 2,057 to 2,492 on the Herfindahl-Hirschman Index (HHI) (indicating a
highly concentrated market) and merger-related changes in HHI ranging from 848 to 1,067 HHI, all
well above the 50 HHI screening threshold for highly
|
|
|
10 |
|
Each suppliers economic
capacity is the amount of capacity that could compete in the relevant
market given market prices, running costs, and transmission availability.
Available Economic Capacity is based on the same factors but
subtracts the suppliers native load obligation from its capacity and
adjusts transmission availability accordingly. |
|
11 |
|
Hieronymus Testimony, Exhibit J-1, at
37. |
|
12 |
|
Merger Policy Statement, Appendix A at
30,128 (Competitive Analysis Screen). |
concentrated markets. As stated in the Merger Policy Statement, for moderately concentrated
markets (1000 = HHI < 1800), the screening threshold for the change in HHI is 100. For the PJM
Pre-2004 and Expanded PJM markets, the post-merger HHIs indicate moderately concentrated markets,
with merger-related increases in HHI ranging from 172 to 668 HHI, all above the 100 HHI screening
threshold for moderately concentrated markets.
16. For the other markets that could be affected by the merger, Northern PSEG, Electric Reliability
Counsel of Texas (ERCOT) and ISO New England, Inc. (ISO-NE), Dr. Hieronymus does not perform a
complete competitive screen analysis, but explains why he thinks such an analysis is not necessary
and why the merger will not harm competition in those markets.
17. For Northern PSEG, Dr. Hieronymus argues that because Exelon does not own any generation in
that market, the merger will not harm competition. He states that when there are not binding
transmission constraints for imports into Northern PSEG, the geographic boundaries of the market
are at least as broad as PJM-East, and he states that Applicants proposed mitigation will offset
any increase in market concentration in that market.13 He argues that when there are
import constraints for Northern PSEG, it should be considered a separate market from PJM East.
However, in that case, the merger will not increase the amount of capacity controlled by the merged
firm or its incentive to withhold generation to raise prices, because Exelon does not own any
capacity in Northern New Jersey, so there is no overlap between the Exelon and PSE&Gs generation
capacity in that market. Despite his argument, Dr. Hieronymus does analyze Northern PSEG and shows
screen failures due to some of Exelons capacity being included in the pro rata allocation of
transmission availability. His analysis shows post-merger concentrations ranging from 2,750 to
7,288 HHI, with merger-related increases in concentration ranging from 99 to 204 HHI. He finds
that divesting 100 MW of generating capacity in Northern PSEG would return market concentration
levels to approximately the pre-merger levels, with the concentration increasing by less than 50
HHI for some load levels and falling in others. He states that if the Commission decides it is
necessary to mitigate the screen failures, Applicants would divest sufficient generation in the
Northern PSEG market as part of their overall divestiture plan.
18. Dr. Hieronymus argues that there is little overlap between Exelon and PSE&Gs generation assets
in the ERCOT market. He states that Exelon owns or controls 3,651 MW of generation capacity,
mostly in the North zone of ERCOT, while PSE&G owns 2,026 MW of affiliated generation capacity in
the West and South zones. He argues that because Applicants capacity is in different zones within
ERCOT, the only market that
|
|
|
13 |
|
Northern PSEG is a subset of PJM-East. |
could be affected by the merger is ERCOT as a whole. He states that Exelon and PSE&Gs capacity in
ERCOT is less than five percent and 2.5 percent respectively, so the merger-related change in HHI
would only be approximately 20 HHI, well under Commissions screening threshold.14
19. For the ISO-NE market, Dr. Hieronymus also argues that, because Exelons and PSE&Gs generation
is in different constrained regions, the smallest relevant market in which both Applicants
generation would compete would be ISO-NE as a whole. He concludes that because Exelon and PSE&G
control only two and three percent of the generation capacity in ISO-NE, combining such small
market shares would not harm competition.15
20. PSE&Gs witness, Mr. Frame, also analyzes non-firm energy markets, using economic capacity and
Available Economic Capacity to represent a suppliers ability to participate in the market. Mr.
Frame analyzes three geographic markets using the approach described by Appendix A of the Merger
Policy Statement: Expanded PJM, PJM Pre-2004, PJM East. He uses the Delivered Price Test to
analyze the effect of the merger on market concentration. Like Dr. Hieronymus, Mr. Frame uses ten
season/load conditions. He uses a range of prices from $30 to $150 per MWh based on prevailing
market-clearing prices in PJM over the last two years for the relevant season/load conditions. He
allocates scarce transmission availability on a pro rata basis and imposes simultaneous imports
limitations in his analysis. Mr. Frame states that he follows the Commissions procedures by
assigning control of generation under contract to the party that has operational control of the
facility.
21. Mr. Frames results are consistent with those of Dr. Hieronymus. He reports screen failures in
PJM-East and Pre-2004 PJM for all season/load conditions, and in Expanded PJM for most season/load
conditions. For PJM-East, he reports post-merger
|
|
|
14 |
|
Dr. Hieronymus refers to the
2ab change in HHI, which is derived from the difference between
adding the squares of the pre-merger market shares of the two firms
(a2 + b2), and squaring the combined firms
post-merger market share ((a+b)2 = (a2 + b2 +
2ab)). The term is commonly used in analyses of changes in market structure. |
|
15 |
|
Dr. Hieronymus cites the Commissions
finding in USGen New England, Inc., 109 FERC ¶ 61,341 (2004), where the
Commission approved the purchase of approximately 7 percent of the capacity in
ISO-NE by a company that already controlled approximately 6 percent of the
capacity in ISO-NE. A 2ab analysis of combining Exelons
and PSEGs capacity in ISO-NE would lead to an increase of approximately
12 HHI, well below the screening thresholds of 50 HHI for highly concentrated
markets and 100 HHI for moderately concentrated markets. |
concentrations ranging from 1,688 to 2,816 HHI, with merger-related changes in HHI ranging from 695
to 1,252 HHI, all well above the Commissions screening thresholds. For Pre-2004 PJM, he reports
post-merger concentrations ranging from 1,133 to 1,509 HHI, with merger-related changes in HHI
ranging from 336 to 443 HHI, all well above the Commissions screening thresholds. For Expanded
PJM, he reports post-merger concentrations ranging from 919 to 1,197 HHI, with merger related
changes in HHI ranging from 178 to 236 HHI, with six of the ten season/load conditions above the
Commissions screening thresholds.
22. Dr. Hieronymus also performs a Competitive Analysis Screen for Available Economic Capacity in
Expanded PJM, PJM Pre-2004, PJM East, and Northern PSEG. However, he argues that Available
Economic Capacity is not an accurate measure in PJM because utilities have been largely released
from their native load obligations in states with retail choice programs; or serve as providers of
last resort through power purchase agreements, or, in the case of New Jersey, through the Basic
Generation Service auction. He reports screen failures in eight of the 10 season/load conditions
in PJM East,16 all season/load conditions in PJM Pre-2004, and none of the season/load
levels for Expanded PJM.
23. Mr. Frame also performs a Competitive Analysis Screen for Available Economic Capacity in
Expanded PJM, PJM Pre-2004, and PJM East. He states that Available Economic Capacity is difficult
to measure in PJM because native load obligations have changed in states with retail choice
programs, standard offer services and Basic Generation Service auctions. He states that the
purpose of his Available Economic Capacity analysis is to show that the mitigation offered to
address the screen failures in the Economic Capacity analysis will mitigate any Available Economic
Capacity screen violation. He states that he uses conservative assumptions for his Available
Economic Capacity analysis and reports screen failures for most season/load conditions for those
markets, all of which are eliminated by the mitigation.
24. Like Dr. Hieronymus, Mr. Frame argues that it is not necessary to analyze the effect of the
merger on competition in the Northern New Jersey market because Exelon does not own any generation
in that market. He does, however, analyze Northern New Jersey by starting with his analysis of the
PJM East market, removing suppliers located in
|
|
|
16 |
|
Under the scenario where only the PECO and
PSE&G loads are taken into account, there are no screen failures. However,
when all PJM Pre-2004 loads are considered, there are screen failures in all
seasons. According to Dr. Hieronymus, this assumption is not critical to the
outcome of his analysis because the mitigation for the screen failures in
economic capacity more than offsets the increases in concentration in Available
Economic Capacity under either assumption. |
Northern New Jersey, and then allocating the import capability into Northern New Jersey among the
PJM East suppliers.17 He states that based on his analysis, divesting approximately 100
MW of generation capacity, including at least 80 MW of coal-fired capacity within Northern New
Jersey, would eliminate any screen violations in the Northern New Jersey Market.
ii. Mitigation for identified screen failures
25. Applicants propose mitigation to address the harm to competition indicated by the screen
failures. First, they propose divesting 2,900 MW of generation capacity in PJM-East in order to
eliminate the peak and super-peak screen failures described above. The 2,900 MW would consist of
1,000 MW of peaking generation and 1,900 MW of mid-merit generation, of which at least 550 MW would
be coal-fired capacity. They state that no more than half of the 2,900 MW would be sold to a
single buyer and that no capacity would be sold to a market participant with a greater than five
percent market share in PJM-East or Expanded PJM (original Buyer Restrictions).18
Applicants note that they have not yet identified the specific generation units that they intend to
divest. They do, however, list those generating units that will be considered for
divestiture.19 Applicants also state they will make a compliance filing showing the
effect on market concentration given the actual divestitures.
26. Applicants originally committed to complete the divestiture within 18 months after the date of
merger consummation, but later committed to complete the divestiture within 12 months.20
They recognize that the Commission requires that interim mitigation for any merger-related harm to
competition be in place at the time of merger consummation. Accordingly, they propose that within
30 days following the end of the month in which the merger closes, they will sell the rights to
2,900 MW of energy and capacity from
|
|
|
17 |
|
Frame Testimony at 39-40. |
|
18 |
|
Applicants original commitment was
designed to ensure that the divestiture will reduce market concentration enough
to eliminate the harm to competition indicated by the screen failures. If, for
example, the capacity were sold to an existing market participant with a large
market share, or if all of the capacity were sold to a single buyer, the
divestiture would not restore market concentration to a level close to the
pre-merger concentration. Applicants subsequently revised their mitigation
proposal, eliminating most of the Buyer Restrictions. |
|
19 |
|
Application, Exhibit J-12. |
|
20 |
|
Answer at 47. |
|
|
|
Docket No. EC05-43-000
|
|
10 |
designated coal, mid-merit and peaking facilities in PJMEast. 21 As with the permanent
mitigation, they state that no more than half of the 2,900 MW would be sold to a single buyer and
that no capacity would be sold to a market participant with a greater than five percent market
share in PJM-East of Expanded PJM. The interim contracts will have a minimum term of one month and
will be in effect for no longer than 18 months after merger consummation. Applicants explain that
the purchasers of the interim capacity and energy will acquire all of the Unforced Capacity
associated with the units, and full dispatch unit and offering rights, including the right to call
for market-based ancillary services, thus enabling the purchaser to offer the units into the PJM
capacity, energy and ancillary services markets.22
27. Applicants propose a virtual divestiture to address the Appendix A screen failures for the
off-peak periods. They will sell long-term energy rights from nuclear baseload units.23
They state that the virtual divestiture will remove any merger-related increase in Applicants
ability or incentive to withhold baseload energy in order to exercise market power. Applicants
propose virtually divesting 2,250 MW of energy from nuclear units located in PJM-East in order to
address the screen failures in that market.24 They note that Dr. Hieronymus analysis
shows that an additional divestiture of 200 MW of capacity in the larger Pre-2004 PJM market is
also required and, accordingly, they will virtually divest another 200 MW of baseload nuclear
energy in the larger, Pre-2004 PJM market.
28. Applicants state that the virtual divestiture will take one of two forms: (1) a firm sales
contract expiring no earlier than 15 years after the date of the merger consummation (Long-Term
Contract Option); or (2) an annual auction of 3-year entitlements to baseload energy, in 25 MW
blocks. Applicants state that the auction process will be administered
|
|
|
21 |
|
Application at 34. |
|
22 |
|
Cassidy testimony at 6. |
|
23 |
|
The energy sales are not meant to
address the identified screen failures in the capacity markets; rather, they
target the off-peak energy screen failures described above. Applicants have
provided a separate mitigation plan for capacity markets, which is described
later in this order. |
|
24 |
|
Exelons witness, Dr. Hieronymus,
identified the need to divest 2,400 MW of baseload capacity in order to restore
competition in PJM-East. Applicants argue that virtually
divesting 2,250 MW on a 100 percent load factor basis is the energy
equivalent of selling 2,400 MW of capacity operating at Exelons
historical capacity factor of 93 percent. Application at 24. |
|
|
|
Docket No. EC05-43-000
|
|
11 |
by an independent auction manager in order to ensure a transparent and objective auction
process.25 The sum of the baseload energy entitlements sold under the two options will
be 2,450 MW (Baseload Mitigation Amount), unless, as described below, the Baseload Mitigation
Amount needed to mitigate harm is reduced by other structural mitigation measures. In addition, no
single purchaser will be allowed to purchase more than 50 percent of the Baseload Mitigation
Amount.
29. Applicants state that under the Long-Term Contract Option, they will sell entitlements to PJM
East baseload nuclear energy for terms of at least 15 years in return for cash or similar rights to
energy taken for delivery outside of PJM (Energy Swap). Applicants originally committed to the
divestiture restrictions regarding the potential purchasers under the Long-Term Contract Option,
and, additionally, committed that they will not sell more that 25 percent of the Baseload
Mitigation Amount to market participants owning three to five percent of the installed generation
capacity in Expanded PJM or PJM East.26
30. Applicants state that, under the auction option, the auctions will be held to coincide with the
New Jersey Basic Generation Service auctions. The product to be auctioned will be a three-year
obligation to take 25 MW of 7 x 24 energy. In the first year, the auction will be phased in by
selling one third of the capacity for a one-year term, one third of the capacity for a two-year
term, and one third of the capacity for a three-year term. In subsequent years, one third of the
capacity will be sold for a three-year term.27
|
|
|
25 |
|
Cassidy Testimony at14. |
|
26 |
|
Applicants argue that this additional condition is to ensure
that the virtual divesture will sufficiently mitigate the harm to competition
indicated by the off-peak screen failures. |
|
27 |
|
As constructed, the Auction Amount will be under contract at
all times. For example, assuming the Auction Amount were 1,500 MW in the first
year (in that case 2,250 MW minus 750 MW under the Long-Term Contract Option),
500 MW would be under one-year contracts, 500 MWs would be under the first year
of two-year contracts, and 500 MWs would be under the first year of three-year
contracts. In the second year, 500 MWs would be under the second year of
two-year contracts, 500 MW would be under the second year of three-year
contracts, and the 500 MWs that expired under the initial one-year contracts
would be in the first year of new, three-year contracts. So each year, one
third of the existing contracts expire and are replaced by new three-year
contracts. |
|
|
|
Docket No. EC05-43-000
|
|
12 |
31. Dr. Hieronymus analyzes the effect of the merger, given Applicants proposed mitigation, and
finds that the merger would not harm competition. For PJM-East, the merger-related changes in
concentration range from falling by 101 HHI in the Winter Peak period to rising by 63 HHI in the
Winter Super Peak period. The post-merger and mitigation markets are moderately concentrated for
all season/load conditions, with the change in market concentration falling within the Commissions
tolerance for all periods. For PJM Pre-2004 and PJM Expanded, with mitigation, the markets are
moderately concentrated in 14 of the 20 total season/load conditions and unconcentrated in the
other 6 season/load conditions. With exception of one season/load condition in each market, all of
the changes in concentration are within the Commissions tolerances. Dr. Hieronymus concludes that
Applicants proposed mitigation eliminates any harm to competition indicated by the screen failures
in his analysis of economic capacity. In addition, the proposed mitigation would reduce market
concentration below the pre-merger level in the three PJM markets in all season/load conditions for
Available Economic Capacity. Therefore, he also concludes that the proposed mitigation eliminates
any harm to competition indicated by the screen failures in his analysis of Available Economic
Capacity.
32. Mr. Frame also finds that the proposed mitigation would eliminate the harm to competition in
energy markets indicated by the screen failures in economic and Available Economic Capacity. Mr.
Frame finds that the proposed mitigation would reduce market concentration below the pre-merger
level in the three PJM markets in virtually all season/load condition for Available Economic
Capacity. For economic capacity, he finds that the post-merger and mitigation markets will be
moderately concentrated for 15 of the 30 season/load condition in the three PJM market scenarios
and unconcentrated for the other 15 season/load conditions, with all changes in HHI falling within
the Commissions tolerance levels.
Notice of Filing and Pleadings
33. Notice of Applicants filing was published in the Federal Register,28 with
interventions and protests due on or before April 11, 2005. Numerous parties filed motions to
intervene.29 The Pennsylvania Public Utility Commission, the New Jersey
|
|
|
28 |
|
70 Fed. Reg. 8,355 (2005). |
|
29 |
|
NRG Power Marketing, Inc., Arthur Kill
Power, LLC, Astoria Gas Turbine Power, LLC, Vienna Power, LLC, and Indian River
Power LLC (collectively NRG Companies); Dynegy Power Corp. (Dynegy);
Consolidated Edison Company of New York (ConEd NY); Reliant Energy, Inc.
(Reliant); Amerada Hess Corporation (Hess); New Athens Generating Company (New
Athens); Strategic Energy, LLC (Strategic); LS |
(continued...)
|
|
|
Docket No. EC05-43-000
|
|
13 |
Board of Public Utilities and the Illinois Commerce Commission filed notices of intervention.
Additionally, several parties filed motions to intervene and protests and some parties file motions
to intervene and comments30. Allegheny Electric Cooperative,
Power Associates, LP (LS Power);
Constellation Energy Commodities Group, Inc. (CCG), together with Constellation
Generation Group, LLC (CGG), and Constellation NewEnergy, Inc. (CNE)
(collectively, Constellation); American Electric Power Service Corporation
(AEP); Wisconsin Electric Power Company (Wisconsin Electric); East Coast Power
LLC (ECP); New Jersey Large Energy Users Coalition (NJLUPC); Mid-Atlantic Power
Supply Association (MAPSA); UGI Development Company (UGID); and TXU Portfolio
Management Company (d/b/a TXU Wholesale Markets) (TXU).
|
|
|
30 |
|
Protests and motions to intervene were
received by Ameren Services Company, who later filed a motion to withdraw their
protests but not their motion to intervene; the Maryland Office of the
Peoples Counsel (Office of the Peoples Counsel); New Jersey
Division of the Ratepayer Advocate (Division of the Ratepayer Advocate);
National Railroad Passenger Corporation (Amtrak); PJM Industrial Consumers
Coalition (Coalition) and Philadelphia Area Industrial Energy Users Group
(Energy Users Group); Hoosier Energy Rural Electric Cooperative, Inc.
(Hoosier); Direct Energy Services (Direct Energy); Dominion Energy, Inc.
(Dominion); City of Dowagiac, Michigan (Dowagiac); Environmental Law and Policy
Center; Pennsylvania Office of the Consumer Advocate (POCA); American Public
Power Association (APPA) and the National Rural Electric Cooperative
Association (NRECA); Midwest Generation, LLC (Midwest Generation); Citizen
Power, with the Energy Justice Network, the Illinois Public Interest Research
Group, New Jersey Citizen Action, the New Jersey Public Interest Research
Group, the Pennsylvania Public Interest Research Group, Public Citizens
Energy Program, and Three Mile Island Alert (collectively, Citizen Power
et al.); FirstEnergy Service Company, with Pennsylvania Electric Company,
Metropolitan Edison Company; Jersey Central Power & Light Company, and
FirstEnergy Solutions Corporation (collectively, FirstEnergy); Pepco Holdings
Inc., with Potomac Electric Power Company, Delmarva Power & Light Company,
Atlantic City Electric Company, Conectiv Energy Supply, Inc., and Pepco Energy
Services, Inc. (collectively, PHI Companies), who later filed a Notice of
Conditional Support; PPL Electric Utilities Corporation, with PPL Energy Plus,
LLC, PPL Brunner Island, LLC, PPL Holtwood, LLC, PPL Martins Creek, LLC, PPL
Montour, LLC, PPL Susquehanna, LLC, and Lower Mount Bethel Energy, LLC
(collectively, PPL Companies); the Office of the Attorney General for the State
of Illinois; NiSource Inc. (NiSource); Philadelphia Gas Works and |
(continued...)
|
|
|
Docket No. EC05-43-000
|
|
14 |
Inc. (Allegheny Electric), Indiana Utility Regulatory Commission, and H-P Energy Resources LLC each
filed motions to intervene out-of-time.
34. Three individuals31 filed comments in this proceeding expressing concerns about the
proposed merger and the effect it would have on individual consumers and the future energy markets.
We find that the issues raised by the individual commentors are outside the scope of this
proceeding.
A. Protests
35. Protestors state claims of factual errors in Applicants analyses: (1) Hoosier contends that
Dr. Hieronymus understated the amount of generation controlled by Applicants when developing the
Competitive Analysis Screen because he failed to include a 200 MW power purchase agreement between
PECO and Hoosier in 2006; (2) the PHI Companies state that Conectiv Energy Services, Inc. only
controls 2,595 MW of generating capacity in PJM East rather than the 4,800 MW used in Applicants
analyses; (3) the analyses should have included the PPL Companies recently-completed 600 MW Lower
Mount Bethel combined cycle facility; and (4) the analyses failed to account for Dominions native
load obligation in the calculation of Available Economic Capacity. Some protestors, including the
PHI Companies, argue that given the material issues of fact raised by inaccuracies in Applicants
analysis, a hearing is necessary.
36. A number of protestors argue that Applicants have not analyzed all of the geographic markets
that will be affected by the merger. The POCA argues that Dr. Hieronymus and Mr. Frame
understated the extent of market concentration resulting from the proposed merger and that it is
unclear whether Applicants analyzed all relevant load pockets and geographic markets, especially
the Northern New Jersey load pocket.
37. Protestors argue that Dr. Hieronymus failed to analyze the mergers effect on markets in PJM
other than PJM- East, PJM Pre-2004, and PJM-Expanded.
the City of Philadelphia (collectively, City of Philadelphia); and H-P
Energy Resources, LLC (H-P Energy). Comments were filed by the American
Antitrust Institute (AAI); Williams Power Company (Williams); and the New
Jersey Board of Public Utilities (NJBPU).
|
|
|
31 |
|
William E. Cleary and Kevin B. Carr filed
comments in this docket. We also received an unsigned filing that ends with
the term the insider. |
|
|
|
Docket No. EC05-43-000
|
|
15 |
38. Environmental Law and Policy Center is concerned about the effects that the proposed merger
would have on market power in the Midwest ISO markets and its effect on the interconnection between
the Midwest ISO and the PJM markets.
39. FirstEnergy, through its expert, Ms. Julia Frayer, argues that Applicants Appendix A analysis
underestimates the Applicants combined post-merger market power, understates the ` levels in the
relevant PJM markets and leads to Applicants proposal of inadequate mitigation. Ms. Frayer
specifically questions Dr. Hieronymus fuel price and market price assumptions. She performs an
alternative analysis showing higher concentration levels and merger-related changes in
concentration, and, thus, higher amounts of capacity needing to be divested. Other protestors,
including the New Jersey Advocate, question assumptions in Dr. Hieronymus analysis and argue
that he should have performed tests of sensitivity of his results to changes in the underlying
assumptions. They conclude that a hearing is necessary to determine the accuracy of his
assumptions and any effects on his results.
40. FirstEnergy argues that Applicants overestimate the entry of new generation and underestimate
the retirement of old generation, thus overstating the degree of competition in PJM and
understating the mergers effect on competition. Ms. Frayer argues that when Dr. Hieronymuss
erroneous assumptions regarding entry and exit (along with other assumptions she questions) are
corrected, post-merger concentration levels are as high as 2,818 HHI, calling for up to 900 MW more
capacity to be divested in order to mitigate the harm to competition.
41. Hoosier also raises questions regarding the model that Applicants used to perform the
Competitive Analysis Screen. It states that Applicants should be required to submit studies
regarding the effect the increased consolidation of suppliers as a result of the proposed merger
would have on market power concentration in PJM and other affected markets. Hoosier specifically
questions Dr. Hieronymus use of a pro-rata allocation of scarce transmission availability rather
than an economic allocation, which it asserts is more accurate and which would result in greater
merger-related changes in market concentration and thus a need for a larger amount of generation
divestiture. Hoosier argues that if the Commission does not reject the application outright, then
the Commission should establish an evidentiary hearing to address the issues of fact raised by the
proposed merger. The PPL Companies also protest the lack of support for Applicants use of the
squeeze down32 method to allocate imports into the relevant PJM
|
|
|
32 |
|
Under the squeeze down
allocation method, shares of available transmission are allocated at each
interface, diluting as they get closer to the destination market. When there
is competing economic supply to get through a constrained transmission
interface into a control area, the transmission capability is allocated to the
suppliers in proportion |
(continued...)
|
|
|
Docket No. EC05-43-000
|
|
16 |
markets and the failure to address the effect of Applicants Financial Transmission Rights on
transmission capacity in the affected markets.
42. The PHI Companies question the value of Applicants Available Economic Capacity analysis
because state-level restructuring is at different stages in the various PJM states. Thus, the
deduction for native load obligations used in Available Economic Capacity analysis does not
accurately reflect competitive conditions in the various PJM geographic markets analyzed by Dr.
Hieronymus. The PHI Companies also argue that the native load deduction in Dr. Hieronymuss
Available Economic Capacity analysis is incorrect because it imputes PECOs provider of last resort
obligations to PECOs affiliated generating companies, which violates the Commissions policy
requiring regulated, load-serving companies to stand at arms length from their marketing
affiliates. In addition, PPLs witness, Dr. Kalt, argues that although Available Economic Capacity
analysis in PJM East is not straightforward, there is sufficient data on buyer and seller
transactions in New Jersey to develop a more refined analysis that would ensure that Applicants
proposed divestitures will pass the Competitive Analysis Screen for Available Economic Capacity.
He concludes that by failing to satisfy the Commissions requirements and not properly analyzing
Available Economic Capacity, Applicants may have substantially underestimated post-merger
concentration levels in both PJM East and PJM Pre-2004.33
43. Some intervenors argue that the merger will increase Applicants ability to exercise market
power through strategic bidding and that Applicants have not sufficiently analyzed the mergers
effect on strategic bidding in the relevant markets. Furthermore, the New Jersey Division of the
Ratepayer Advocate (Division of the Ratepayer Advocate) states that the Competitive Screen Analysis
submitted by Applicants raises several questions. It argues that data published by PJM shows that
the PJM East markets are substantially more concentrated than Applicants analysis suggests and
that the Applicants methodologies might not detect certain market power problems, such as
strategic bidding concerns. The Division of the Ratepayer Advocate also argues that the mitigation
measures proposed by Applicants do not adequately address the market power problems created by the
proposed merger. In addition, POCA argues that Applicants have not analyzed the potential for
strategic bidding or other actions that could increase prices in the PJM market.
to the amount of economic capacity each supplier has
outside of the interface. Application, Exhibit J-4 at 10-11.
|
|
|
33 |
|
Kalt Testimony at 30-31. |
|
|
|
Docket No. EC05-43-000
|
|
17 |
44. Direct Energy argues that Applicants market power analysis significantly understates
Applicants potential market power after the merger. Direct Energys expert witness, Dr. Andrew
Kleit, argues that the merger significantly enhances the merged firms ability to unilaterally
exercise market power by withholding output of key generation resources along the market supply
curve. Dr. Kleit compares Applicants post-merger costs of withholding output (foregone revenue)
to the benefits (higher prices), and finds that the benefits of withholding the output of peaking
facilities are significantly enhanced by the merger. Dr. Kleit concludes that the merger enhances
the incentive of the merged firm to exercise market power through withholding of output from
peaking facilities. He recommends that the Commission analyze the costs and benefits of
withholding from each of the merged firms peaking facilities.
45. Some parties argue that the Commission does not apply the Competitive Analysis Screen as a
bright line test and that the Applicants, by proposing mitigation specifically designed to restore
the concentration level to within the screens tolerances, have misinterpreted the Commissions
merger policy. For example, the PPL Companies argue that tools such as market share and HHI
screens provide only the starting point for assessing the competitive implications of a
merger.34 They argue that the issue is whether the divesture will result in a market
structure that is sufficiently competitive, not whether a particular HHI level is achieved.
46. A number of parties protest Applicants proposed Buyer Restrictions. The PPL Companies
witness, Dr. Kalt, argues that market forces should determine who acquires the divested assets and
at what price. He further argues that the restrictions may harm market efficiency by not allowing
those buyers that could most efficiently use the generation resources to participate in the
auction.35 The AAI argues that giving Applicants control of the divesture process is
akin to the fox guarding the henhouse.36 It notes that a Federal Trade Commission
(FTC) Staff Study showed that when the FTC
|
|
|
34 |
|
PPL at 7, citing U.S. Department of Justice
and Federal Trade Commission, Horizontal Merger Guidelines, 57 Fed. Reg.
41,552, Sec. 2.0 (1992), revised, 4 Trade Reg. Rep (CCH) ¶ 13,104 (April
8, 1997) (Merger Guidelines). |
|
35 |
|
Kalt Testimony at 15-17. |
|
36 |
|
AAI at 13. |
|
|
|
Docket No. EC05-43-000
|
|
18 |
determined the assets that were to be divested, merging companies urged the FTC to divest assets to
weak buyers; proposed packages of assets that were too narrow to ensure fully viable competition;
and took actions that diminished the viability of the business acquired by the buyer.37
47. Midwest Generation states that the Commission should consider whether Applicants proposed
Buyer Restrictions are reasonable; it says that they could undermine Applicants ability to fully
divest the assets necessary to mitigate the market power problem. Therefore, the Commission should
consider requiring Applicants to eliminate the restrictions or, in the alternative, require
Applicants to identify an alternative should their restrictive divestiture plan fail.
48. Protestors argue that Applicants proposed virtual divestiture is not as effective as physical
divestiture for a number of reasons. Hoosier requests that the Commission reject Applicants
virtual divestiture proposal and require absolute and permanent divestiture of ownership. The APPA
and NRECA state that the proposal is inadequate to remedy the potential market power abuses that
will result from the proposed merger. Additionally, POCA argues that virtual divestiture has never
before been relied upon by the Commission as a mitigation tool and that it is not a permanent
structural change.
49. Regarding the virtual divestiture proposal, FirstEnergy argues that Applicants must submit the
terms and conditions of the long-term contracts; specify the auction protocols; include the
long-term rights to capacity as well as energy so that there is sufficient capacity-related
mitigation; and enter into long-term, firm contracts for nuclear energy and capacity, or impose bid
caps for the non-nuclear assets that are more likely to set prices. It also states that the PJM
Market Monitoring Unit (MMU) must monitor the implementation of the interim mitigation measures.
FirstEnergy also questions the practical effects of virtual divestiture, such as how the
Applicants market power will be held in check after the long-term contracts expire, and what
Applicants will do if there are not enough purchasers in the auction process or those buyers
default. In addition, FirstEnergy states that Applicants will obtain a market price for their
energy, and questions whether the energy sales are actually mitigation if Applicants are able to
receive the same price (i.e., post-merger, post-mitigation) for the energy that they would have
received without mitigation.38
|
|
|
37 |
|
AAI at 14, citing Federal Trade Commission, Bureau of
Competition, Study of the Commissions Divestiture Process. Washington,
D.C. 1999 at 16. |
|
38 |
|
FirstEnergy at 46. |
|
|
|
Docket No. EC05-43-000
|
|
19 |
50. FirstEnergy argues that the Commission rejected partial divestiture in the AEP/CSW
merger39 for the reasons stated above. It states that, in that case, the Commission
rejected applicants proposal to divest a minority interest in a generating facility while
retaining operational control over the output of the facility, and required applicants to divest
their entire ownership interest in the generating facilities at issue.40 Finally,
FirstEnergy argues that the Commission rejected a proposal similar to Applicants baseload auction
in Allegheny/DQE41, where the Commission expressed concern that the entire output of the
facility in question would not be sold under the proposed RFP, and stated:
Divestiture would permanently eliminate the opportunity for the merged company to
exercise the market power (by withholding output to raise electricity prices)
conferred on them by the merger.42
51. AAI also finds flaws in Applicants proposed divestiture plan, arguing that it does not provide
sufficient information to satisfy concerns such as the need to create viable, independent
competitors in the markets. Specifically, AAI argues that Applicants proposed virtual divestiture
would allow Applicants to keep ownership and control of the capacity while they sell or swap the
energy to third-party purchasers and that this would not adequately address the market power
concerns raised by the proposed merger or create a viable competitor in the market. Another
problem is that with Applicants controlling the virtual (and actual) divestiture process, the
Commission could not modify or oversee the divestiture plans; and Applicants would have little
incentive to divest and mitigate in a way that would create viable competitors and markets. AAI
also argues that Applicants have not demonstrated the claimed efficiencies or other benefits that
would allegedly result from the merger, particularly Applicants nuclear assets. Finally, AAI
notes that the antitrust agencies prefer structural mitigation, such as divestiture, to
conduct-based remedies, which are often difficult to design, cumbersome and costly to administer,
and easier to circumvent than structural remedies.43
|
|
|
39 |
|
American Electric Power Co., et al., 90
FERC ¶ 61,242 (2000) (AEP/CSW). |
|
40 |
|
FirstEnergy at 43, citing AEP/CSW at 61,792. |
|
41 |
|
Allegheny Energy, Inc., et al., 84 FERC
¶ 61,223 (1998) (Allegheny/DQE). |
|
42 |
|
FirstEnergy at 45, citing Allegheny/DQE at 62,070. |
|
43 |
|
AAI at 9, citing U.S. DOJ, Antitrust Division,
Antitrust Division Policy Guide to Merger Remedies (2004). |
|
|
|
Docket No. EC05-43-000
|
|
20 |
52. The City of Philadelphia also protests Applicants use of virtual divestiture. The Office of
the Peoples Counsel claims that Applicants do not sufficiently explain how virtual divestiture
will effectively mitigate market power. Therefore, they state that the Commission should establish
hearing procedures to address the validity of the proposed mitigation and to explore how the
mitigation, including the proposed virtual divestiture, will remedy the market power problems and
screen failures resulting from the proposed merger.
53. Amtrak argues that the Applicants fail to set forth the legal basis for using the virtual
divestiture as permanent mitigation and fail to demonstrate its effectiveness. Furthermore, Amtrak
argues that the proposed virtual divestiture is not a permanent mitigation measure, since control
of all generation will return to the merged entity after a fixed time period. Amtrak also argues
that the PJM Market Monitoring Unit (MMU) is unable to compensate and adequately administer the
unduly complicated and administratively burdensome proposed virtual divestiture.
54. The PHI Companies state that virtual divestiture is unacceptable because it fails to transfer
control over the units operation, including the scheduling and duration of maintenance outages,
and because the actual merged entity, and its market power, will outlast the virtual divestiture.
The PHI Companies argue that the three year baseload auction energy sales might not continue over
the proposed 15-year period, and urge the Commission to evaluate the actual mitigating effects of
the virtual divestiture and impose certain conditions on the virtual divestiture. The PHI
Companies economic witness, Dr. Cichetti, argues that the three-year and 15-year contracts do
not adequately mitigate Applicants market power because the nuclear units would not be divested
and would still be controlled by EE&G, which will be able to affect market prices in the Basic
Generation Service auction. He concludes that the virtually divested MWs should be considered to
be controlled by EE&G in Dr. Hieronymus Appendix A analysis. Therefore, in order to fully evaluate
the effect on the PJM markets and the validity of Applicants mitigation plan, the PHI Companies
request that the Commission establish an evidentiary hearing.
55. The NJBPU states that it is concerned about the creation of significant market power in the PJM
markets involved in the states Basic Generation Service auctions and the effect that that market
power would have on the Basic Generation Service auction process. The NJBPU asked the PJM MMU to
study the effects of the proposed merger on competition in all relevant PJM markets. It also
raises several concerns regarding Applicants proposed mitigation plan and the effect the
mitigation would have competition in the relevant PJM markets. Therefore, the NJBPU requests that
the Commission establish an evidentiary hearing to fully evaluate all aspects of Applicants
proposed merger.
|
|
|
Docket No. EC05-43-000
|
|
21 |
56. The Illinois Attorney General states that the merger would exacerbate already existing market
power problems in the PJM markets that influence the prices paid for electricity by Illinois
customers. It states that the Illinois Commerce Commission is in the process of approving an
auction similar to the Basic Generation Service auctions that take place in the New Jersey markets,
and argues that the proposed merger could undermine the ability of the proposed auction to secure
electricity at competitive prices for Illinois consumers. Therefore, the Illinois Attorney General
requests that the Commission set this matter for hearing.
57. AAI argues that Applicants failure to specify which units will be divested allows Applicants
to divest the units that are least likely to compete with the assets kept by Applicants.
Similarly, numerous parties, including Hoosier, AAI, the PHI Companies, FirstEnergy, the PPL
Companies and the Division of the Ratepayer Advocate, argue that Applicants mitigation plan fails
to comply with the Commissions requirements by failing to specify which of Applicants facilities
would be divested.44
58. FirstEnergys witness, Ms. Frayer, raises a number of concerns regarding Applicants interim
mitigation proposal. Specifically, she argues that: (1) Applicants have not provided sufficient
detail about the interim mitigation;45 (2) there must be a credible and transparent
means of oversight over Applicants enforcement of the interim auctions, as the Commission
recognized in OG&E;46 and (3) Applicants proposal to bid the nuclear capacity into the
PJM markets at a $0 price does not mitigate market power because the nuclear plants do not set the
market-clearing price.
59. Protestors also point out that transmission expansion is a form of market power mitigation.
FirstEnergy argues that the Commission should consider what studies the PJM MMU might perform to
identify the specific transmission enhancements Applicants could be required to construct to
relieve congestion in PJM East as a condition of merger approval. The PHI Companies argue that
Applicants may have positions in the PJM queue for generation interconnection projects and that
they should be required to
|
|
|
44 |
|
Protestors cite the Merger Policy Statement
at 30, 136, where the Commission stated that merger applicants must specify the
units to be divested. |
|
45 |
|
Ms. Frayer cites the Commissions finding in
AEP/CSW, where the
Commission required Applicants to file the terms and
conditions associated with interim mitigation so the Commission could
assess whether the proposed mitigation would be effective. Frayer Testimony at
51, citing AEP/CSW at 61,794. |
|
46 |
|
Frayer Testimony at 51, citing Oklahoma Gas & Elec. Co., 108
FERC ¶ 61,004 at PP 38-39 (2004) (OG&E). |
|
|
|
Docket No. EC05-43-000
|
|
22 |
relinquish these positions in order to enable other parties to construct generation in the affected
markets, thus limiting the merged company from re-establishing its pre-mitigation market
power.47
60. The PHI Companies argue that the sheer size of the merged company (nearly 40,000 MW of
generation in PJM) creates market power problems that the Commissions Competitive Analysis Screen
does not address. POCA also argues that the size and scope of this proposed merger will present
opportunities for the merged entity to wield market power, even after the proposed mitigation and
divestiture. POCA points out that Applicants would still own 37,100 MW of generation in PJM,
including 14,400 MW, or 36 percent of the capacity in PJM East, the most constrained market in PJM.
61. Protestors question how the proposed merger will affect Applicants authorization to sell power
at market-based rates. First Energys witness, Ms. Frayer, performed an analysis which she
characterized as being required for Applicants to be able to continue to sell power at market-based
rates, and concluded that Applicants would fail the 20 percent market share
screen.48
While acknowledging that this case is under section 203 of the FPA, not
section 205, FirstEnergy concludes that the Commission will have to address the issue of the merged
firms market-based rate authorization, and that the Commission should make a decision in the 203
proceeding that will pass muster in the related section 205 market-based rate
proceedings.49 FirstEnergy argues that when the 20 percent market share threshold is
violated, which Ms. Frayer shows will occur even when Applicants proposed mitigation plan is
imposed, the Commission then requires a delivered price test which is exactly what the
Applicants performed in this section 203 proceeding. Dominions witness, Mr. Frank Graves, also
finds that, even with mitigation, Applicants will have a greater than 20 percent market share in
Expanded PJM, and that Applicants would need to divest an additional 1,200 MW in order to pass the
Commissions market share screen for market-based rate authorization.
|
|
|
47 |
|
PHI Companies at 45. |
|
48 |
|
In April 2004, the Commission established a 20 percent
Wholesale Market Share indicative screen, as well as another screen, for
analyzing generation dominance in market-based rate applications. AEP
Marketing, Inc., et al., 107 FERC ¶ 61,018 (2004). |
|
49 |
|
First Energy at 38. |
|
|
|
Docket No. EC05-43-000
|
|
23 |
62. Dominion argues that the market-share screen failure indicates that Applicants will have market
power in PJM and urges the Commission to reject any argument that the PJM MMU can address market
power issues in the PJM market. Amtrak, the Coalition and the Energy Users Group also argue that
the Commission should not rely on the PJM MMU to identify and prevent exercises of market power.
63. FirstEnergy states that Applicants have not provided any details regarding their planned
reorganization of the unregulated entities owned by Exelon and PSE&G, and argues that the
Commission cannot find that the reorganization will be consistent with the public interest until
Applicants provide details. FirstEnergy states that in Ameren Energy, the Commission recognized
that some types of internal reorganizations can harm competition, and asserts that the Commission
cannot act on Applicants proposed internal restructuring based on the limited information provided
in the application.50
64. NiSource states that it does not oppose the merger, but it requests that the Commission
condition approval on the resolution of NiSources increased parallel path flow, or loop flow,
problems, which will be exacerbated by the proposed merger. Therefore, NiSource requests that the
Commission require Applicants to further study how the proposed merger will affect loop flow and
take certain remedial actions, such as requiring Applicants to mitigate their loop flow if the
Applicants proposed merger is approved.
B. Applicants Answer to the Protests
65. On May 10, 2005, Applicants filed an answer and amendment to their original filing. Notice of
the answer and amendment to the filing was published in the Federal Register,51 with
comments due on or before May 27, 2005.
66. Applicants acknowledge that protestors have raised some good points regarding errors in Dr.
Hieronymuss original analysis, but argue that, even with the appropriate revisions to the inputs
in their analysis, Applicants have shown that the proposed divestiture fully mitigates the
merger-related harm to competition. Applicants cite four specific examples of factual errors in
the original analysis: (1) the analysis should have included a 200 MW power purchase agreement
between PECO and Hoosier in 2006;
|
|
|
50 |
|
FirstEnergy at 54-56, citing Ameren
Energy Generating Co., et al., 103 FERC ¶ 61,128 (2003) (Ameren
Energy). |
|
51 |
|
70 Fed. Reg. 29, 299 (2005). |
|
|
|
Docket No. EC05-43-000
|
|
24 |
(2) the analysis should have included PPLs recently completed 600 MW Lower Mount Bethel combined
cycle facility; (3) the analysis should have used 2,595 MW, rather than 4,800 MW, of generating
capacity for Conectiv Energy Services, Inc. in PJM East; and (4) the analysis failed to account for
Dominions native load obligation in the calculation of Available Economic Capacity. Applicants
state that Dr. Hieronymus has made those changes in his analysis and that the resulting changes are
minor and do not affect the mitigation required to repair the mergers harm to competition.
67. Applicants respond to protestors arguments regarding the relevant geographic markets that
would be affected by the merger. Answering the PPL Companies and the PHI Companies argument
regarding the Northern New Jersey market, Applicants state that, because there was no overlap
between Exelons and PSE&Gs generation in Northern New Jersey, Dr. Hieronymus analyzed the effect
of the merger on that market and found that the mitigation for the PJM East market, along with an
additional 100 MW divestiture of generation located in Northern New Jersey, would mitigate the harm
to competition.
68. The PPL Companies argue that due to prevailing transmission constraints, the PJM Classic
market, consisting of PJM Classic and the Allegheny Power system (Allegheny), should be analyzed as
a separate market within the larger PJM Pre-2004 market. In response, Applicants assert that
although PJMs western interface once created a transmission constraint separating Allegheny from
PJM Classic that constraint no longer exists, because PJM now redispatches the system when the
constraint threatens to limit the west-to-east flows within PJM.52 Applicants cite the
PJM Market Monitors 2004 State of the Market Report, which explains how the system operator
redispatches higher-cost generating units in order to maintain the prevailing west-to-east flows
from Allegheny into PJM Classic.
69. Applicants also address Protestors assertion that they should have analyzed PJM West and the
Rest of PJM Pre-2004 market (PJM Pre-2004 minus PJM West). They argue that the prevailing power
flows are east-to-west, so the resulting transmission constraints can make PJM East a load pocket
and, thus, a separate geographic market. However, Applicants argue that east-to-west flows are
unconstrained, so there is no reason to consider PJM West as a separate market, because suppliers
in PJM East can compete in the PJM West Market. Applicants contend that Protestors rationale for
defining the relevant geographic market based on sellers opportunity costs is inconsistent with
Commission precedent and Appendix A of the Merger Policy Statement. They state that Appendix A
instructs applicants to consider those suppliers
|
|
|
Docket No. EC05-43-000
|
|
25 |
with low enough variable costs that they could compete (subject to transmission constraints) in a
geographic market, not whether potential suppliers would consider the opportunity cost of selling
into a particular geographic market.
70. Applicants address protestors questions about the fuel cost and assumed wholesale market
prices in their analysis. While acknowledging that the assumed market prices are important
parameters in the model, they argue that consistency between fuel cost assumptions and the
prevailing market prices is most critical, and that Dr. Hieronymuss and Mr.
Frames testimonies are each internally consistent in their fuel cost and market price assumptions.
That is, fuel cost assumptions on the low end of the range of observed or projected costs should
correspond to market price assumptions on the low end of the range of observed or projected prices;
likewise for high prices. They state that the protestors, including FirstEnergys witness, Ms.
Frayer, have been able to show different results by changing one or the other of Dr. Hieronymus
assumptions about fuel costs or market prices, but that those results are meaningless without a
corresponding change in the other assumption. Moreover, Applicants
assert that Ms.
Frayers arguments about the accuracy of the fuel cost inputs are overstated because they do not
change the merit order of the plants that would be dispatched under various market conditions;
thus, they do not materially affect the results of Applicants analysis.53 Applicants
point out that Dr. Hieronymus and Mr. Frame used different fuel cost and market price assumptions,
but arrived at very similar results, thus showing that the results are not sensitive to changes in
fuel cost and market price assumptions. Finally, Applicants argue that some of the fuel costs and
market prices assumed by protestors witnesses are wrong.54
71. Applicants address claims that they should have performed more tests on the sensitivity of
their results to changes in the assumed market prices. First, they argue that by using a range of
prices from $20/MWh to $80/MWH and arriving at similar results throughout the range, Dr. Hieronymus
has shown that changes in the assumed market price will not materially change his results. Second,
as noted above, they argue that Mr. Frames analysis serves as a sensitivity test of Dr.
Hieronymus analysis and confirms that the results are not sensitive to changes in fuel cost and
market price assumptions.
|
|
|
53 |
|
Applicants argue that under any
plausible forecast, changes in fuel cost assumptions would not, for example,
make coal-fired capacity cheaper than nuclear capacity, or natural gas-fired
capacity cheaper than coal-fired capacity. Thus, the results for economic
capacity would not be materially different under any reasonable fuel cost
assumption. |
|
54 |
|
Answer at 17. |
|
|
|
Docket No. EC05-43-000
|
|
26 |
72. Regarding FirstEnergys assertion that Dr. Hieronymus overestimated the amount of new
generation coming on line and underestimated the amount of old generation being retired in PJM,
Applicants state that FirstEnergys claims are erroneous and are based on statements Dr. Hieronymus
used in a different context, not in his analysis of energy markets. They state that in his
analysis of energy markets, Dr. Hieronymus relied on PJM reports as to which plants would be coming
on line and which would be retired in 2006, the test year, and that his comments about entry that
FirstEnergy cites were more general and in the context of the competitiveness of long-term capacity
markets. They also note that FirstEnergys witness, Ms. Frayer, used the same assumptions
regarding generation entry and exit in her analysis of the relevant energy markets as did
Dr. Hieronymus.
73. Applicants also address protests regarding Dr. Hieronymus allocation of available transmission
in his analysis. Applicants challenge Hoosiers and the PPL Companies claims that using a pro
rata, rather than economic, allocation of available transmission skews the results of the analysis
by understating the allocation of import capability for Applicants low-cost generation and
systematically reducing the HHI. They say that the Commission has accepted the use of pro rata
transmission allocation in numerous DPT analyses. They further state that, despite claims of an
opportunistic use of the pro rata allocation by Dr. Hieronymus, he has always used that method in
his many DPT analyses before the Commission.
74. Regarding their analysis of Available Economic Capacity, Applicants reiterate their argument
that in retail choice states such as those affected by the merger, Available Economic Capacity is
difficult to measure and does not accurately portray competitive conditions. They state that
protestors largely agree with that assertion and that protestors attacks on Dr. Hieronymus
analysis of Available Economic Capacity miss the fundamental point. While other suppliers native
load data are not available, they do have data on their own native load obligation, so they are
able to model their own Available Economic Capacity and conclude that the divestiture will bring
that total below the pre-merger level.
75. Applicants address the numerous protests regarding the possibility of the merger creating or
enhancing the merged firms incentive and/or ability to engage in strategic bidding, thus
increasing its unilateral market power. First, they argue that the Commissions Merger Policy
Statement does not require an analysis of strategic bidding, nor is there case precedent requiring
such an analysis. Rather, the Commission relies on the analysis described in Appendix A of the
Merger Policy Statement, which is based on the Merger Guidelines, a well-established and
court-affirmed analytical methodology. They further state that HHI screens are useful for
analyzing the effect of a merger on the unilateral exercise of market power and cite the Merger
Guidelines, which state that [o]ther things being equal, market concentration affects the
likelihood that one firm, or a
|
|
|
Docket No. EC05-43-000
|
|
27 |
small group of firms, could successfully exercise market power.55 Finally, they state
that the analysis by Direct Energys witness, Dr. Kleit, of the cost and benefits of withholding
and strategic bidding, is filled with errors and questionable assumptions.
76. Applicants characterize the protests regarding their proposed mitigation as falling into two
major categories: (1) the Applicants proposed an inadequate amount of divestiture; and (2) virtual
divestiture does not adequately mitigate market power. They further state that the questions
raised by protestors are not issues of material fact that would require a hearing to explore, but
legal and policy issues that can be decided by the Commission without a hearing.
77. Applicants respond to the PHI Companies, the PPL Companies and FirstEnergys argument that
Applicants have misinterpreted the HHI screen as an absolute standard for Commission approval of a
merger or acquisition. They assert that it is the PHI Companies, PPL Companies and FirstEnergy who
have misinterpreted the Commissions reliance on the HHI screen. Citing the Merger Policy
Statement and the Merger Filings Requirements Rule, Applicants state that the Commission uses the
screen to identify those mergers or acquisitions that will not require a hearing or additional
mitigation in order to be authorized by the Commission, absent compelling evidence otherwise raised
by intervenors. They conclude that because their proposed mitigation returns market concentration
to levels that would pass the Competitive Analysis Screen, and no intervenor has made a showing
that the merger has anticompetitive effects despite passing the screens, they have met the
Commissions standard for showing a lack of harm to competition.
78. Applicants argue that FirstEnergys assertion that an additional 890 MW of divestiture is
required to avoid screen failures in the summer rest of peak and shoulder rest of peak periods
is based on a miscalculation of Applicants proposed divestiture. They argue that Ms. Frayer
undercounted the amount of the proposed divesture that would be relevant for the summer rest of
peak and shoulder rest of peak periods by 1200 MW, because she was inconsistent between the
types of units that would be considered economic capacity given her assumed price levels and the
types of units that Applicants have committed to divest.56
79. While Applicants disagree with the argument raised by numerous protestors regarding Applicants
proposed Buyer Restrictions to purchase the divested plants and virtually divested energy, they
offer to withdraw most of the proposed restrictions. They
|
|
|
55 |
|
Answer at 25, citing § 2.0 of the
Merger Guidelines. |
|
56 |
|
Hieronymus Supplemental Testimony at 23-24. |
|
|
|
Docket No. EC05-43-000
|
|
28 |
are willing to withdraw the restrictions that: (1) no more than half of the fossil generation
would be sold to a single buyer and; (2) none would be sold to a market participant with a greater
than five percent market share in PJM-East or Expanded PJM. Additionally, they withdraw the
restriction that they will not sell more than 25 percent of the Baseload
Mitigation Amount to market participants owning three to five percent of the installed generation
capacity in Expanded PJM or PJM East. They continue to propose, however, the 50 percent limit on
the total purchase of the virtually divested nuclear capacity.57
80. In order to allow suppliers with larger pre-existing market shares in PJM to purchase the
divested capacity, Applicants propose divesting an additional 1,100 MW of generating capacity (900
MW of fossil generating capacity and 200 MW of virtual nuclear capacity) in the PJM Pre-2004
market. Dr. Hieronymus analyzes the effect of the merger on competition with the increased
divestiture and the assumption that equal shares of the entire divestiture amount were purchased by
the four largest owners of capacity in PJM-East: PPL, Reliant, Conectiv and FirstEnergy. Under
that scenario, for PJM-East, he finds that the post-merger-and-mitigation concentration levels
range from 1,218 to 1,465 HHI, with changes in concentration ranging from negative 88 to 95 HHI,
all within the Commissions screening threshold for moderately concentrated markets. For PJM
Pre-2004, he finds that the post-merger-and-mitigation concentration levels range from 996 to 1,292
HHI, with changes in concentration ranging from 48 to 105 HHI, with one period (shoulder peak, a
moderately concentrated market with a change in concentration of 100 HHI) failing the Commissions
screening threshold for moderately concentrated and unconcentrated markets.58
81. Applicants acknowledge that the additional mitigation does not necessarily cure all possible
screen failures for all possible combinations of sales to companies with large market shares. They
state that they will, therefore, make a compliance filing showing the effect on market
concentration given the actual divestitures and the same data and assumptions used in Applicants
revised Appendix A analysis, in order to show that no material screen failures will have resulted.
82. Applicants characterize the protests regarding their proposed virtual divestiture as falling
into two major categories: (1) virtual divestiture is not as effective as physical divestiture in
mitigating market power; and (2) compliance with the virtual divestiture commitment will be
difficult to monitor, giving Applicants the ability to avoid the commitments they have made to the
Commission.
|
|
|
57 |
|
Answer at 32. |
|
58 |
|
Hieronymus Supplemental Testimony at 50. |
|
|
|
Docket No. EC05-43-000
|
|
29 |
83. Applicants argue that the virtual divestiture is as effective as physical divestiture. They
argue that the fact that the Commission has never approved sales of capacity, such as the virtual
divesture proposal, as long-term mitigation, does not preclude the virtual divesture plan from
being effective long-term mitigation. They state that, in the Merger Policy Statement, the
Commission contemplated a possible alternative to physical divestiture that is similar to their
proposed virtual divestiture:
[O]ne alternative might be to divest the ownership rights to energy and capacity to
a number of owners. The unit could then be operated as a competitive joint venture
and parts of its output could be bid or sold independently.59
Applicants argue that their virtual divestiture plan, while not a joint venture, does divest the
ownership rights to energy to a number of owners that can independently sell that energy or bid it
into the PJM market.
84. Applicants argue that the Commission did not, in the Merger Policy Statement, establish
physical divestiture as the only plausible mitigation for harm to competition; rather it recognized
that there are numerous mitigation measures that can be effective and stated that it would
consider the adequacy of various mitigation measures on a case-by-case basis.60
Applicants assert that they have provided the analysis necessary for the Commission to determine
the adequacy of virtual divestiture, and cite the testimony of Mr. Cassidy and Mr. Sabitino,
explaining that the rights to the energy are firm rights and that the Applicants would have to pay
liquidated damages if they failed to deliver. They further argue that, because the liquidated
damages are based on the cost of covering any shortfall, they would have no incentive to withhold
the energy subject to the virtual divestiture in order to profit from increased energy prices,
because they would have to pay the cost of any such increase.
85. Applicants state that, under the virtual divestiture plan, the obligation to deliver energy is
not tied to any specific unit and that they will guarantee the delivery of a specific amount of
24/7 energy under both the Auction Plan and the Long-Term
|
|
|
59 |
|
Answer at 35, citing Merger Policy Statement at 30,137. |
|
60 |
|
Id. at 30,900. |
|
|
|
Docket No. EC05-43-000
|
|
30 |
Contract Plan, regardless of which units are operating.61 They assert that this
guarantee eliminates the ability to profit by withholding output from the units that are under the
virtual divestiture plan. Finally, Applicants note that the Commission has recognized in a number
of cases that the operating characteristics of nuclear units reduce the danger of withholding
output in order to raise prices.62
86. In response to FirstEnergys assertion that the Commission rejected the sale of long-term power
as mitigation in Allegheny, Applicants argue that FirstEnergy omitted the reasoning behind the
Commissions decision and that the circumstances are different here. They state that, in
Allegheny, the Commission was concerned that the merged company reserve[s] the right to reject any
and all bids, and that the merged company would thus retain control over the generation facility.
Here, they argue, Applicants have committed to sell all of the energy that is offered, regardless
of the price of the bids, and an independent auction monitor will oversee Applicants compliance
with that commitment.
87. Applicants dispute FirstEnergys assertion that they will receive the same price for the
virtually divested energy as they would have in the absence of mitigation. They state that, under
the virtual divestiture plan, they will receive the price determined in the auction for the
three-year life of each contract, whereas if they retained control of the output of the nuclear
units, they would be able to benefit from any market price increases during the same three-year
period. They conclude that, because of the three-year contracts, they will have no economic
incentive to increase the market price in order to increase profit from the virtually divested
capacity.
88. Applicants challenge Dr. Cichettis assertion that they will retain control of both the
three-year and the 15-year products offered in the virtual divestiture plan because the purchasers
of those products will likely resell the power in the Basic Generation Service auction. They state
that, in both cases, the Applicants are obligated to deliver 24/7 energy to the buyers, and the
buyers, not the sellers, will determine whether to participate in the Basic Generation Service
auction or use it elsewhere. Applicants conclude that they cannot control the capacity or the
price of the energy in the Basic Generation Service auction.
|
|
|
61 |
|
Answer at 36. |
|
62 |
|
Answer at 37, citing U.S. Gen New England, 109 FERC
¶ 61,361 at P23 (2004); Ohio Edison Co., 94 FERC
¶ 61,291 at 62,044 (2001); and Commonwealth Edison Co., 91 FERC ¶
61,036 at 61,134 n. 42 (2000). |
|
|
|
Docket No. EC05-43-000
|
|
31 |
89. Regarding protestors claims that the proposed energy swaps could harm competition in other
geographic markets by increasing the concentration of control of capacity and energy in other
geographic markets, Applicants argue that any such swap would have to be approved under section 203
and that the Commission could address any competitive concerns. Moreover, Applicants argue that
they control very little electric generation capacity in other geographic markets, so the
possibility of harm to competition elsewhere is remote.
90. Applicants recognize protestors arguments that the antitrust agencies generally prefer
structural mitigation to behavioral mitigation and that behavioral mitigation requires ongoing
monitoring for compliance. In response, Applicants commit to establish a public compliance web
site that will show how they are complying with the virtual divestiture and all other mitigation
requirements.63 Applicants reiterate their commitment that the annual auctions for
three-year energy contracts will be administered by an independent auction manager.
91. Applicants respond to the numerous protests regarding their proposal for implementing the
mitigation. In response to the PHI Companies concern that the three year baseload auction energy
sales might not continue over the proposed 15-year period, Applicants state that the PHI Companies
are mistaken, and restate their commitment from the Application:
Applicants explicitly reaffirm that the entire Baseload Mitigation Amount
of nuclear virtual divestiture (2,600 MW) will remain in place after 15
years, subject to a reduction in the mitigation amount if the Applicants PJM East
nuclear capacity is decommissioned, derated, or sold or there is construction of new
transmission transfer capability into PJM East.64
92. A number of protestors question the 18-month time period for the fossil divestiture and argue
that it should be shorter. For example, AAI states that antitrust agencies advocate shorter time
periods for completing divestitures. In response, Applicants commit to executing sales agreements
and making filings before the Commission for the approval of the sales no later than one year after
the closing date of the Transaction.65
|
|
|
63 |
|
Answer at 43. |
|
64 |
|
Answer at 46. |
|
65 |
|
Answer at 47. |
|
|
|
Docket No. EC05-43-000
|
|
32 |
93. Regarding protestors arguments that the Merger Policy Statement requires Applicants to
identify the specific units that will be divested, Applicants argue that while they did not
identify the exact units, they did identify the location and the types of generation to be divested
and the pool of generation facilities eligible for divesture. They further argue that by not
specifying the exact units, they give potential buyers more flexibility and let market forces
decide which units should be divested. Finally, they argue that in AEP/CSW, rather than accepting
applicants commitment to divest portions of two generating facilities totaling 550 MWs, the
Commission expressly directed applicants to divest any unit or units totaling the same number of
megawatts and having the same cost, operation, and location characteristics as the specific
plants.66 They conclude that the Commission has made it clear that it is not necessary
to specify the plants that will be divested to mitigate Appendix A screen failures.
94. Applicants respond to protestors arguments regarding the proposal to reduce the amount of the
baseload mitigation MW-for-MW for any increase in transmission transfer capability into PJM-East or
for any reduction in Applicants nuclear generating capacity due to de-rating, decommissioning, or
sales of nuclear capacity in PJM-East. Applicants assert that the market power concern regarding
nuclear units is that, because they are low-cost units that are always in merit, their owners
benefit from any withholding of other units that would raise the market-clearing
price.67 They argue that a decrease in the amount of nuclear capacity held by
Applicants, whether through divestiture, de-rating, or unit retirement, would have the same effect
in terms of mitigating market power. Thus, any reduction in the nuclear capacity held by
Applicants should be considered effective market power mitigation, because any such reduction
reduces the ability to profit from withholding output from other units. Regarding decreases to the
baseload mitigation amount for increases in transmission transfer capability into PJM East,
Applicants argue that increasing transfer capability into PJM-East would enable competitive
suppliers to defeat attempts by generators in PJM East to drive up prices by withholding output,
and, thus, should also be considered effective market power mitigation.
95. Applicants respond to the numerous challenges to the effectiveness of their proposed interim
mitigation. Regarding FirstEnergys assertion that the PJM MMU should monitor Applicants
compliance with their interim mitigation plan, Applicants reiterate their commitment to establish a
public compliance web site that will show how they are complying with the virtual divestiture and
all other mitigation requirements,
|
|
|
66 |
|
Answer at 49 citing AEP/CSW at 61,792. |
|
67 |
|
Applicants reiterate their argument that the Commission has recognized, in a number of cases, that the operating
characteristics of nuclear units reduce the danger of withholding output from
nuclear plants in order to raise prices. |
|
|
|
Docket No. EC05-43-000
|
|
33 |
including the interim mitigation plan. Moreover, they state that the PJM MMU has access to all the
bid data in the PJM markets and will be able to track the amount of capacity bid into the PJM
market under the interim mitigation plan. Regarding FirstEnergys claim that the Application
provides insufficient detail about the interim mitigation, Applicants refer to the Cassidy
testimony, which describes the amount of the dispatch rights; the rights afforded the purchasers of
the capacity; the terms of the master agreement for the sales; the price of the energy and
capacity; the timing and duration of the interim sales; and any associated rollover
provisions.68
96. FirstEnergy asserts that Applicants proposal to bid the output of their nuclear plants into
the PJM energy market at a $0 price is inadequate because nuclear plants do not set the
market-clearing price, and, therefore, Applicants should propose bid caps for their generating
units that are likely to set the price. Applicants respond that they are doing precisely what
FirstEnergy recommends. They have committed to bid the mid-merit and peaking units (the units most
likely to set the clearing price) into the PJM market subject to a variable cost bid cap.
Applicants challenge various claims that they should only be allowed to charge cost-based rates.
They say that such claims are unfounded and, as a practical matter, no protestors have explained
how offers of cost-based sales could be made in the single-clearing-price PJM Market.
97. A number of protestors, including FirstEnergy and PHI Companies, request that Applicants
provide transmission upgrades as part of their mitigation package. Applicants state that, while
they have opted for generation divestiture rather than transmission expansion as their form of
market power mitigation, they are engaged in the PJM Regional Transmission Planning Process, and
commit to additional transmission expansion. Specifically, in addition to their existing
transmission commitments, they commit to complete two transmission projects whether or not the
merger is approved by the Commission, and, if the Commission approves the merger without an
evidentiary hearing, they commit to fund $25 million of transmission projects on PJMs list of
Economic Projects over the next five years.69
98. Applicants characterize a number of issues raised by protestors as being policy issues that
have no merit and do not require a hearing to resolve. First, they respond to protestors claims
that, if the merger is approved, it will halt future merger activity in PJM by increasing the level
of market concentration. They argue that the Commission
|
|
|
68 |
|
Application, Cassidy testimony at 5-8. |
|
69 |
|
Answer at 60. |
|
|
|
Docket No. EC05-43-000
|
|
34 |
has determined that it will review mergers on their own merits, rather than based on the effect
they could have on possible future mergers.70
99. In addition, Applicants argue that claims that the merger would create a mega-utility with a
dominant market position and that the Commissions Appendix A analysis does not sufficiently
address such a possibility are misguided. They state that no intervenor has identified any
specific issues that cannot be addressed using the tools available to the Commission.
100. Applicants note that a number of protestors have argued that the merged firm will not pass the
Commissions screen for generation market power under its market-based rates review. In response,
Applicants state that they disagree with protestors conclusions, but, more importantly, they argue
that the Commission can address the issue of the merged firms market-based rates when Applicants
make their updated market-based rates filing.
101. Applicants argue that NiSources protests regarding loop flows should be rejected because they
are not related to the merger. They state that NiSources complaint is about loop flows that might
arise due to ComEd joining PJM, and that the Commission already has a proceeding regarding loop
flows between PJM and the Midwest ISO.71 They further note that NiSource has filed a
complaint in Docket No. EL05-103 in which it raised the same concerns.
102. Applicants respond to FirstEnergys assertion that they have not demonstrated that their
proposed internal corporate restructuring is consistent with the public interest. They state that
FirstEnergys cite to the Commissions finding in Ameren Energy is misplaced, because Applicants
have committed that there will be no transfers of generation assets from merchant generating
companies to traditional franchised utilities, which was the Commissions concern in Ameren Energy.
|
|
|
70 |
|
Id. at 63, citing Ohio Edison Co., 85 FERC
¶ 61,203 at 61,846 (1998) (rejecting intervenors requests to
look at possible future mergers when assessing the potential competitive
effects of a merger.) |
|
71 |
|
Applicants cite the Joint Operating
Agreement in Docket No. ER04-375, first accepted in Midwest Independent
Transmission System Operator, Inc. 106 FERC ¶ 61,251 (2004).
Answer at 76. |
|
|
|
Docket No. EC05-43-000
|
|
35 |
C. The PJM MMU Study
103. The PJM MMU analyzed the effect of the proposed transaction on competition in PJMs energy,
capacity, regulation, and spinning reserve markets.72 In its energy market analysis,
the PJM MMU looks at the market for all of PJM, as well as defined locational markets.73
The PJM MMU notes that one must take care in interpreting the results and offers that one must
recognize that Dominion entered the PJM market on May 1, 2005, so the market conditions before that
date no longer exist. Further, the post-Dominion integration data reflects only a narrow range of
market conditions.
104. The PJM MMU states that it calculated market concentration levels on a pre- and post-merger
basis for two time periods: (a) October 1, 2004 through April 30, 2005, and (b) May 1, 2005
through May 8, 2005. The PJM MMU states that on average, the hourly energy market was moderately
concentrated, both pre- and post-merger, during both periods. The post-merger increase in average
HHIs ranges from 290 to 301, and the average HHI in the post-merger market is between 1,537 and
1,643.74 The PJM MMU concludes that the proposed merger results in an increase in HHI
that exceeds that specified as raising concern in the Merger Guidelines. It states that the
proposed merger would significantly increase concentration in the energy market as defined by these
metrics and the standards of the Merger Guidelines and therefore raises concerns about potential
adverse competitive effects, absent mitigation.75 The PJM MMU states that the
divestiture of 4,500 MWh of generation would reduce the post-merger HHI levels to pre-merger
levels and that the divestiture of 2,600 MWh of generation would reduce the post-merger HHI levels
so that the increase is less than 100 points.
105. The PJM MMU states that in PJMs locational marginal pricing based market, transmission
constraints create smaller, locational markets with different structural characteristics than the
aggregate market. Thus, the PJM MMU examines the locational
|
|
|
72 |
|
In response to a request from the NJBPU, the
PJM MMU prepared a report and analysis of the proposed transactions
impact on the PJM wholesale markets (PJM MMU Study). The NJBPU filed the study
with the Commission making the PJM MMU Study part of the record. |
|
73 |
|
The MMU examined the energy markets
created when the Western, Central, and Eastern interfaces are constrained as
well as the smaller market created when the Keeney Transformer is constrained. |
|
74 |
|
PJM MMU Study at 12 and 14. |
|
75 |
|
Id. at 14. |
|
|
|
Docket No. EC05-43-000
|
|
36 |
markets created when the Western, Central, and Eastern interfaces are binding constraints. It also
examines the locational eastern market created when the Keeney 500/230 kilovolt (kV) transformer is
constrained. The PJM MMU states that it performed this analysis in a way that is fully consistent
with PJMs actual procedure for dispatching units to solve a constraint.76 The PJM MMU
notes that its analysis included only those units whose increased output would relieve the
constraint. That is, the PJM
MMU calculated the HHI based on the ownership of combustion turbine capacity that could relieve the
transmission constraint. It states that its approach is consistent with the Commissions approach
that looks at a variety of demand conditions.
106. The PJM MMU states that the Eastern interface pre-merger HHI is 2,593, but that this market is
structurally competitive because it passes PJMs three-pivotal-supplier test for market
concentration.77 It states that the merger would result in an HHI increase of 972
points and the failure of the three-pivotal-supplier test. The PJM MMU states that this harm to
competition could be mitigated by capping market offers when the Eastern interface market is not
competitive; by the merged company agreeing to offer power from units only at marginal cost (as
defined in the offer capping rules); or by adequate divestiture of generation by the merged
company. The PJM MMU states there is sufficient capacity in the list of candidate facilities to
return the post-merger HHI to pre-merger levels, but that it is not possible to state
definitively how many MW of capacity must be divested without knowing which units would be divested
and the purchasers of these units.78
107. The PJM MMU states that the Western interfaces pre-merger HHI is 1,552, and that this market
is structurally competitive because it passes the three-pivotal-supplier test for market
concentration. It states that the merger would result in an HHI increase of 240 points, but that
the market still passes the three-pivotal-supplier test. The PJM MMU concludes that the merger
nonetheless raises concerns about potential adverse competitive effects absent mitigation, because
it would significantly increase concentration in the Western interface market. The adverse
competitive impact of the merger could be mitigated by capping market offers when the Western
interface market is not competitive, an agreement of the merged company to offer units only at
marginal
|
|
|
76 |
|
Id. at 17. |
|
77 |
|
The MMU states that this conclusion is
consistent with the conclusion reached in the October 26, 2004 filing by the
MMU in Docket Nos. ER04-539-001, 002, and EL04-121-000. |
|
78 |
|
PJM MMU Study at 18 and 19. |
|
|
|
Docket No. EC05-43-000
|
|
37 |
cost, or adequate divestiture of generation by the merged company. The PJM MMU states that there
is sufficient capacity within the list of candidate facilities to return the post-merger HHI to
pre-merger levels, but that it is not possible to state definitively how many MW of capacity must
be divested without an exact specification of the units to be divested and the purchasers of these
units.79
108. The PJM MMU states that the Central interfaces pre-merger HHI is 1,870, but that this market
is structurally competitive because it passes the three-pivotal-supplier test for market
concentration. It states that the merger would result in an HHI increase of 479 points, but that
the market still passes the three-pivotal-supplier test. The PJM MMU concludes that the merger
nonetheless raises concerns about harm to competition because it would significantly increase
concentration in the Central interface market. This could be mitigated by capping market offers
when the Central interface market is not competitive, an agreement of the merged company to offer
units only at marginal cost, or adequate divestiture of generation by the merged company. The PJM
MMU reiterates there was sufficient capacity within the list of candidate facilities to return the
post-merger HHI to pre-merger levels, but that it is not possible to state definitively how many MW
of capacity must be divested without an exact specification of the units to be divested and the
purchasers of these units.80
109. The PJM MMU states that the Keeney transformer market pre-merger HHI is 3,004 and that this
market is not structurally competitive because it fails the three-pivotal-supplier test for market
concentration. It states that the merger would result in an HHI increase of 161 points. The PJM
MMU states that the adverse competitive impact of the merger could be mitigated by capping market
offers when the Eastern-interface market is not competitive, an agreement of the merged company to
offer units only at marginal cost (as defined in the offer capping rules), or adequate divestiture
of generation by the merged company. The PJM MMU states there is sufficient capacity in the list
of candidate facilities to return the post-merger HHI to pre-merger levels, but that it is not
possible to state definitively how many MW of capacity must be divested without an exact
specification of the units to be divested and the purchasers of these units.81
|
|
|
79 |
|
Id. at 20 and 21. |
|
80 |
|
Id. |
|
81 |
|
Id. at 18 and 19. |
|
|
|
Docket No. EC05-43-000
|
|
38 |
|
D. |
|
Responses by Protestors to Applicants Answer and to the PJM
MMU Study |
110. NJBPU argues that EE&Gs plant retirements should not result in a MW-for-MW reduction in the
amount of market power mitigation, because unlike divestiture, plant retirements do not create new
competitors. It also asserts that more information is required to determine whether the mitigation
plan is effective. Many different permutations of actual and virtual divestiture are possible, and
the Commission cannot evaluate the merits of all of them without an evidentiary hearing.
111. FirstEnergy argues that because transmission expansion is required by the PJM Regional
Transmission Expansion Plan, it cannot be considered market power mitigation. In addition, H-P
Energy argues that Applicants commitment of $25 million towards transmission expansion projects
may supplant transmission projects being built by merchant transmission companies. It further
states that Applicants are unfairly bypassing the PJM RTEP process.
112. Protestors continue to question some of the assumptions in Dr. Hieronymus analysis and argue
that the Applicants have offered mitigation based on inaccurate results that are favorable to
Applicants. Specifically, FirstEnergy and the PPL Companies argue that the market prices used for
electricity are still inaccurate. FirstEnergy further argues that what Applicants characterize as
FirstEnergys witness mistakes were actually mistakes in Dr. Hieronymus database, and that upon
correcting for Dr. Hieronymuss mistakes, the merger fails the HHI screens. The PPL Companies
argue that using actual FTR holdings to allocate imports to generators results in PJM-East market
concentration that is considerably higher than indicated by Dr. Hieronymus, and that Applicants
proposed divestiture is not sufficient to mitigate the harm to competition. FirstEnergy further
argues that lifting the restrictions on who can buy the units will result in an inadequate amount
of divestiture.
113. The PPL Companies argue that Applicants continue to ignore PJM Classic and Northern New Jersey
as relevant geographic markets. In addition, the PPL Companies assert that EE&G may have the
ability and incentive to shut down nuclear units to drive up energy prices. It says that
Applicants did not address the effect of the proposed merger on PJMs three-pivotal supplier rule.
|
E. |
|
Applicants Answer to Protestors Responses and Comments on
the PJM MMU Study |
114. Applicants reply that the PJM MMU Study confirms the validity of their analysis. They read
the PJM MMU Study as concluding that the proposed merger raises market power issues, but that the
Applicants proposed mitigation can resolve them. Applicants note that the PJM MMU did not perform
an Appendix A analysis, and advise the
|
|
|
Docket No. EC05-43-000
|
|
39 |
Commission not to rely on the PJM MMU Study as a substitute for one. Applicants note that their
own Appendix A analysis shows that there are no screen violations after divestiture, so the
Commission can find that the transaction will not harm competition without considering the PJM MMU
Study. Applicants do, however, believe that the PJM MMU Study confirms Dr. Hieronymus analysis in
two important respects: (1) the PJM MMU Study reaches results similar to those reached by Dr.
Hieronymus regarding the state of the markets studied before and after the proposed merger, and (2)
the PJM MMU concludes that it is possible to implement the mitigation proposed by the Applicants to
address the market power issues associated with the proposed merger, depending on the units
divested and who buys them.82
115. With respect to point (2) above, Applicants argue that the need to identify the units to be
divested and the purchasers of the capacity (before concluding that the transaction addresses
market power concerns) can be met without further analysis or a hearing. It is not possible to
identify the purchasers of the generation at present. Applicants commit to make a filing when they
implement their divestiture in order to demonstrate, based on the specifics of the divested units
and purchasers, that no material Appendix A screen violations will occur as a result of the
divestiture.83 Applicants state that the fact that the units it included as its
divestiture candidates can return the markets to their pre-merger state should give the Commission
confidence that their proposed divestiture of 1,200 MW of peaking generation can adequately
mitigate screen failures in the PJM MMUs energy submarkets.84
116. Applicants criticize the PPL Companies supplemental affidavit from Dr. Kalt. They state that
the affidavit does not respond to their May 9 Answer, that there is no reason Dr. Kalt could not
have performed his analysis and included it in his original comments, and that Dr. Kalts analysis
is easily dismissed because Financial Transmission Rights do not provide the holder with any
physical right to import power.85
|
|
|
82 |
|
Comments and Answer of Exelon at 6. |
|
83 |
|
Id. at 7. |
|
84 |
|
Id. at 9. |
|
85 |
|
Id. at 12. |
|
|
|
Docket No. EC05-43-000
|
|
40 |
117. Likewise,
Applicants state that FirstEnergys supplemental affidavit from Ms. Frayer
presents a new study of the effect of the merger on energy markets that does not respond to the
Applicants revised mitigation proposal. They state that Ms. Frayer analyzed a higher price for
various market conditions, thus including more generation in her analysis than did Dr. Hieronymus.
However, Ms. Frayer neglected to take into account, when assessing Applicants mitigation proposal,
additional divested generation that is economic at higher prices. Applicants conclude that this
results in a systematic understatement of the effectiveness of the mitigation they offer.
118. Applicants respond to FirstEnergys and the PPL Companies claim that Applicants commitment
to fund additional transmission expansion projects is just a commitment to do what they are already
required to do under PJMs Regional Transmission Planning Process. They point out that one of the
projects to which they commit is on the list of projects required by the Regional Transmission
Planning Process, but that they are committing to accelerate the project so that it will be in
service a year earlier than required by the Regional Transmission Planning Process. Applicants
note that the other projects they propose are or will be on PJMs Economic Project list and that
transmission owners are under no obligation to go forward with projects on this list.86
In response to concerns raised by H-P Energy that the Applicants may fund projects that H-P
Energy already is pursuing, Applicants commit to not attempt to supplant any of the three projects
identified by H-P Energy.87
Discussion
119. Pursuant to Rule 214 of the Commissions Rules of Practice and Procedure, 18 C.F.R. §
385.214 (2004), the timely, unopposed motions to intervene serve to make the entities that filed
them parties to the proceeding. We will grant Allegheny Electric, H-P Energy and the Indiana
Utility Regulatory Commissions motions to intervene out-of-time, since we find that doing so will
not unduly disrupt the proceeding or place an undue burden on the parties. Rule 213(a)(2) of the
Commissions Rules of Practice and Procedure, 18 C.F.R. § 385.213(a)(2) (2004), prohibits an answer
to a protest unless otherwise ordered by the decisional authority. We will accept the answers
filed herein because they have provided information that assisted us in our decision-making
process.
|
|
|
86 |
|
Id. at 18. |
|
87 |
|
Applicants Answer 2 at p. 19. |
|
|
|
Docket No. EC05-43-000
|
|
41 |
120. Applicants have shown that the merger, with the mitigation proposed, will not harm competition
in any relevant energy market. We find that Applicants revised mitigation proposal, which
increases the total mitigation from 5,500 to 6,600 MW and removes almost all of the restrictions on
who can buy the assets, addresses the competitive concerns raised by intervenors.
A. Adequacy of Applicants Analysis
121. Applicants have corrected the factual errors in their original analysis that commenters
identified. This does not materially alter the results. We note that none of the protestors that
identified the factual errors in Applicants original analysis argue that Applicants did not
correct those errors.
122. We are not convinced by Applicants argument that Northern New Jersey is not a relevant
geographic market. As noted by the PHI Companies and others, there are times when transmission
constraints bind, leaving Northern New Jersey isolated from the rest of PJM-East. However, we
agree with Applicants that, during those periods, the merger would not harm competition because
Exelon does not have any generating facilities that would be combined with PSE&Gs existing
generation in that load pocket. We note that there are times when imports from the rest of PJM
East, where Exelon does own significant generating resources, would result in a merger-related
increase in concentration due to Exelons share of the pro rata transmission allocation. In those
cases, there are screen failures in the Northern PSEG market. We note Applicants have committed to
mitigate all screen failures. We also note that Dr. Hieronymus testimony indicates that a 100 MW
divestiture of generation capacity located in Northern PSE&G, along with the proposed mitigation
for the PJM East market, is necessary to fully mitigate the merger-related increase in market
concentration in Northern PSE&G. While Applicants have not explicitly committed to divesting 100
MW of generation located within Northern PSE&G, we consider the two statements above to be a
commitment to do so, and we rely on that commitment in finding that the merger will not adversely
affect competition in the Northern PSE&G wholesale electricity market.88.
123. We reject arguments that PJM-Classic should be considered a separate relevant geographic
market within PJM Pre-2004. We note that the PJM MMU report does not consider PJM-Classic as a
separate market, and no one has shown that there are frequent binding transmission constraints that
isolate PJM-Classic from the rest of PJM Pre-2004.
|
|
|
Docket No. EC05-43-000
|
|
42 |
124. We also reject arguments that PJM-West should be considered a separate geographic market. The
critical issue in defining geographic markets is identifying the sellers who can physically and
economically compete in the market. Given that the binding transmission constraints within PJM are
predominantly west-to-east, it is reasonable to model PJM-East as a separate market within PJM, but
not necessary to model PJM-West as a separate market because suppliers from all of PJM are able to
sell into PJM-West.
125. Applicants have adequately addressed the protests concerning the fuel cost and wholesale
market price assumptions in their analysis of energy markets. Dr.
Hieronymus fuel cost and market price assumptions are consistent in that the assumed market price
corresponds with the running costs of the units most likely to set the market-clearing price in the
PJM energy markets for the given season-load conditions. We agree with Applicants that the fact
that Dr. Hieronymus and Mr. Frame used different fuel cost and market price assumptions, but
arrived at very similar results, indicates that the results are not sensitive to changes in fuel
cost and market price assumptions. Moreover, the consistency of Dr. Hieronymus results across
various assumed market prices shows that the results of the analysis are robust.89 In
addition, the PJM MMU Study largely confirms the accuracy of Applicants results, finding similar
pre-merger and post-merger concentration levels.
126. Applicants appropriately accounted for generation entry and exit in their analysis. They used
publicly available data from PJM covering the 2006 test year and included retirements and new plant
entries that are reasonably expected to occur in 2005 and 2006. In OG&E, we noted that we will
consider foreseeable and reasonably certain changes in market conditions as part of the baseline
scenario.90 Applicants have met that standard in their analysis.
127. Applicants and intervenors modeled various scenarios regarding who buys the divested assets.
As noted by numerous protestors, as well as the PJM MMU Study, the effectiveness of Applicants
proposed divestiture depends critically on the distribution of the buyers and their pre-existing
presence as sellers in the PJM markets. Applicants initially addressed this issue by putting
restrictions on the pool of eligible buyers and the
|
|
|
89 |
|
For example, using Economic Capacity in
PJM-East, under assumed prices ranging from $55 to $80, the merger-related
change in concentration ranges from 860 to 1,113 HHI and Applicants
proposed divestiture of 4,500 MW of Economic Capacity returns the concentration
to within 100 HHI of the pre-merger level. See Supplemental Hieronymus
testimony, Exhibit J-28 p 1. |
|
90 |
|
OG&E at P 32. |
|
|
|
Docket No. EC05-43-000
|
|
43 |
amount of the divested capacity that any one purchaser can acquire. However, many protestors
argued that such restrictions could harm the competitive process and could even allow Applicants to
gain a dominant position in PJM by having only smaller, weaker competitors.
128. The parties raise valid issues on both sides of this argument. We find that Applicants
elimination of the restrictions on eligible buyers addresses protestors concerns about harming the
competitive process by freezing out some of the possible or likely purchasers of the assets.
However, we need to be sure that, at the conclusion of the divestiture, competition has been
restored to its pre-merger level, for the merger to be consistent with the public interest.
Therefore, in addition to our section 203 review of the individual divestiture transactions, at the
end of the divestiture process Applicants must make a compliance filing in this docket and we will
review the results to be sure that concentration in the affected markets is close to pre-merger
levels. If the analysis shows that the mergers harm to competition has not been sufficiently
mitigated, we will require additional mitigation at that time. We will direct Applicants to make a
compliance filing within 30 days of the closing of the final divestiture, with an Appendix A
analysis showing the post-merger-and-divestiture market concentration levels for economic capacity
in all relevant markets.
129. We are not persuaded by arguments that Applicants should have used an economic (i.e. least
cost) allocation rather than a pro rata allocation of scarce transmission transfer capability in
their analysis. We have accepted the pro rata allocation methodology in numerous merger cases, and
believe it reasonably models suppliers ability to compete in a given destination market.
Moreover, in Order No. 642, we stated:
A variety of allocation methods are possible, and the Commission has acknowledged
that certain methods provide more accurate and reasonable results than others (i.e.,
pro-rata as opposed to least-cost). Applicants must describe and support the method
used and show the resulting transfer capability allocation.91
Here, Applicants have described and supported their transmission allocation
methodology.92
|
|
|
91 |
|
Order No. 642 at 31,894. |
|
92 |
|
See Application Exhibit J-4 at p. 9. |
|
|
|
Docket No. EC05-43-000
|
|
44 |
130. Protestors raise a number of issues regarding Applicants Available Economic Capacity
analysis. We agree with protestors and Applicants that in analyzing wholesale markets in retail
choice states such as New Jersey and Pennsylvania, the native load deduction for the Available
Economic Capacity calculation is difficult to assess. We have stated, in a number of contexts that
as states move toward retail competition, native load obligations may change so that it is part of
a broader set of contractual obligations, and we encourage applicants to test the sensitivity of
the Available Economic Capacity results to changes in the native load assumptions.93
Here, Applicants have analyzed Available Economic Capacity under two different assumptions of the
native load obligation and reported similar results: moderately concentrated markets with screen
failures under most season/load conditions. Most importantly, in all time periods, the divestiture
proposed to address the screen failures identified in the Economic Capacity analysis more than
offsets the increase in concentration shown in the Available Economic Capacity analysis. We
conclude that Applicants have shown that the merger, as mitigated, will not harm competition when
Available Economic Capacity is used to measure suppliers ability to compete in those markets.
131. We are not convinced by arguments that Applicants should have analyzed the mergers effect on
their ability and incentive to harm competition by engaging in strategic bidding (which is a form
of unilateral market power). The Commissions analysis focuses on a mergers effect on competitive
conditions in the market. That is, we look at the mergers effect on the concentration of the
relevant markets, as measured by the HHI. Protestors argue that the HHI solely looks for the
possibility of the coordinated exercise of market power and misses the possibility of the
unilateral exercise of market power. They say that Applicants have not shown that the merger will
not increase the likelihood of the merged firm exercising unilateral market power. We reject this
argument for two reasons. First, the Merger Guidelines recognize that the HHI does, in fact,
convey information about the likelihood of the unilateral exercise of market power.94
Second, in order to address the screen failures in various season/load conditions, Applicants have
proposed divesting units with a range of operational and cost characteristics, including the types
of units that protestors argue could be used to engage in strategic bidding or withholding in order
to exercise unilateral market power.
|
|
|
93 |
|
See Order No. 642 at 31,888. |
|
94 |
|
Section 2.0 of the Merger Guidelines. |
|
|
|
Docket No. EC05-43-000
|
|
45 |
Furthermore, such strategic bidding or withholding could qualify as market manipulation under the
Market Behavioral Rule #295 and result in, among other things, revocation of
market-based rate authority.
132. Protestors argue that Applicants have erroneously interpreted the Commissions HHI screen as
an absolute standard for merger authorization and, thus have offered mitigation that is focused
solely on passing the screen, rather than on mitigating the merger-related harm to competition. We
agree with protestors that the mitigation needs to preserve competition, not necessarily to restore
the HHIs to avoid screen violations. There are a number of ways to mitigate increases in market
power (e.g. generation divestiture, transmission expansion, or behavioral measures such as
must-offer requirements), and we have imposed various forms of market power mitigation depending on
the circumstances. Applicants proposal to divest sufficient capacity to reduce market
concentration to within the screening tolerance for increases from the pre-merger concentration
level is one reasonable way to mitigate the merger-related harm to competition.96 As
stated above, the HHI conveys information about the likelihood of both the coordinated and
unilateral exercise of market power. By restoring the HHI to near pre-merger levels, Applicants
will restore competition to the pre-merger level, and meet their burden to show that the merger, as
mitigated, will not harm competition in wholesale energy markets.
B. Adequacy of Applicants Proposed Mitigation
133. We are not convinced by FirstEnergys arguments that Applicants proposed divestiture does not
sufficiently mitigate the merger-related increase in market power. In both studies,
FirstEnergys witness, Ms. Frayer, understated the amount of the proposed mitigation in various
seasons because she assumed a lower price in the mitigation scenario than in the
post-merger-without-mitigation scenario, thus not giving credit for some of the units being
divested. In short, divested units that were economic were incorrectly considered uneconomic
by Ms. Frayer.
|
|
|
95 |
|
Market Behavior Rules, 105 FERC ¶
61,218 (2003) Order on Rehg, 107 FERC ¶ 61,175 (2004) Rule # 2.E
bidding the output of or misrepresenting the operational capabilities of
generation facilities in a manner which raises market prices by withholding
available supply from the market. |
|
96 |
|
We note that Applicants analysis of
the post-merger-and-mitigation market concentration shows one season/load
condition for the PJM-East energy market where the change HHI is large enough
to fail the Competitive Analysis Screen. As we have said in other merger
cases, we do not find that borderline, non-systematic screen failures
necessarily indicate harm to competition. |
|
|
|
Docket No. EC05-43-000
|
|
46 |
134. Protestors raise numerous issues regarding the effectiveness of Applicants proposed virtual
divestiture of 2,600 MW of energy from nuclear capacity. In particular, many protestors argue that
the Commission should only accept actual, physical divesture as effective mitigation. However, as
stated above, there are a number of possible effective market power mitigation tools, and we have
recognized that different options can be reasonable for a given set of circumstances. We have
recognized that operational control of generation resources is a key element of market power
analysis and mitigation.97 Here, the virtual divesture effectively transfers control of
the output of 2,600 MW of nuclear capacity from the merged firm to the purchasers. That is, the
merged firm cannot withhold the energy from the market and the buyer of the firm rights, not the
seller, determines where and to whom the energy is ultimately sold. Applicants have committed to
sell all of the energy that is offered, regardless of the price of the bids, and that an
independent auction monitor will oversee Applicants compliance with that commitment. Moreover,
the liquidated damages provisions in the contracts, reduce the merged firms incentive to withhold
output to drive up wholesale energy prices because it would be contractually obligated to pay the
cost of any price increase. In effect, the virtual divestiture is a must-offer provision that
removes the ability to withhold output, along with a contractual provision that reduces the
incentive to withhold output in order to affect market outcomes. As we have said in numerous
contexts, we are concerned about a mergers effect on the merged firms ability and incentive to
harm competition.98 Furthermore, as a condition of the Commissions approval,
Applicants must agree that, if the virtual divestiture does not in fact mitigate the problems
identified, Applicants will propose to the Commission mitigation that will mitigate the problems
identified.
135. Protestors also object to the virtual divesture on the grounds that it will be difficult to
monitor. For example, AAI notes that the antitrust agencies prefer physical divestiture because it
removes the need for ongoing monitoring. We recognize that concern, but find two critical factors
supporting virtual divesture as a reasonable alternative to physical divestiture. First, as we
have stated in a number of cases, the operational characteristics of, and regulatory scrutiny over,
nuclear units virtually eliminate the possibility of withholding output to drive up
prices.99 Second, Applicants have committed to establish an independent monitor to
oversee the auction itself and Applicants compliance with the contracts, and Applicants will
establish a public compliance website that will show how
|
|
|
97 |
|
See, e.g., Order No. 642 at n. 39. |
|
98 |
|
See, e.g., Order No. 642 at 94. |
|
99 |
|
Commonwealth Edison Co., 91 FERC ¶ 61,036 (2000). |
|
|
|
Docket No. EC05-43-000
|
|
47 |
they are complying with the virtual divestiture and other mitigation requirements. We rely on
those commitments in our finding that the virtual divestiture effectively mitigates the
merger-related harm to competition. We will direct Applicants to make a compliance filing within
30 days of this order, detailing the process for the selection of the independent monitor.
136. We reject arguments that Applicants may have market power in the three-year and 15-year
contract markets and that they may retain control of the contracts through the New Jersey Basic
Generation Service auction. First, the Commission has determined that long-term capacity markets,
absent specified entry barriers, are inherently competitive.100 No protestor has raised
compelling evidence that there are significant entry barriers in the PJM markets. Second, if
Applicants attempted to withhold from the three-year contract market by selling only the 15-year
contracts, as hypothesized by Ameren, the purchasers of the 15-year contracts would have an
incentive to sell three-year contracts in response to any price increase. Regarding the PHI
Companies argument about the New Jersey Basic Generation Service auction, Applicants have designed
the three-year baseload energy auctions to support sales into the Basic Generation Service auction,
but the buyers of the three-year baseload energy products will control the energy and can therefore
resell them into the Basic Generation Service auction, or in some other manner. The fact that the
buyers of the three-year baseload energy products may be likely to resell the energy into the New
Jersey Basic Generation Service auction does not imply that the Applicants will regain control of
the energy.
137. We reject FirstEnergys assertion that Applicants will receive the same price for the
virtually divested energy as they would have in the absence of mitigation. First, as argued by
Applicants, under the virtual divestiture plan, Applicants will receive the price determined in the
auction for the three-year life of each contract, whereas if they retained control of the output of
the nuclear units, they would be able to benefit from any market price increases during the same
three-year period. Second, by giving up control of
|
|
|
100 |
|
Promoting Wholesale Competition Through
Open Access Non-discriminatory Transmission Services by Public Utilities and
Transmitting Utilities, Order No. 888, FERC Stats. & Regs., Regulations
Preambles January 1991-June 1996 ¶ 31,036 (1996), order on rehg,
Order No. 888-A, FERC Stats. & Regs., Regulations Preambles July 1996-December
2000 ¶ 31,048 (1997), order on rehg, Order No. 888-B, 81 FERC
¶ 61,248 (1997), order on rehg, Order No. 888-C, 82 FERC
¶ 61,046 (1998), affd in relevant part sub nom. Transmission
Access Policy Study Group v. FERC, 225 F.3d 667 (D.C. Cir. 2000), affd
sub nom. New York v. FERC, 535 U.S. 1 (2002). |
|
|
|
Docket No. EC05-43-000
|
|
48 |
6,600 MW of through the divestiture and virtual divestiture, Applicants have adequately mitigated
the merger-related increase in market power. Therefore, they would not be able to raise the price
of energy by other means, as the previous contracts expire, in order to raise the price they
receive for the three-year contracts.
138. Protestors have argued that, the proposed energy swaps could harm competition in other
geographic markets. Any such energy swaps will require section 203 authorization, and we will
review the effect on competition in those proceedings. We note that swaps with suppliers in
markets adjacent to PJM, such as MISO or the New York ISO, might not warrant a MW-for-MW reduction
in the mitigation amount because Applicants would get control of capacity that could sell into PJM,
subject to transmission constraints. In such cases, the MW reduction in Applicants mitigation
amount would be reduced by the merged firms pro rata share of the import capability into PJM.
139. Likewise, we reject arguments regarding this mergers possible effect on future mergers.
Future mergers will require section 203 authorizations, and we will review the effect on
competition in those proceedings. We note, without prejudice to any future proceedings, that
Applicants divestiture plan will restore the concentration level in the relevant markets to within
100 HHI of the pre-merger level, so there will be little effect on future mergers.
140. The PHI Companies say that the three year baseload auction energy sales might not continue
over the proposed 15-year period. In response, Applicants commit that the entire Baseload
Mitigation Amount of nuclear virtual divestiture (2600 MW) will remain in place after 15 years,
subject to a reduction in the mitigation amount if the Applicants PJM East nuclear capacity is
decommissioned, derated, or sold or there is construction of new transmission transfer capability
into PJM East. Therefore, Applicants have adequately addressed the PHI Companies concerns
regarding the duration of the baseload auction energy sales.
141. A number of protestors argue that the Merger Policy Statement requires Applicants to identify
the specific units that will be divested. In response, Applicants argue that while they cannot now
identify the exact units, they do identify the location and the types of generation to be divested
and the pool of generators eligible to buy. In addition, the PJM MMU states that without knowing
the exact units and the buyers of those units, it could not make a meaningful assessment of the
effectiveness of the proposed divestiture, and a supplemental analysis must be performed once a
definitive declaration of the divested assets has been developed.101 While the Merger
Policy
|
|
|
Docket No. EC05-43-000
|
|
49 |
Statement does state that applicants must identify the specific units to be divested,102
in this instance, we find Applicants proposal sufficient because the divestiture can adequately
mitigate the merger-related harm to competition; moreover, once the specific units have been
identified, we will be able to ensure that they are appropriate units to make divestiture effective
through the subsequent compliance filing discussed above. Finally, establishing a pool of
generation eligible for divestiture, rather than specifying exact units, addresses protestors
reverse cherry picking argument that Exelon will divest its least valuable units, rather than
creating viable competitors by divesting the efficient units. Establishing a pool of generation
eligible for divestiture allows the potential buyers of the plants to bid on the ones that they
most highly value.
142. We note that, because of the way the PJM MMU did its analysis (using unit-specific historical
energy sales and calculating HHIs for units that can relieve internal PJM constraints), it did need
to know the exact plants that are going to be divested in order to assess the effectiveness of the
proposed divestiture. However, under the Commissions Appendix A analysis, we need to know the
general location (i.e. control area or sub-region of an RTO) and cost characteristics of the
generators being divested not the actual units in order to calculate the
post-merger-and-divestiture HHIs. Applicants have provided that information and shown that, based
on reasonable assumptions about the buyers of the assets, the post-merger-and-mitigation HHIs are
sufficiently close to the pre-merger HHIs to mitigate the merger-related harm to competition.
Moreover, Applicants have committed to provide an Appendix A analysis of the mergers effect on
competition, based on the actual acquirers of the actual divested assets, once they are known. We
rely on that commitment in making our finding that the divestiture adequately mitigates any
merger-related harm to competition in the relevant energy markets. If the analysis shows that the
mergers harm to competition has not been sufficiently mitigated, we will require additional
mitigation at that time, pursuant to our authority under FPA.
143. We find that Applicants proposed MW-for-MW reduction of the amount of the baseload energy
mitigation is reasonable. As stated earlier in this order, there are a number of reasonable market
power remedies, including divesture and transmission expansion and we have relied on those remedies
based on the circumstances before us. We agree with Applicants that offsets to the baseload
mitigation amount for increases in transmission transfer capability into PJM East are reasonable
because increasing transfer capability into PJM-East would enable competitive suppliers to defeat
attempts by generators in PJM East to drive up prices by withholding output. In fact, in OG&E, we
found that a transmission expansion was a reasonable form of mitigation for the increase
|
|
|
102 |
|
We note that the Merger Policy Statement is not binding as a statute or regulation. |
|
|
|
Docket No. EC05-43-000
|
|
50 |
in market power associated with OG&Es acquisition of a rival generator.103 Applicants
have also made a convincing argument that a decrease in their nuclear capacity, whether through
divestiture, de-rating, or unit retirement, would mitigate market power, because the incentive to
withhold output is an increasing function of the amount of baseload capacity from which the merged
firm could profit due to higher energy prices. Therefore, by reducing the amount of baseload
capacity they control, they reduce their incentive to withhold marginal capacity in order to raise
the market price.
144. We find that the amount of interim mitigation, along with Applicants variable cost bid caps
for the mid-merit and peaking units, mitigates the merger-related harm to competition in the
relevant energy markets. First, Applicants will offer the same amount of capacity in their interim
mitigation (4,000 MW of fossil and 2,600 MW of nuclear) as in their proposed physical and virtual
divestiture, which, as we explained above, adequately mitigates the merger-related harm to
competition. Second, the commitment to bid the fossil units at variable cost eliminates the
ability to harm competition by strategic bidding or economic withholding. In addition, we find
that the Cassidy Testimony describing the amount of the dispatch rights; the rights afforded the
purchasers of the capacity; the terms of the master agreement for the sales; the price of the
energy and capacity; the timing and duration of the interim sales; and any associated rollover
provisions, adequately describes the proposal. We rely on Applicants commitment to establish a
public compliance web site that will show how they are complying with the
virtual divestiture and all other mitigation requirements, including the interim mitigation plan,
and require that the interim mitigation be in place upon consummation of the merger.
145. We reject arguments that we should address in this proceeding whether Applicants will pass the
Commissions market-based rates screen. Any issues regarding Applicants generation market
dominance will be addressed in the pending proceeding on Exelons triennial review filing, and in
future similar proceedings.
146. NiSources concerns about loop flows are related to ComEds participation in the PJM RTO and
power flows between the Midwest ISO and PJM, not to the merger. Therefore we will address
NiSources issues regarding loop flows in the proceeding under Docket No. EL05-103.
|
|
|
|
|
|
Docket No. EC05-43-000
|
|
51 |
147. We agree with FirstEnergys argument that transmission expansion that is required by the PJM
Regional Transmission Expansion Plan should not be considered market power mitigation. As we
stated in OG&E, changes in market conditions that are foreseeable and reasonably certain to occur
are not mitigation.104 Transmission upgrades, depending on where they fall in the PJM
Regional Transmission Planning Process queue, can be foreseeable and reasonably certain to occur,
and thus might not be considered mitigation. However, although we will accept Applicants
transmission commitments, we are not relying on them in our finding that Applicants proposed
mitigation adequately addresses the merger-related harm to competition. Rather we are relying on
Applicants proposed sale of 6,600 MW of capacity to mitigate the merger-related harm to
competition. As stated above, we will allow offsets to the baseload mitigation amount specifically
for transmission expansions that increase import capability into PJM-East. At this time,
Applicants have not proposed any new projects that would expand import capability into PJM-East.
In order to grant an offset of the baseload mitigation amount, we will require Applicants to make a
showing that any transmission upgrades would increase transfer capability into PJM-East, and that
they were not foreseeable and reasonably certain as of June 2005. H-P Energy argues that
Applicants commitment of $25 million towards transmission expansion projects may supplant
transmission projects being built by merchant transmission companies. Applicants have addressed
that concern, in part, by committing not to attempt to supplant any of the three projects
identified by H-P Energy. In addition, we note that the PJM Regional Transmission Expansion Plan
process identifies numerous transmission projects
that could be undertaken by merchant transmission providers as well as other transmission providers
and generators looking for interconnection. There are considerably more projects identified than
undertaken in a given year. Therefore, we accept Applicants commitment to fund $25 million of
transmission expansion projects and their commitment to avoid supplanting any of the H-P Energy
identified projects. To avoid supplanting any other bidder seeking to fund any other project on
PJMs list of Economic Projects over the next five years, Applicants are required to bid only on
those projects identified but not undertaken by any other entity. Additionally, we will require
that Applicants follow all other procedures under the PJM Regional Transmission Expansion Plan for
any transmission expansion projects.
148. Regarding FirstEnergys argument that Applicants have not demonstrated that their proposed
internal corporate restructuring is consistent with the public interest, we note that, absent
concerns about transfers of generation assets from unregulated merchant generating companies to
regulated franchised utilities we expressed in Cinergy105 and
|
|
|
104 |
|
Id. |
|
105 |
|
Cinergy Services Inc., et al., 102 FERC
¶ 62,128 at 63,345 (2003). |
|
|
|
|
|
|
Docket No. EC05-43-000
|
|
52 |
Ameren106, the Commission has held that internal reorganizations will not result in harm
to competition.107 Here, Applicants have committed that there will be no transfers of
generation assets from unregulated merchant generating companies to regulated franchised utilities.
We rely on that commitment in finding that that internal corporate restructuring will not result
in any harm to competition in any relevant market. In addition, as discussed infra, Applicants
have committed to hold wholesale customers harmless from any merger-related costs so the internal
reorganization will not adversely affect wholesale rates. Moreover, the internal restructuring
will not adversely affect this Commissions or any state commissions ability to regulate the
merged company. Therefore, we find that Applicants have shown that their proposed internal
corporate restructuring is consistent with the public interest.
C. Capacity Markets
149. Dr. Hieronymus also analyzed the effect of the merger on capacity markets in PJM-East and
Expanded PJM. For PJM-East, he assumed the same 7,300 MW import capability as in his analysis of economic capacity. He reports that Exelons and PSE&Gs
pre-merger shares of capacity in PJM-East are 18 and 25 percent respectively and that the merger
would increase market concentration from 1,282 to 2,196 HHI, well above the Commissions screening
threshold for highly concentrated markets. For Expanded PJM, he assumed the same 7,500 MW import
capability as in his analysis of economic capacity. He reports that Exelons and PSE&Gs
pre-merger shares of capacity in Expanded PJM are 15 and 8 percent respectively and that the merger
would increase market concentration from 799 to 1,044 HHI, above the Commissions screening
threshold for moderately concentrated markets. He states that Applicants need to divest 5,300 MW
of capacity in PJM-East to eliminate the screen failures and restore market competition to the
pre-merger level.108
|
|
|
106 |
|
Ameren Energy at 61,142. |
|
107 |
|
See Order No. 642 at 31,902. |
|
108 |
|
Dr. Hieronymus finds that because PJM
East is located within Expanded PJM, the capacity divestiture in PJM East would
be effective mitigation for Expanded PJM and sufficiently reduce market
concentration. |
|
|
|
|
|
|
Docket No. EC05-43-000
|
|
53 |
150. PSE&Gs witness, Mr. Frame, analyzed the effect of the merger on competition in PJM-East and
capacity markets. For PJM-East, he assumes the same 7,300 MW import capability as in his analysis
of economic capacity. He reports that Exelons and PSE&Gs pre-merger shares of capacity in
PJM-East are 16.8 and 24.0 percent, respectively, and that the merger would increase market
concentration from 1,127 to 1,932 HHI, well above the Commissions screening threshold for highly
concentrated markets. For capacity markets, he assumed the same 7,500 MW import capability. He
reports that Exelons and PSE&Gs pre-merger shares of capacity in Expanded PJM are 15.0 and 8.0
percent respectively and that the merger would increase market concentration from 687 to 926 HHI,
within the Commissions screening threshold for moderately concentrated markets.
151. As described above, Applicants commit to divest 2,900 MW of capacity in PJM-East in order
to address the peak and screen failures identified in the analysis of economic capacity in
PJM-East. Therefore, they state that they will need to mitigate an additional 2,400 MW of
capacity, which they refer to as the Capacity Mitigation Amount. Applicants propose bidding into
the PJM monthly and annual Planning Year capacity auctions the lesser of the Capacity Mitigation
Amount or the entire net Unforced Capacity Position in PJM less 100 MW.109
152. Applicants note that PJM is restructuring its capacity market, which may change relevant
geographic capacity markets that could be affected by the merger. They commit to make a filing
with the Commission 30 days after the closing of the merger in which they will make any necessary
adjustments to their capacity market mitigation and will demonstrate the effect of that mitigation
on PJMs restructured capacity markets.
153. Exelons witness, Dr. Hieronymus, analyzes the effect of the merger, given Applicants
proposed capacity mitigation, and finds that the merger does not harm competition in the PJM
capacity markets. For PJM-East, with mitigation, market concentration is 1,380, within 100 HHI of
the pre-merger concentration, within the Commissions tolerance for moderately concentrated
markets. For Expanded PJM, with mitigation, the capacity market is unconcentrated. Dr. Hieronymus
concludes that Applicants proposed mitigation eliminates any harm to competition indicated by the
screen failures in his analysis of PJM capacity markets.
|
|
|
109 |
|
Applicants explain that they may not have
the full 2,400 MW available to bid into the PJM-East capacity market because
the capacity might otherwise be committed. They state that they need to retain
a small amount of uncommitted capacity in order to hedge the risk of
fluctuations in their POLR obligation. Application at 39. |
|
|
|
|
|
|
Docket No. EC05-43-000
|
|
54 |
154. PSE&Gs witness, Mr. Frame, also finds that the proposed mitigation would eliminate the harm
to competition in PJM capacity markets indicated by the screen failures. In his analysis of the
PJM-East capacity market, he concludes that 4,614 MW of capacity would need to be divested in
PJM-East and that no divestiture is necessary in Expanded PJM in order to restore market
concentration to within the Commissions tolerance level. Therefore, he finds that the proposed
5,300 MW of capacity mitigation more than offsets the harm to competition resulting from the
merger.
155. FirstEnergy argues that Applicants would own around 60 percent of the capacity and they could
use that capacity to raise prices and otherwise exercise market power. Therefore, FirstEnergy
states that that the Commission should direct Applicants to file an analysis of the effects of the
forthcoming capacity markets, which are subject to redesign by PJM, and explain how Applicants
proposed mitigation will effectively deter the exercise of market power in those markets. In the
alternative to a follow-up filing, FirstEnergy states that the Commission should set this matter
for hearing.
156. First Energys witness, Ms. Frayer, also reviewed and assessed Applicants proposed capacity
market mitigation, and concluded that Applicants proposal is inadequate to mitigate their
post-merger market power in PJM capacity markets. Ms. Frayer finds that Applicants would
need to divest up to an additional 4,650 MW (above the 2,900 MW that Applicants have committed to
divest) to mitigate market power in the PJM-Expanded capacity market, after the commencement of the
single capacity market in June 2005. She also finds that Applicants would need to divest up to an
additional 2,721 MW (above the 2,900 MW that Applicants have committed to divest) to mitigate
market power in the PJM-East capacity market, after the establishment of local capacity markets.
157. Regarding Applicants proposed capacity market mitigation, protestors argued that despite
their commitment to bid up to 2,400 MW of capacity into the PJM daily capacity auction at a zero
price, Applicants could still have incentive to withhold any other capacity in order to drive up
the market-clearing price. In response, Applicants have committed to bid all of their uncommitted
capacity at zero, which, they assert, will remove any economic incentive they may have had to
withhold capacity in order to increase the market clearing price.
|
|
|
|
|
|
Docket No. EC05-43-000
|
|
55 |
158. The PJM MMU stated that it analyzed the aggregate capacity market as well as defined
locational capacity markets. It analyzed the aggregate capacity market using actual market data
and total capacity. It analyzed locational capacity markets using total and incremental capacity,
where incremental capacity includes only those units whose increased output would relieve the
relevant transmission constraint. The PJM MMU notes that the structure of the capacity market
makes for an extremely inelastic demand curve for capacity, and one needs to account for this fact
in an analysis of the competitive impacts of the proposed merger.
159. The PJM MMU found the pre-merger PJM capacity credit markets to exhibit moderate levels of
concentration in the daily capacity credit market and high levels of concentration in the monthly
and multimonthly capacity credit markets. It found the average HHI for the daily capacity credit
market to be 1,233 with a minimum of 820 and a maximum of 2,500. HHIs for the longer term monthly
and multimonthly capacity credit markets averaged 2,125 with a minimum of 841 and a maximum of
4,151. The PJM MMU found the post-merger HHI in the daily capacity credit market to average
1,389, an increase of 156 points from the pre-merger value. Post-merger HHIs for the monthly and
multi-monthly capacity credit market averaged 2,149, for an increase of 24 points from the
pre-merger average.
160. The PJM MMU also evaluated the market structure for total capacity in the aggregate PJM
market, and the PJM East and PJM Mid-Atlantic regional capacity markets. The results showed that
the merger caused HHI increases of 314 and 241 points for the Total PJM pre- and
post-Dominion markets, respectively, 501 for the PJM Mid-Atlantic market, and 1,120 to 1,810 points
for the PJM East market, depending on assumptions made for imports. The results also showed that
post-merger market concentration is moderate in total PJM and PJM Mid-Atlantic, and high in PJM
East, and that there is a single pivotal supplier in every case.
161. The PJM MMU states that, given the potential for a locational capacity market in eastern PJM,
it performed an additional analysis for this market to more accurately reflect the incremental way
in which a locational capacity market would clear. The results of the locational incremental
analysis for eastern PJM show the pre-merger HHI to be in the moderate range with a single pivotal
supplier. The proposed merger resulted in an HHI change of over 100 points.
162. The PJM MMU found that the proposed merger results in an HHI increase that exceeds the
threshold specified in the Merger Guidelines for both the aggregate and local capacity markets.
The merger therefore raises concerns about potential adverse competitive effects, absent
mitigation. The PJM MMU states that the merging companies proposal to offer capacity at a zero
price represents a from of behavioral
|
|
|
|
|
|
Docket No. EC05-43-000
|
|
56 |
mitigation that would resolve the issue if properly structured. It states that the companies
proposal must be structured so that it would provide the required mitigation for a variety of
capacity market designs, given the current uncertainty about the ultimate design. If the capacity
market were restructured so that all participants were required to offer all capacity into the
market, it explains, the companies proposal would have to cover all capacity offered to the market
(where the market would include the monthly and multi-monthly auctions, as well as the daily
market).
|
5. |
|
Protestors Responses to Applicants Answer and the PJM MMU Study |
163. First Energy argues that Applicants proposal to bid all of their capacity at $0 will give them
incentive to sell their capacity in the monthly (term) market for capacity, thus rendering their
capacity mitigation ineffective. Moreover, FirstEnergy argues that the PJM MMU has expressed
serious concerns about market power in PJM capacity markets. Therefore, FirstEnergy requests that
the Commission condition the merger on Applicants not acquiring any additional generation within
PJM until two years after the implementation of the restricted capacity markets, and on Applicants
submitting a compliance filing once PJMs capacity design is restructured, showing that they do not
have market power in relevant capacity markets.
164. NJBPU argues that plant retirements can be a form of withholding to increase capacity market
prices in a manner that would be profitable for the merged entity, but that would be riskier and
less or unprofitable for PSE&G on a standalone basis. It states that the PJM MMU shares the concern
that retirement may be a form of withholding. PJM itself is struggling with this issue and has not
yet set policy much less had implementation experience. NJBPU discusses retirement policy
including the need for a policy to ensure that retirements are not used to exercise market
power,and PJMs need for a clear retirement policy, with a test for market
power.110
|
6. |
|
Applicants Answer to Protestors Responses
to ApplicantsAnswer and the PJM MMU Study |
165. With respect to capacity markets, Applicants argue that the PJM MMU study effectively endorses
Applicants capacity market mitigation. The PJM MMU study concludes that the proposal to offer
capacity at a zero price represents a form of behavioral mitigation that would resolve the capacity
market power issue if properly structured. Applicants note the PJM MMUs concern that this
mitigation might not work
|
|
|
110 |
|
NJBPU Response at 16, Generator Retirement
WG, Joseph Bowring, PJM Market Monitoring Unit Manager. May 11, 2004. |
|
|
|
|
|
|
Docket No. EC05-43-000
|
|
57 |
for other capacity market structures adopted by PJM in the future. In response, Applicants note
that they have committed to proposing a new capacity market mitigation plan for the Commissions
approval 30 days after the closing of the Merger, when the details of the new PJM capacity markets
should be known.
166. Applicants also dismiss Ms. Frayers assertion that they will circumvent their zero-bid
proposal in the daily capacity market by bidding into term capacity markets. Applicants state that
to the extent that they attempt to increase the term market price by withholding capacity from that
market, the other market participants will know that the Applicants are required to offer their
uncommitted capacity into the daily capacity market at a price of zero. As a result, if the price
in the term markets were to exceed competitive levels as a result of withholding by the Applicants,
participants in those markets can simply refuse to purchase term capacity from Applicants and
instead purchase the capacity that the Applicants must offer into the daily market at a price of
zero. Thus Applicants state that the requirement to bid capacity into the daily market at a price
of zero mitigates market power in both the daily and term capacity markets.
|
7. |
|
Commission Determination |
167. Applicants have shown that the merger, with the mitigation proposed, will not harm competition
in any relevant capacity market. In addition to the physical divestiture of 4,000 MW of generating
capacity, Applicants have committed to bid all of their uncommitted capacity at zero. Therefore,
they will have no ability to withhold capacity in order to increase the market clearing price. As
noted by the PJM MMU, Applicants proposal to offer capacity at a zero price represents a form of
behavioral mitigation that would resolve the capacity market power issue if properly structured.
We share the PJM MMUs concern that this mitigation might not work for other capacity market
structures adopted by PJM in the future. Therefore, when the Commission approves a new capacity
market for PJM, we will require Applicants to submit a new analysis of the mergers
effect on the PJM capacity market and, if the analysis shows that the merger-related harm to
competition is not fully mitigated, propose a new mitigation plan for the Commissions approval
within 30 days of any such approvals.
|
|
|
|
|
|
Docket No. EC05-43-000
|
|
58 |
D. Ancillary Services
168. Applicants state that the merger will not harm competition in any relevant ancillary services
markets. They state that PJM does have markets for spinning reserves and regulation services, and
therefore analyze competition in those markets. Dr. Hieronymus states that Exelon
and PSE&G have 6 and 39 percent shares of the Mid-Atlantic spinning reserve capability,
respectively.111 He estimates that the market is moderately concentrated with a
merger-related increase of 507 HHI. He finds that a divestiture of 147 MW of spinning reserve
capacity would be necessary to bring the effect of the merger within the Commissions tolerance
level. Dr. Hieronymus concludes that Applicants proposed divestiture of 2,900 MW of fossil-fired
generation capacity, some of which is capable of providing spinning reserves, will sufficiently
mitigate the merger-related harm to competition in the spinning-reserve markets. PSE&Gs witness,
Mr. Frame, comes to the same conclusion, based on his review of the available PJM data.
169. Dr. Hieronymus also reviews the most recent available data for the PJM regulation market. He
reports that the market is moderately concentrated, with Exelon and PSE&G holding 13 and 12 percent
shares of the 2,011 MW of regulation-capable capacity in the Mid-Atlantic zone of PJM respectively.
Therefore, the merged firm will have approximately 25 percent of the regulation-capable capacity
(approximately 500 MW) in PJM Mid Atlantic Area Council (PJM MAAC), more than half of which is
pumped-storage capacity, which he argues is generally an uneconomic source of regulation. He notes
that the merged firm will not be a pivotal supplier of regulation services because there are more
than 1,500 MW of competing supply able to serve a peak load of approximately 700 MW. He concludes
that the merger will not harm competition in the PJM regulation market. PSE&Gs witness, Mr.
Frame, notes that the 2003 PJM Market Monitor Unit Report states that within PJM MAAC, there are
113 generating units capable of providing 2,011 MW of reserve capacity, and that in 2003,
regulation requirements in PJM MAAC ranged from 220 MW to 750 MW. He
concludes that because the regulation market demand can be met more than two times over by alternative suppliers
at the peak, and by a far greater amount during the off-peak, the merger will not harm competition
in the PJM regulation market.
|
|
|
111 |
|
He estimates the total market capability
for spinning reserves in the Mid-Atlantic market as 3,033 MW, with Exelon and
PSEG have 196 and 1,191 MW of spinning-reserve capable capacity, respectively.
The numbers are from the 2001 PJM Market Monitoring Unit Report on Spinning
Reserve Market. |
|
|
|
|
|
|
Docket No. EC05-43-000
|
|
59 |
170. Mr. Frame describes the ancillary services markets in PJM and states that there are two
spinning reserve products offered in PJM: Tier 1 and Tier 2. He states that Tier 1 spinning
reserves are provided by the unloaded capacity of steam generating units that have been bid into
the PJM energy market, but have not been called on to produce energy. He concludes that because
the provision of Tier 1 spinning reserves is essentially a by-product of participating in the
energy markets, the mergers effect on competition in the Tier 1 spinning reserves market will not
materially differ from the mergers effect on competition in energy markets. He concludes that
because Applicants proposed divestiture will mitigate any merger-related harm to competition, it
will also mitigate any harm to competition in the Tier 1 Spinning PJM reserve market.
171. Mr. Frame states that Tier 2 spinning reserves are used when Tier 1 reserves are exhausted,
and, historically, have been provided by hydroelectric units and combustion turbines with
condensing capacity. He states that PSE&G and Exelon currently control 1,191 and 196 MWs of
capacity capable of providing Tier 2 spinning reserves within the MAAC region of PJM,
respectively.112 He argues that the Applicants proposed divestiture will likely offset
any merger-related increase in the concentration of the Tier 2 spinning reserves market, because
Applicants plan to divest more than 196 MWs of generation capacity capable of providing Tier 2
spinning reserves, so the merged firm will have a smaller share of the market than PSE&Gs
pre-merger share.
172. FirstEnergy questions Applicants conclusion that the merger will not adversely affect
competition in ancillary services markets. FirstEnergys witness, Ms. Frayer, argues that Dr.
Hieronymus has not supported his assertion that regulation and spinning reserves prices are
intrinsically linked to energy market prices. She further argues that, because Applicants have not
specified the exact units that will be divested, it is premature to conclude that the proposed
mitigation plan for energy also satisfies ancillary services market concerns.
173. The PJM MMU states that its merger analysis focuses on the Mid-Atlantic Regulation Market as
the spinning reserves market most likely to be affected by the merger. It states that its results
are based on 12 months of actual spinning reserves market data through March 31, 2005.
|
|
|
112 |
|
Mr. Frame notes that Tier 2 spinning reserves is procured on a cost basis in other PJM regions. |
|
|
|
|
|
|
Docket No. EC05-43-000
|
|
60 |
174. The PJM MMU calculated hourly HHI values based upon regulation offered, regulation offered and
eligible, and regulation assigned as follows: Average HHI for pre-merger regulation offered
1,692; Average HHI for regulation offered and eligible 1,772; and Average HHI for regulation
assigned 2,497. The post-merger analysis is based on actual regulation market data for the
twelve months that ended March 31, 2005, modified to combine the ownership of PSE&G and Exelon
resources into a single company. The average post-merger HHI for regulation offered was 1,795, for
a change of 103 points, for regulation offered and eligible it was 1,900, for a change of 128
points, and for regulation assigned it was 2,628, for a change of 131 points.
175. The PJM MMU states that the analysis of the regulation market shows that the proposed merger
results in an increase in HHI that exceeds the increase specified in the Merger Guidelines. It
states that the proposed merger would significantly increase concentration in the regulation market
as defined by these metrics and the standards of the Merger Guidelines and therefore raises
concerns about potential adverse competitive effects, absent mitigation. It bases its conclusion
on the 128 point increase in average HHI for offered and eligible regulation. The PJM MMU states
that mitigation of the merger effects could be provided by an application of existing PJM market
rules to the PJM Mid-Atlantic Regulation Market; the merged company could agree to offer its
regulation capability into the market at cost-based levels. It states that as an alternative, the
merged company could agree to offer its regulation capability into the market at cost-based rates.
The PJM MMU further notes that the anticompetitive effects of the merger could be mitigated by
divestiture of regulation resources in the Mid-Atlantic Regulation Market, but that it is not
possible to evaluate the Applicants proposed divestiture plan without knowing which units would be
divested.
176. The PJM MMU states that its merger analysis focuses on the Mid-Atlantic Regulation Market as
the spinning reserves market most likely to be affected by the merger. Its results are based on 12
months of actual spinning market data through March 31, 2005. The PJM MMU analyzed the Tier 2
spinning reserve market (where Tier 2 resources include units that are backed down to provide
spinning capability and condensing units synchronized to the system and available to increase
output). It found the pre-merger average HHI to be 4,651 and the average post-merger HHI to be
4,671, a change of 20 points. The PJM MMU states that the proposed merger results in an increase
in the HHI that is less than that specified in the Merger Guidelines, and that the merger does not
raise competitive concerns in the spinning reserves market. The PJM MMUs analysis differs in two
ways from the Commissions Delivered Price Test. Its analysis includes all regulation capability
offered into the market without regard to cost. In addition, its analysis includes all regulation
offered by each supplier, while the Delivered Price Test uses the gross supply by participants net
of their load obligation.
|
|
|
|
|
|
Docket No. EC05-43-000
|
|
61 |
|
3. |
|
Commission Determination |
177. We recognize that ancillary service market data are not as readily available as that for
energy and capacity markets. As such, we find Applicants reliance on the PJM Market Monitor
Reports to be a reasonable way of analyzing the effect of the merger on competition in those
markets. Moreover, while pivotal supplier and market share analyses are not part of the Commission
standard review in section 203 cases, we find them informative here, given the lack of sufficient
data for complete analysis of the mergers effect on the ancillary service market concentration.
178. We find that the merger, as mitigated, will not harm competition in PJM ancillary services
markets. Applicants have shown that there are numerous supply alternatives in the PJM ancillary
services market. In addition, the divestiture of fossil units in PJM will include units capable of
providing spinning reserves and regulation services. Applicants analysis shows that their
proposed divestiture will reduce their control of capacity able to supply ancillary services to
less than the pre-merger level, under reasonable assumptions regarding the units that are
ultimately divested. In addition, the PJM MMU found that the anticompetitive effects of the merger
could be mitigated by divestiture of regulation resources in the Mid-Atlantic Regulation Market,
where almost all of the fossil units Applicants have proposed divesting are located. Regarding
FirstEnergys concern that it is premature to conclude that the proposed mitigation plan for energy
also satisfies ancillary services market concerns because Applicants have not specified the exact
units that will be divested, as we stated regarding the mitigation for energy markets, Applicants
have committed to provide an analysis of the mergers effect on competition, based on the actual
acquirers of the actual divested assets, once they are known. We rely on that commitment in making
our finding that the divestiture adequately mitigates any merger-related harm to competition in the
relevant ancillary services markets. If the analysis shows that the mergers harm to competition
has not been sufficiently mitigated, we will require additional mitigation at that time.
|
|
|
|
|
|
Docket No. EC05-43-000
|
|
62 |
E. Vertical Market Power Issues
179. Applicants address the effect of combining their transmission and generation assets. They
state that the only transmission owning entities involved, ComEd, PECO, and PSE&G, have all
transferred operational control over their transmission facilities to the PJM RTO. Applicants state that the Commission has held on a number of occasions that such a
transfer to a fully-functioning, Commission-approved RTO addresses the possibility of abuse of
transmission market power.113
180. Applicants also address the concern that the transaction will allow them to obtain some
control over the PJM decision-making process. They state that the transaction will have no effect
on the makeup of PJMs independent Board of Directors. Applicants further state that with respect
to the Members, Reliability, and Electricity Market Committee, PECO, the voting member for Exelon,
and PSE&G, the voting member for PSE&G, are both in the Transmission Owners sector, which has a 20
percent voting interest in the committees. Applicants expect that the transaction will result in
the Exelon and PSE&G votes combining into a single vote, increasing EE&Gs voting interest from 10
percent (the current share for each of PECO and PSE&G) to 11 percent. They argue that this
increase of 1 percent in a voting sector that has a total 20 percent voting interest is de minimis.
They also note that even this change will be negated if Dominion Virginia Power joins the
Transmission Owner Sector.
181. Applicants state that, with respect to the PJM East Transmission Owners Agreement, voting
rights are counted both based on individual members and on a weighted basis. A two-thirds vote in
each category is required to approve all major changes, and at least three opposition votes are
required to defeat any major change. They state that EE&Gs increased share of individual member
votes will be de minimis, going from one-in-nine to one-in-eight under the PJM East Transmission
Owners Agreement, and from one-in-14 to one-in-13 if the East, West, and South Transmission
Owners Agreements are consolidated into a single agreement, as is currently under consideration.
Applicants note that EE&Gs weighted share will go up more significantly, but provisions limiting
the weighted vote of an individual transmission owner to a maximum of 25 percent and requiring a
two thirds vote on each an individual and a weighted basis protect other transmission owners from
EE&Gs increased weighted share. EE&G will not be able to veto any proposed TOA changes because at
least three individual votes are required for such block.
|
|
|
113 |
|
Application at 44 citing Ameren Corp., 108 FERC at P 61. |
|
|
|
|
|
|
Docket No. EC05-43-000
|
|
63 |
182. Applicants also address the effect of combining their natural gas distribution and electric
generation assets. PECO provides natural gas distribution service to only one electric generator,
a 28 MW facility owned by Merck.114 They note that there are two other independent
generators in PECOs service area, but these generators take service directly from an interstate
natural gas pipeline. Furthermore, they argue that newly built generation facilities could readily
avoid PECOs small service area or connect directly to an interstate pipeline.115 They
state that PSE&Gs natural gas distribution system serves eight current or former generating
facilities in New Jersey under contract with the utility, as well as two merchant generators (the
Tocso plant and the Williams Red Oak plant). They note that the latter facilities are served by
PSE&G under long-term natural gas transportation contracts or discounted tariffs.116
Applicants further state that both companies provide natural gas distribution services to
affiliated generation facilities.
183. Applicants witness, Dr. William Hieronymus, states that no vertical market power concerns
arise as a result of the transactions combination of natural gas distribution facilities and
electric generation assets. This is because new generation can connect to one of EE&Gs Local
Distribution Companies (LDCs) or directly interconnect with a pipeline system, so the local
distribution company cannot impede entry by other competitors. Dr. Hieronymus further states that
the simple ownership of LDCs operations does not allow Applicants to self-deal or use other means
of using gas LDCs to favor affiliated activities. He notes that distribution tariffs are regulated
by the state public utility commissions, which impose open access distribution requirements.
Further, the ability to earn even ceiling rates in distribution tariffs is frequently constrained
by bypass alternatives or the existence of long-term contracts.
|
114 Application at 46. |
|
115
Id. at 46-47. |
|
116
Id. at 47. |
|
|
|
|
|
|
Docket No. EC05-43-000
|
|
64 |
184. Dr. Hieronymus states that other vertical concerns are not present because both Pennsylvania
and New Jersey have in place codes of conduct between gas and electric affiliates; both utilities
are governed by the Commissions Order No. 2004;117 and the amount of generation served
is so small that knowledge of customers operations is of no commercial value to electric
generators. He conducted the analysis required under section 33.4 of the Commissions regulations,
analyzing the downstream markets for PJM East, PJM Pre-2004, and Expanded PJM. He notes that the
Commission has found that market power in both the upstream natural gas market and the downstream
electric market is necessary for a vertical market power problem. After accounting for Applicants
mitigation commitments, he found that neither the PJM Pre-2004 nor the Expanded PJM downstream
markets are highly concentrated post-merger. However, the PJM East market remains highly
concentrated post-mitigation,118 so he analyzed the PJM East upstream market,
consistent with the Commissions regulations.119 He found this market not to be highly
concentrated and concludes that competitive conditions will not be conducive to a vertical
foreclosure strategy.
185. PSE&Gs witness, Mr. Frame, also concludes that the combination of Applicants natural gas and
electric generation resources would not harm competition. He states that neither Exelon nor PSE&G
owns any interstate natural gas pipelines and that the natural gas facilities owned by their
affiliated LDCs are available to electric generators on a state regulated open access basis.
|
|
|
117 |
|
Standards of Conduct for Transmission
Providers, Order No. 2004, FERC Stats. & Regs., Regulations Preambles ¶
31,155 (2003), order on rehg, Order No. 2004-A, III FERC Stats. & Regs.
¶ 31,161 (2004), 107 FERC ¶ 61,032 (2004), order on rehg, Order
No. 2004-B, III FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 31,166 (2004), 108 FERC ¶
61,118 (2004), order on rehg, Order No. 2004-C, 109 FERC ¶ 61,325
(2004), order on rehg, Order No. 2004-D, 110 FERC ¶ 61,320 (2005). |
|
118 |
|
Hieronymus testimony at 72. |
|
119 |
|
Revised Filing Requirements, FERC Statutes & Regulations ¶ 31,111 at 31,904. |
|
|
|
|
|
|
Docket No. EC05-43-000
|
|
65 |
186. The AAI asserts that membership in an RTO is not sufficient to ensure that sellers will not be
able to exercise vertical market power through their ownership of transmission, citing a show cause
order in which the Commission initiated an investigation of Exelon regarding alleged sharing of
non-public information regarding maintenance outages.120
187. No party contests Applicants description of the PJM governance structure. The PHI Companies
assert, however, that EE&G might be positioned to exert undue influence on the PJM RTO as a result
of its holding the largest transmission investment in PJM.
188. Protesters dispute Applicants claim that they will not be able to exercise vertical market
power in the natural gas market. Direct Energy asserts that Applicants analysis is flawed for two
reasons. First, Applicants use data that incorrectly represents interstate pipeline capacity
deliverable to relevant markets, and says Applicants omitted capacity served in eastern
Pennsylvania (in PJM East) in their calculation of Columbia Gas Transmission and Texas Eastern
Transmission pipelines deliverability from Pennsylvania to New Jersey and from New Jersey to
Delaware, respectively. Direct Energy claims that as a result, Applicants have understated
Columbia Gas and Texas Easterns contribution to the PJM East gas market. Direct Energy also
claims that Applicants have overestimated the size of the PJM gas market by incorrectly counting as
deliveries in PJM gas that goes through PJM, but is ultimately delivered in New York and New
England. Direct Energys witness, Dr. Briden, states that as a result, Applicants analysis
understates the concentration in the upstream natural gas market, which he claims will be highly
concentrated after the merger.121
189. The POCA expresses concern regarding EE&Gs 35.6 percent share of natural gas transportation
capacity in the PJM East market. It states that with one party controlling a substantial amount of
a capacity in such a constrained market, the exercise of market power could result in significantly
increased gas costs to other LDCs and marketers in that market.122 The Commission
should examine the amount of capacity that EE&G
|
|
|
120 |
|
AAI Protest at 17, citing Exelon Corporation, PECO Energy Company, Exelon Generation Company, L.L.C., and Exelon
Power Team, Show Cause Order, 97 FERC ¶ 61,009, October 3, 2001. |
|
121 |
|
Briden Testimony at 7-8. |
|
122 |
|
POCA Protest at 22-23. |
|
|
|
|
|
|
Docket No. EC05-43-000
|
|
66 |
would hold on individual pipelines, as many LDCs in the Northeastern markets are captive to one or
two pipelines. EE&G may be able to withhold capacity and raise natural gas prices.
190. The Division of the Ratepayer Advocates also expresses dissatisfaction with Applicants
analysis of the natural gas market. Division of the Ratepayer Advocate states that the Application
does not address horizontal market power issues that may result from the merger of the PHI
Companies and PSE&Gs gas capacity assets, the potential for aggregating additional power by
providing asset management services for third parties, or the effect of such activities on various
markets. Division of the Ratepayer Advocate says that with the Applicants holding 35.6 percent of
available capacity in the PJM East market area, any additional control of gas capacity resources
(for example, through asset management agreements) would place the Applicants in a position to
exert market power through various actions.123 Division of the Ratepayer Advocates
witness, LeLash, further states that Applicants fail to provide information concerning the control
of storage capacity held by the entities holding the interstate transportation
entitlements.124
The City of Philadelphia echoes the concern that Applicants could abuse their market power in the
transportation of natural gas to gain a competitive advantage in the relevant natural gas
distribution markets.125
191. Three protesters (FirstEnergy, Direct Energy, and POCA) express concerns that concentration in
the upstream and downstream markets may allow the exercise of market power. FirstEnergy states
that post-mitigation, the upstream PJM East market is at least moderately concentrated and the PJM
East downstream market is highly concentrated. Direct Energy adds that because both the upstream
and downstream markets will be highly concentrated after the merger, the proposed merger raises
vertical market power concerns for which Applicants offer no mitigation.126 Direct
Energys witness, Dr. Briden, suggests mitigation in the form of a transfer of a share of
Applicants natural gas pipeline capacity to third party marketers not affiliated with Applicants.
The POCA states that Applicants should not dismiss as irrelevant the failure to pass the downstream
portion of the vertical market power test (in PJM East), because the ability to affect
|
|
|
123 |
|
Division of the Ratepayer Advocate Protest at 16. |
|
124 |
|
LeLash Testimony at 4. |
|
125 |
|
City of Philadelphia Protest at 7. |
|
126 |
|
Direct Energy Protest at 8. |
|
|
|
|
|
|
Docket No. EC05-43-000
|
|
67 |
electricity prices through the control of natural gas supply or delivery could result in increased
prices to all consumers, particularly since gas-fired plants operate on the margin and often set
the market-clearing price in PJM.
192. Applicants reply to AAIs protest by stating that the Commission never found any violations in
the proceedings that AAI cite. They conclude that AAI has presented no basis for concluding that
the Commission should change its policy regarding RTO membership. They similarly dismiss, as mere
speculation, the PHI Companies assertion that Applicants will be able to exert influence on PJM.
193. Applicants address concerns regarding the effect of the merger on the upstream natural gas
market by restating their assertion that the transaction will not create a new situation where the
combined entity could increase electric prices by denying gas supplies to other participants.
Applicants state that because of their substantial divestiture commitment, they will have less
Available Economic Capacity in the downstream electric market than they do today and that the
upstream market will not be highly concentrated post-merger. Applicants witness, Dr. Hieronymus,
answers protests that he calculated the HHI incorrectly by stating first that capacity that is
bound for New York or New England is often sold into PJM East. Further, Dr. Hieronymus states that
Direct Energy calculated upstream HHIs incorrectly by failing to remove Applicants northern-bound
capacity in their calculations. He also states that Dr. Briden incorrectly calculates others
share in the HHI calculations as the sum of their market shares, quantity squared, as opposed to
the sum of the squares of the individual market shares. Correcting for these errors, he states,
the upstream HHI is 1,651, so there are no vertical market power concerns.127
194. Applicants address protesters concerns regarding the storage market by stating that
Applicants own no storage capacity and contract for relatively small amounts (less than 12 percent)
of PJMs storage capacity. They state that because their share of storage capacity is smaller than
their share of pipeline capacity, the storage market raises no vertical concerns.
|
|
|
|
|
|
Docket No. EC05-43-000
|
|
68 |
|
4. |
|
Protestors Response to Applicants Answer |
195. With regard to natural gas, the NJBPU states that it is concerned that the availability of
spot market, short-term interruptible transportation in a market with peak period deliverability
constraints is inadequate for new generation project developers and their lenders. It further
argues that the Commission must decide whether the total pipeline capacity controlled by the
Applicants will serve as a barrier to entry.128
196. Direct Energy repeats its claim that Applicants overstated the size of the PJM East natural
gas market. With respect to the purported error in the others category of his HHI calculation,
Direct Energy witness Briden states that Dr. Hieronymus made the same mistakes in Exhibit J-16 of
his original testimony.
197. With regard to electric transmission, the NJBPU agues that Applicants membership in PJM does
not, by itself, ensure that their ownership and control of major electric transmission systems
cannot be used to favor affiliated generation or hinder competing suppliers. The NJBPU remains
concerned that influence in favor of corporate objectives may skew the projects that are built and
stymie competing projects that could help other suppliers.
|
5. |
|
Commission Determination |
198. Applicants have shown that the combination of their generation and transmission facilities
will not harm competition. Applicants have, pre-merger, transferred operational control over their
transmission facilities to PJM, and the Commission has held, on a number of occasions, that such
transfer mitigates the ability to use control of transmission assets to harm competition in
wholesale electricity markets. We agree with Applicants that AAIs protest does not provide a
basis for concluding that the Commission should change its policy regarding RTO
membership.129
199. Applicants have shown that that the proposed merger will not allow them to control PJM. While
no party contests Applicants description of PJMs governance structure, the PHI Companies
speculate that Applicants might be able to exert undue influence on PJM as a result of holding
the largest transmission investment in PJM. However, it does not explain how this would happen.
|
|
|
128 |
|
NJBPU Response at 19. |
|
129 |
|
See, e.g. AEP/CSW at 61,788. |
|
|
|
|
|
|
Docket No. EC05-43-000
|
|
69 |
200. Applicants have shown that the combination of their generation and natural gas distribution
facilities will not harm competition. In Order No. 642, we stated that in order for a merger to
create or enhance vertical market power, both the upstream and downstream markets must be
highly concentrated.130 Applicants witness, Dr. Hieronymus, has
shown that, given the mitigation, the downstream markets are not highly concentrated after the
merger. Moreover, he has shown that the upstream market is not highly concentrated. Applicants
have shown that protesters claims to the contrary result, in part, from selective omission of
relevant capacity, an assertion that protesters do not counter. Dr. Hieronymus Exhibit J-16
clearly shows the others market share to be 16.7 percent, and their contribution to HHI to be 19.
Had he used the calculation method Dr. Briden attributes to him, his contribution to HHI for
others would have been 279 points, not 19.
201. We disagree with NJBPUs assertion that Applicants will be able to foreclose new generation
entry. Neither company owns interstate pipeline facilities, so this is not a convergence merger
comparable to those in which the Commission has identified vertical market power issues as a result
of the combination of electric and gas utilities. While Applicants do own natural gas LDCs through
PECO and PSE&G, they do not own interstate transportation facilities. Potential entrants seeking
fuel supplies can opt for a
direct connection to the interstate pipelines serving the relevant markets rather than Applicants
LDCs. Therefore, the merger does not give Applicants the ability to impede entry of gas-fired
generating facilities.
202. Applicants have also shown that their presence in the natural gas storage market is small
enough not to raise competitive concerns here. Applicants do not own storage facilities, and
estimate their contracted share of the storage market to be less than 12 percent.
Therefore, they would have little ability to influence downstream electricity prices.
203. With regard to the POCAs and the Division of the Ratepayer Advocates concerns regarding
horizontal effects in the natural gas market, we note that, under section 203 of the FPA, we
consider the effects of an increase in concentration in the upstream market to the extent that it
could harm competition in wholesale electricity markets. Here, as noted above, Applicants have
shown that both the upstream and downstream markets are not highly concentrated, thus the
horizontal upstream combination will not harm competition in the relevant downstream wholesale
electricity markets.
|
|
|
130 |
|
Order No. 642 at 31,911 (emphasis added). |
|
|
|
|
|
|
Docket No. EC05-43-000
|
|
70 |
F. Effect on Rates
204. Applicants state the transaction will not adversely affect the rates for any wholesale power
or transmission customers. First, Applicants commit to hold transmission customers harmless from
any increase in Commission-jurisdictional transmission rates to the extent that such costs exceed
demonstrated savings related to the transaction. Applicants further state that no wholesale power
rates will be affected because, of the three franchised utilities involved in the merger (ComEd,
PECO and PSE&G), only ComEd has any wholesale requirements customers, and Applicants commit to hold
ComEds customers harmless from any merger-related costs that exceed demonstrated merger-related
benefits. Exelon and PSE&Gs remaining customers are charged market-based rates that will not be
affected by the sellers cost of service and, thus, will not be affected by the merger.
205. The POCA says that the PJM OATT would allow the Applicants to file surcharges mechanisms or
formula rates that might allow transmission rates to increase without reflecting the benefits of
the merger.131
206. Dowagiac states that without proper mitigation, consumers will face both power and
transmission cost increases as a result of the proposed merger. Dowagiac argues that the proposed
mitigation measures are long-term and complex and will allow numerous opportunities for Applicants
to exercise market power. It is also skeptical of Applicants pledge to protect current consumers
from price increases as a result of the proposed merger. Dowagiac states that, regarding the ComEd
and PECO merger, ComEd and PECO pledged not to let financial injury fall on Dowagiac... [which is]
now paying SECA charges of $1,107.83/MW- month to ComEd for PJM service.132 Therefore,
based on the current merger proposal and Exelons history in past mergers, Dowagiac argues that the
Commission should condition the approval of the proposed merger on the fulfillment of all
conditions associated with the ComEd and PECO merger. Specifically, Dowagiac requests that Exelon
be directed to protect Dowagiac against any possible financial injury resulting from either the
current merger proposal or the ComEd/PECO merger.
|
|
|
131 |
|
POCA Protest at 33-34. |
|
132 |
|
Dowagiac Protest at 5. |
|
|
|
|
|
|
Docket No. EC05-43-000
|
|
71 |
207. In response to protestors assertions that the merger would harm wholesale competition in PJM,
thus, adversely affecting wholesale electricity rates, Applicants state that they have already
addressed those concerns with the proposal to mitigate any merger-related harm to wholesale
competition. In addition, in order to address the POCAs concern that Applicants hold harmless
commitment is inadequate, Applicants clarify that their hold harmless agreement allows for no
surcharge or formula rate that would allow them to recover merger-related costs unless those costs
were offset by merger-related savings.133
208. In response to Dowagiacs protest regarding through-and-out transmission rates related to
ComEds participation in the PJM RTO, Applicants argue that Dowogiacs complaints are not related
to the merger and should be addressed in Docket No. EL02-111 or another appropriate
forum.134
|
4. |
|
Responses to Applicants Answer |
209. H-P Energy argues that Applicants should not be able to use the automatic cost recovery
provisions of Schedule 12 of the PJM OATT without meeting all of the safeguards and procedures of
Schedule 12. They state that the safeguards contained in Schedule 12 ensure that mandatory charges
imposed on market participants are just and reasonable, and that Applicants have not justified
bypassing any of those Commission-approved safeguards.135
|
5. |
|
Commission Determination |
210. The Commission finds that Applicants have shown that the transaction will not adversely affect
wholesale rates. We rely on Applicants hold harmless commitment for transmission rates in making
this finding. In addition, wholesale power rates will not be adversely affected by the merger
because, only ComEd has any wholesale requirements customers and Applicants commit to hold ComEds
customers harmless regarding any
|
|
|
133 |
|
Applicants Answer at 74. |
|
134 |
|
In Docket No. EL02-111, the Commission opened a section 206 proceeding to investigate the issue of rate pancaking
between PJM and the Midwest ISO and to determine whether the transmission rates
were just and reasonable. |
|
135 |
|
H-P Energy Protest at 18. |
|
|
|
|
|
|
Docket No. EC05-43-000
|
|
72 |
merger-related costs that exceed demonstrated merger-related benefits. We rely on Applicants hold
harmless commitment in finding that wholesale customers rates will not be adversely affected by
the merger. Applicants other wholesale customers are charged market-based rates that will not be
affected by the sellers cost of service and, thus, will not be affected by the merger.
211. We agree with H-P Energy that Applicants should not be able to use the automatic cost recovery
provisions of Schedule 12 of the PJM OATT. Applicants shall make the appropriate filings under
section 205 of the FPA, related to cost recovery of any transmission expansion projects. Finally,
we find that Dowagiacs arguments regarding through-and-out transmission rates will be addressed in
the complaint filed under Docket No. EL02-111.
G. Effect on Regulation
212. Applicants state that the transaction will not adversely affect federal regulation. They
state that the transaction will not result in the formation a new holding company under PUHCA that
would preempt the Commissions jurisdiction. They note that the transaction will bring PSE&G into
the Exelon registered holding company system, and the Applicants commit to waive the pre-emptive
effects of the Securities and Exchange Commissions jurisdiction on this Commission under Ohio
Power.136
213. Applicants state the transaction will not adversely affect state regulation. They have filed
for approval from the Pennsylvania Public Utility Commission (PaPUC) and the NJBPU, both of whom
will therefore be able to protect their own jurisdiction. Applicants state that while the Illinois
Commission does not have jurisdiction over the transaction, it does have jurisdiction to regulate
ComEd, and they have filed notice of the transaction with the Illinois Commission. They further
state that after the merger is complete, ComEds ownership will not change; it will remain an
operating company within a registered holding company system. They conclude that the transfer will
not have any effect on regulation of ComEd under Illinois law and that ComEd will remain under the
jurisdiction of the Illinois Commerce Commission.
|
|
|
136 |
|
Ohio Power Co. v. FERC, 954 F.2d 779 (D.C. Cir. 1992)(Ohio Power). |
|
|
|
|
|
|
Docket No. EC05-43-000
|
|
73 |
214. POCA argues that while Applicants submitted their application to the PaPUC, Applicants argued
that the PaPUC lacks jurisdiction over this merger and only requested approval of the PaPUC in the
alternative. Therefore, POCA requests that the Commission examine the potential adverse impact of
the proposed merger on state regulation. Since this proposed merger would create one of the
nations largest public utility holding companies and presents significant market power issues with
a novel and untested mitigation proposal, POCA requests that the Commission investigate all issues
related to the proposed merger by establishing further discovery, a hearing and access to further
filings to determine if the proposed merger satisfies the Commissions guidelines and is in the
public interest.
215. Citizen Power, et al. raises concerns about the mergers effect on power markets in general,
and, in particular, the NJBPUs regulatory authority, if the PUHCA is repealed.137
216. In response to the POCAs concerns about the effect of the merger on state regulation in
Pennsylvania, Applicants argue that the merger will not affect the structure of PECO, the one
affected utility that is under the PaPUCs jurisdiction. They further note that the PaPUC has
intervened in the proceeding before the Commission, but has not raised any concerns regarding the
effect of the merger on its regulatory authority or requested that the Commission address that
issue. In response to Citizens Power, et al.s concerns about the effect of the merger on
regulation if PUHCA is repealed, Applicants argue that the NJBPU can address any issues related to
PUHCA repeal in the merger proceeding before it. In addition, they note that the NJBPU has not
requested that Commission assist it on this issue.
|
|
|
137 |
|
Citizen Power notes that, because PSEG is headquartered in New Jersey, where it conducts the bulk of its utility
business, it is not part of an interstate holding company, and PSEGs
utility transactions are regulated by the New Jersey BPU. Citizen states that
if PSEG is swallowed up by Exelon, a multi-state holding company,
the NJBPU will lose its ability to protect New Jersey customers. Citizen
Protest at 5. |
|
|
|
|
|
|
Docket No. EC05-43-000
|
|
74 |
|
4. |
|
Commission Determination |
217. We find that the merger will not adversely affect Commission or state regulation. We rely on
Applicants commitment to follow the Commissions Ohio Power policy in finding that the merger will
not adversely affect Commission regulation. Applicants have shown that the transaction will not
harm any states ability to regulate any of the merging parties. The merger is subject to review
by the NJBPU, who can therefore protect its jurisdictional interests. We note that the PaPUC has
intervened in the proceeding before the Commission, but has not requested that the Commission
address any issues regarding the effect of the merger on its regulatory authority. Furthermore,
the PaPUC, the Illinois Commerce Commission, and the NJBPU will retain regulatory authority over
the merged company. We note that none of the affected state commissions have requested that the
Commission address the effect of the merger on state regulation.
The Commission orders:
(A) Applicants proposed merger and internal restructuring is hereby authorized, subject to
Commission acceptance of the Applicants compliance filings, as discussed in the body of this
order.
(B) The foregoing authorization is without prejudice to the authority of the Commission or any
other regulatory body with respect to rates, service, accounts, valuation, estimates or
determinations of costs, or any other matter whatsoever now pending or which may come before the
Commission.
(C) Nothing in this order shall be construed to imply acquiescence in any estimate or
determination of cost or any valuation of property claimed or asserted.
(D) The Commission retains authority under sections 203(b) and 309 of the FPA to issue
supplemental orders as appropriate.
(E) Applicants shall make any appropriate filings under section 205(a) of the FPA, as
necessary, to implement the proposed Transaction.
(F) Applicants must submit their proposed final accounting within six months of the
consummation of the merger. The accounting submission should provide all merger-related accounting
entries made to the books and records of PSE&G, along with appropriate narrative explanations
describing the basis for the entries.
(G) Applicants shall make a compliance filing to the Commission within 30 days of the
completion of their divestiture, providing an Appendix A analysis of the mergers effect on
competition in energy and capacity markets, given actual plants and
|
|
|
|
|
|
Docket No. EC05-43-000
|
|
75 |
assets divested and the actual acquirers of the divested assets. If the analysis shows that the
mergers harm to competition has not been sufficiently mitigated, Applicants must propose
additional mitigation at that time.
(H) Applicants shall make a compliance filing to the Commission within 30 days of this
order showing that they have established an independent monitor to oversee the baseload energy
auction and Applicants compliance with the terms of the energy contracts; and that they have
established a public compliance website the showing how they are complying with the virtual
divestiture and other mitigation requirements, including the interim mitigation.
(I) Applicants shall notify the Commission within 10 days of the date that the merger has been
consummated.
By the Commission.
( S E A L )
|
|
|
|
|
Magalie R. Salas, |
|
|
Secretary. |
exv99wd11w1
Exhibit D-11.1
113 FERC ¶ 61,299
UNITED STATES OF AMERICA
FEDERAL ENERGY REGULATORY COMMISSION
Before Commissioners: Joseph T. Kelliher, Chairman;
Nora Mead Brownell, and Suedeen G. Kelly.
|
|
|
Exelon Corporation
|
|
Docket Nos. EC05-43-000 |
Public Service Enterprise Group, Inc.
|
|
EC05-43-001 |
ORDER DENYING REHEARING, ACCEPTING COMPLIANCE FILING AND GRANTING CLARIFICATION
(Issued December 21, 2005)
1. Numerous entities1 filed requests for rehearing of the Commissions Merger
Order2 authorizing the merger of Exelon Corporation (Exelon) and Public Service
|
|
|
1 |
|
American Public Power Association (APPA), National Rural Electric
Cooperative Association (NRECA), Public Citizens Energy Program (Public Citizen), together with
Action Alliance of Senior Citizens of Greater Philadelphia, Citizen Power, Energy Justice Network,
Illinois Public Interest Research Group (IPIRG), New Jersey Citizen Action (NJ Citizen Action), New
Jersey Public Interest Research Group (NJPIRG), Pennsylvania Public Interest Research Group
(PennPIRG), Philadelphia Association of Community Organizations for Reform Now, Service Employees
International Union, SEIU New Jersey State Council, Tenant Action Group, Three Mile Island Alert
and Utility Workers Union of America Local 601, Hoosier Energy Rural Electric Cooperative, Inc.
(Hoosier Energy), Pennsylvania Office of Consumer Advocate (PaOCA), New Jersey Board of Public
Utilities (NJBPU), New Jersey Division of the Ratepayer Advocate (NJ Ratepayer Advocate),
Philadelphia Gas Works together with the City of Philadelphia (Philadelphia Gas), PPL Companies
(PPL), and the Illinois Attorney General on behalf of the People of the State of Illinois
(Illinois). Public Citizens Energy Program with Citizen Power, Energy Justice Network, IPIRG, NJ
Citizen Action, NJPIRG, PennPIRG and Three Mile Island Alert are collectively referred to
throughout this order as Public Citizen. As discussed below, the remainder of the entities
joining in Public Citizens request for rehearing did not intervene in the original proceeding, and
we will not allow them to intervene at this late date and request rehearing as parties. |
|
2 |
|
Exelon Corporation and Public Service Enterprise Corporation, Inc., 112 FERC
¶ 61,011 (2005) (Merger Order.) |
|
|
|
|
|
Docket Nos. EC05-43-000 and 001 |
|
|
2 |
|
Enterprise Corporation, Inc. (PSEG) (collectively, Applicants) under section 203 of the Federal
Power Act (FPA).3 In this order, we deny the requests for rehearing.
Background
2. Applicants requested Commission approval of a transaction that includes Exelons acquisition of
PSEG and the resulting indirect acquisition of Exelons and PSEGs jurisdictional facilities and
the internal restructuring and consolidation of Exelons and PSEGs subsidiaries establishment of a
new corporate structure for the new entity, Exelon Electric & Gas Corporation (EE&G). The
Commission determined that proposed transaction, which included mitigation of harm to the
competitive market through substantial divestiture of generation and several compliance filings
with the Commission, is consistent with the public interest, as required by section 203 of the
FPA.4
3. Several parties filed timely requests for rehearing. Applicants filed an answer, and NJBPU
filed an answer to Applicants answer. Philadelphia Gas filed a motion to strike Applicants
answer to the requests for rehearing.
Discussion
4. When late intervention is sought after the issuance of a dispositive order, the prejudice to
other parties and burden upon the Commission of granting the late intervention may be substantial.
Thus, movants bear a higher burden to demonstrate good cause for granting such late
intervention.5 Action Alliance of Senior Citizens of Greater Philadelphia, Philadelphia
Association of Community Organizations for Reform Now, Service Employees International Union, SEIU
New Jersey State Council, Tenant
|
|
|
3 |
|
16 U.S.C. § 824(b) (2000). The Energy Policy Act of 2005 (EPAct 2005) repeals
the Public Utility Holding Company Act of 1935 (PUHCA 1935) and enacts the Public Utility Holding
Company Act of 2005 (PUHCA 2005). EPAct 2005 §§ 261 et seq., Pub. L. No. 109-58, 199 Stat. 594
(2005). We analyzed this transaction under section 203 as it appears pre-EPAct 2005, since the
amended section 203 does not become effective until February 8, 2006. Additionally, this
transaction was filed before EPAct 2005 was enacted. EPAct 2005 §§ 1289(c) Pub. L. No.
109-58, 199 Stat. 594 (2005). |
|
4 |
|
Id. |
|
5 |
|
See, e.g., Midwest Independent Transmission System Operator, Inc., 102 FERC
¶ 61,250 at P 7 (2003). |
|
|
|
|
|
Docket Nos. EC05-43-000 and 001 |
|
|
3 |
|
Action Group and the Utility Workers Union of America Local 601 have not met this higher burden.
5. Pursuant to Rule 713(d) and Rule 213(a)(2) of the Commissions Rules of Practice and
Procedure,6 answers to requests for rehearing are not permitted. Therefore, the
Commission will reject Applicants answer to the requests for rehearing. Since we reject
Applicants answer, we find Philadelphia Gas motion to strike Applicants answer moot.
6. On August 1, 2005, pursuant to the Merger Order, Applicants submitted a compliance filing
outlining the independent administration of the baseload energy auction, including the hiring of an
auction manager and an independent auction monitor.7 Notice of the August 1, 2005
compliance filing was published in the Federal Register, with comments due on or before December 8,
2005. The City of Philadelphia filed a timely protest to the compliance filing. We will accept
Applicants compliance filing, as discussed below.
|
B. |
|
Did the Commission Fail to Address Protestors in the
Merger Order? |
|
1. |
|
Requests for Rehearing |
7. Several parties argue that the Commission failed to address comments made in response to
Applicants proposal. NJBPU states that the Commission ignored the report of the PJM
Interconnection, LLC (PJM) Market Monitoring Unit (PJM MMU) evaluating the mergers effect on the
PJM-administered markets. NJBPU argues that the PJM MMU has access to historical market
information and additional information relating to the specific PJM region which makes the PJM MMU
analysis superior to the Applicants Appendix A analysis and the only bona fide assessment of the
mergers effects on the PJM markets.8
8. Additionally, NJBPU states that the Commission failed to recognize that the PJM
MMU recommended more precise mitigation than that proposed by Applicants. NJBPU also argues that
the Commission failed to address arguments that Applicants Appendix A analysis was based on
questionable assumptions and thus understated Applicants market power and the mitigation necessary
to ameliorate that market power. Some of these errors are assuming a low share of transmission
import capacity and
|
|
|
6 |
|
18 C.F.R. § 385.713(d) and § 385.213(a)(2) (2005). |
|
7 |
|
August 1, 2005 Compliance Filing, Docket No. EC05-43-000. |
|
8 |
|
NJBPU Request for Rehearing at 23. |
|
|
|
|
|
Docket Nos. EC05-43-000 and 001 |
|
|
4 |
|
ignoring the effect of retirement of facilities and the possibility of withholding or other
strategic bidding.
9. PPL argues that the Commission failed to address its comment that Applicants improperly analyzed
the Northern New Jersey and PJM Classic markets, including evaluating appropriate mitigation in the
Northern New Jersey market and the amount of import capability applicants have in the PJM Classic
market. PPL also states that the Commission never responded to the issue of increased cost-capping
under PJMs three pivotal supplier rule.
|
2. |
|
Commission Determination |
10. It is simply not correct that the Commission failed to address these issues. The Commission
addressed the analysis of the PJM MMU specifically in PP 103-109 of the Merger Order and throughout
the Commissions discussion section. The Merger Order also addresses the issues of properly
analyzing the Northern New Jersey and PJM Classic markets in evaluating Applicants market
power.9 PPL argues that the Commission did not address increased cost-capping under
PJMs three-pivotal-supplier rule. We did not directly address the three-pivotal-supplier rule
because we made a finding, based on Applicants Appendix A analysis, that competition in the
relevant capacity markets would not be adversely affected by the merger.10 We do not
use the three-pivotal-supplier rule in our analysis of a mergers effect on competition. Rather,
it is a test used by the PJM Market Monitor to determine when bid caps should be put into place.
11. While the Commission disagrees that we failed to address these issues in the Merger Order, we
will once again explain the basis for many of the decisions in the Merger Order below.
|
C. |
|
Should the Commission Have Established an Evidentiary Hearing to Evaluate Issues of
Material Fact? |
|
1. |
|
Requests for Rehearing |
12. Several parties argue that the Commission should have established an evidentiary hearing to
evaluate numerous disputed issues of material fact, such as inconsistencies and concerns about
Applicants Appendix A analysis and the proposed divestiture.11
|
|
|
9 |
|
Merger Order at PP 122-23. |
|
10 |
|
Id. at P 167. |
|
11 |
|
Hoosier Energy at 3. |
|
|
|
|
|
Docket Nos. EC05-43-000 and 001 |
|
|
5 |
|
13. For example, Public Citizen states that Applicants analysis and economic expert witness were
not subject to cross-examination and discovery.12
14. PaOCA and Illinois argue that the Commissions failure to establish an evidentiary hearing
denied parties a meaningful opportunity to be heard and to develop a complete record.13
PaOCA identifies several issues that, it argues, require a opportunity for discovery,
cross-examination and full analysis through an evidentiary hearing. Denial of such an opportunity,
PaOCA argues, would violate the parties due process rights.14
15. NJ Ratepayer Advocate argues that the Commission erred in failing to establish an evidentiary
hearing to evaluate numerous issues of material fact, including Applicants ability to engage in
strategic bidding and the effect Applicants gas operations will have on competition.15
NJ Ratepayer Advocate also identifies several other issues that should have been analyzed through
an evidentiary hearing and argues that the Commissions failure to order the hearing was arbitrary
and capricious and was not reasoned decision-making.16
16. PPL argues that the Commissions failure to order an evidentiary hearing to address the issues
of material fact was not a consideration of the relevant
factors.17 PPL states that the Commission ignored expert testimony, exhibits and
analysis that demonstrated that material issues of fact existed.18 This failure to
establish a hearing terminated the parties ability to explore these issues through discovery and
cross-examination, according to PPL .19
|
|
|
12 |
|
Public Citizen at 12. |
|
13 |
|
PaOCA at 5-6. |
|
14 |
|
Id. at 9. |
|
15 |
|
NJ Ratepayer Advocate at 5 & 9. |
|
16 |
|
Id. at 16. |
|
17 |
|
PPL at 8. |
|
18 |
|
Id. at 9. |
|
19 |
|
Id. at 12. |
|
|
|
|
|
Docket Nos. EC05-43-000 and 001 |
|
|
6 |
|
|
2. |
|
Commission Determination |
17. The Commission has broad discretion regarding when to set matters for hearing.20 If
the Commission can resolve disputed issues based on the written record, then the Commission is not
required to establish an evidentiary hearing to address disputed issues of fact.21 No
party has shown why the voluminous written record22 in this case was inadequate.
|
D. |
|
Did the Commission Fail to Evaluate Market Power in the Natural Gas Market? |
|
1. |
|
Requests for Rehearing |
18. NJPBU and Philadelphia Gas argue that the Commission did not consider all the evidence in
finding that the merger would not have anticompetitive effects on the natural gas market. They
state that the Commission ignored the analysis of Dr. Paul Carpenter, which indicated that the
merger will affect natural gas prices in the PJM East market due to Applicants control of upstream
gas capacity and
storage.23 Dr. Carpenters analysis concluded that Applicants will have significant
market power in the relevant natural gas market. The HHI screen failures are not remedied by the
mitigation because the mitigation only attempts to remedy the horizontal concentration in the
electricity market, not the vertical concentration in the natural gas market.24
19. NJ Ratepayer Advocate argues that the Commission erred in failing to evaluate the natural gas
markets because there is a potential for horizontal market power in natural gas transportation and
storage rights. This market power could lead to gas price manipulation even in the absence of a
high level of concentration in the market.
|
|
|
20 |
|
ISO New England, Inc., 111 FERC ¶ 61,096 (2005). |
|
21 |
|
Moreau v. FERC, 982 F.2d 556 at 568 (D.C. Cir. 1993). |
|
22 |
|
The record in this case exceeds 2,000 pages. |
|
23 |
|
NJPBU at 41. |
|
24 |
|
Philadelphia Gas at 20. |
|
|
|
|
|
Docket Nos. EC05-43-000 and 001 |
|
|
7 |
|
|
2. |
|
Commission Determination |
20. With respect to the vertical competitive impacts of a merger, the Commission examines three
issues: (1) foreclosure/raising rivals costs; (2) competitive coordination; and (3) regulatory
evasion.25 The Commission has held that in order for a merger to have an adverse impact
on competition by increasing the merged firms ability or incentive to engage in foreclosure or
raise rivals costs, both the upstream and downstream markets must be highly
concentrated.26
21. NJBPU, Philadelphia Gas, and NJ Ratepayer Advocate either misunderstand the Commissions
standard for consistency with the public interest, or propose a new standard. As explained in the
Revised Filing Requirements, we examine the effect of a merger on the upstream natural gas market,
but only in conjunction with the downstream wholesale electric energy market. And only if both of
these markets are concentrated do we have concerns.27
22. The FPA does not grant the Commission authority to examine the horizontal impact of a merger on
natural gas markets alone, which is what the parties ask. The Commission did indeed examine
concentration in the natural gas market, in conjunction with concentration in the wholesale energy
market, and determined that the merger did not raise an issue with respect to foreclosure.
|
|
|
25 |
|
Revised Filing Requirements Under Part 33 of the Commissions Regulations, Order
No. 642, 65 Fed. Reg. 70,984 (2000), FERC Stats. & Regs., Regulations Preambles July 1996-December
2000 ¶ 31,111 at 31,904 (2000) (Revised Filing Requirements). |
|
26 |
|
Id. at 31,911. See also Dominion Resources, Inc. and Consolidated Natural Gas
Company, 89 FERC ¶ 61,162 (1999). |
|
27 |
|
The Natural Gas Act does not grant the Commission authority to examine the
effect of a merger on the horizontal natural gas market. The Natural Gas Act states that [n]o
natural-gas company or person which will be a natural-gas company upon completion of any proposed
construction or extension shall... acquire or operate any such facilities or extensions thereof,
unless there is in force with respect to such natural-gas company a certificate of public
convenience and necessity issued by the Commission authorizing such acts or operation. 15 U.S.C.
§ 717f (c)(1)(a) (2001). |
|
|
|
|
|
Docket Nos. EC05-43-000 and 001 |
|
|
8 |
|
|
E. |
|
Did the Commission Err in Accepting Applicants Proposal to Allocate Transmission
Transfer Capacity on a Pro Rata Basis? |
|
1. |
|
Requests for Rehearing |
23. Hoosier Energy argues that the Commission erred in accepting Applicants allocation in their
study of scarce transmission transfer capability on a pro rata basis. It argues that this method
of allocation creates a bias towards lower HHI estimates in the market analysis by maximizing the
hypothetical participation of all potential competitors, regardless of price.28 Hoosier
Energy argues that the Commission ignored the argument that a least cost access method should be
used to enable low cost suppliers to secure firm transmission rights, thus possibly precluding more
expensive suppliers from access to the market.29
|
2. |
|
Commission Determination |
24. We will deny Hoosier Energys request for rehearing. As we stated in the Merger Order, we are
not persuaded that Applicants should have used an economic (i.e. least cost) allocation rather than
a pro rata allocation of scarce transmission transfer capability in their analysis. We have
accepted the pro rata allocation methodology in numerous merger cases,30 and believe it
reasonably models suppliers ability to compete in a given destination market. Moreover, Hoosiers
argument that the use of the pro rata allocation creates a bias towards lower HHI estimates by
maximizing the hypothetical participation of all potential competitors, regardless of price,
ignores a key feature of the DPT: only sellers with costs within 5 percent of the market price are
assumed to be competing for the scarce transmission capability. All sellers with a profit
opportunity would be competing to sell into the destination market. The pro rata allocation method
recognizes that and gives appropriate weight to the potential sellers based on relative
size.31
|
|
|
28 |
|
Hoosier Energy at 10. |
|
29 |
|
Id. |
|
30 |
|
Order No. 654 at 31,894; Commonwealth Edison, 91 FERC ¶ 61,036 (2000); CP&L
Holdings, 92 FERC ¶ 61,023 (2000). |
|
31 |
|
For example, for simplicity, assume that there are two potential sellers
competing for 1,000 MWs of scarce transmission capability, with 1,500 MWs and 500 MWs of economic
capacity, respectively. The pro rata allocation method would assign 750 MWs and 250 MWs to the two
suppliers, respectively. |
|
|
|
|
|
Docket Nos. EC05-43-000 and 001 |
|
|
9 |
|
|
F. |
|
Should the Commission Have Evaluated Applicants Ability to Engage in
Strategic Bidding? |
|
1. |
|
Requests for Rehearing |
25. NJ Ratepayer Advocate argues that the Commission should have required Applicants to conduct a
further analysis of their ability to engage in strategic bidding. Due to the nature of the Basic
Generation Service auctions and the large market share Applicants will have in New Jersey, NJ
Ratepayer Advocate states that Applicants could engage in strategic bidding in the Basic Generation
Service
auctions and exercise market power. However, the Commission determined that Applicants would not
be able to exercise market power and engage in strategic bidding based on the analysis of the HHI
screen and the Commissions Market Behavior Rules.32
|
2. |
|
Commission Determination |
26. We deny rehearing. Strategic bidding is a form of economic withholding, which is a way of
exercising market power.33 In the Merger Order, we gave two reasons why the Applicants
Appendix A analysis did address the mergers effect on Applicants incentive or ability to engage
in strategic bidding. First, the DOJ Merger Guidelines recognize that the HHI conveys information
about the likelihood of the unilateral exercise of market power.34 Second, in order to
address the screen failures in various season/load conditions, Applicants proposed divesting units
with a range of operational and cost characteristics, including the types of units that protestors
argue could be used to engage in strategic bidding or withholding. Using widely accepted measures
of a mergers effects on competition and the market power of the merged firm, Applicants showed
that the proposed divestiture would mitigate any increase in the merged firms market power and
thus its ability to harm competition through strategic bidding.
|
G. |
|
Did the Commission Employ a Flawed Competitive Analysis? |
|
1. |
|
Requests for Rehearing |
27. PPL argues that the Commission should have required Applicants to address the
|
|
|
32 |
|
NJ Ratepayer Advocate at 6. |
|
33 |
|
Market Behavior Rules, 105 FERC ¶ 61,218 (2003), order on rehg, 107 FERC ¶
61,175 (2004) Rule 2.E prohibits bidding the output of or misrepresenting the operational
capabilities of generation facilities in a manner which raises market prices by withholding
available capacity from the market. |
|
34 |
|
Section 2.0 of the DOJ Merger Guidelines. |
|
|
|
|
|
Docket Nos. EC05-43-000 and 001 |
|
|
10 |
|
concerns PPL raised as to whether Applicants chosen price levels accurately reflected market
prices; instead the Commission accepted Applicants vague response that choosing market prices...
is as much an art as it is a science.35
PPL asserts that the accuracy of Applicants DPT should have been set for hearing.36
|
2. |
|
Commission Determination |
28. We deny PPLs request for rehearing. Applicants supported their DPT by: (1) providing tests of
the sensitivity of their results to changes in the critical parameters in the model; (2) answering
protestors specific questions regarding assumed input prices and wholesale energy market prices;
(3) providing an analysis by PSEGs witness, Mr. Rodney Frame, that confirmed Dr. Hieronymus
results.37 In addition, as we stated in the Merger Order, the PJM MMU Study largely
confirmed the accuracy of Applicants results, finding similar pre-merger and post-merger
concentration levels. PPL has not explained why this was not adequate.
|
H. |
|
Did the Commission Ignore Evidence of Applicants Power Marketing in Analysis? |
|
1. |
|
Requests for Rehearing |
29. Public Citizen argues that the Commission should have discussed the failure of Applicants
market concentration analysis to address Applicants power marketing activities.38
|
|
|
35 |
|
PPL at 33-34. |
|
36 |
|
Id. at 35. |
|
37 |
|
As explained in P 125 of the Merger Order, Dr. Hieronymus; market price
assumptions are consistent in that the assumed market price corresponds with the running costs of
the units most likely to set the market-clearing price in the PJM energy markets for the given
season-load conditions. In addition, the fact that Dr. Hieronymus and Mr. Frame used different
fuel cost and market price assumptions, but arrived at very similar results, indicates that the
results are not sensitive to changes in fuel cost and market price assumptions, and the consistency
of Dr. Hieronymus; results across various assumed market prices shows that the results of the
analysis are robust. |
|
38 |
|
Public Citizen at 16. |
|
|
|
|
|
Docket Nos. EC05-43-000 and 001 |
|
|
11 |
|
|
2. |
|
Commission Determination |
30. We deny Public Citizens request for rehearing. The Appendix A analysis focused on capacity
controlled by all potential sellers in the relevant market. Without control of capacity, whether
through ownership of physical assets or through power purchase agreements, sellers cannot harm
competition in wholesale energy markets. If Applicants (or any other potential suppliers) gain
control of generation capacity through power marketing activities, the Appendix A analysis does
consider power marketing activity, but simply the presence of a large power marketing operation
does not, in itself, confer any additional market power on the merged firm or on any other seller.
|
I. |
|
Did the Commission Improperly Fail to Consider Supplemental Evidence? |
|
1. |
|
Requests for Rehearing |
31. Philadelphia Gas argues that the Commission ignored evidence it submitted pointing out errors
in Applicants analysis that affected the evaluation of the proposed mergers effect on the
delivered gas market in PJM East.39
|
2. |
|
Commission Determination |
32. Comments and protests to the proposed merger were due on or before April 11, 2005. In response
to the numerous comments and protests filed in response to Applicants proposed merger, on May 10,
2005 Applicants made a supplemental filing that amended their proposed analysis and mitigation.
The Commission then provided all parties with an additional opportunity to respond to the
supplemental filing with comments due on or before May 27, 2005. Several parties, including
Philadelphia Gas, filed additional comments in response to Applicants amended filing and many of
the additional comments included lengthy responses to the Applicants amended market power
analysis. However, one month after the comment date had already passed, Philadelphia Gas filed
additional comments disputing Applicants amended market power analysis.
33. The Commission did not accept Philadelphia Gas additional comments due to the lateness of its
filing. The Commission has discretion whether to accept a late-filed answer. After reviewing
Philadelphia Gas June 27, 2005 filing, the Commission determined that it did not provide new
information that would have assisted the Commission in its decision-making process. Therefore, the
Commission properly declined to accept the late-filed comments. However, we note that Philadelphia
Gas arguments actually duplicated arguments raised by FirstEnergy, NJ Ratepayer Advocate
|
|
|
39 |
|
Philadelphia Gas at 19-20. |
|
|
|
|
|
Docket Nos. EC05-43-000 and 001 |
|
|
12 |
|
and Pennsylvania Office of the Consumer Advocate, among others, and those arguments were addressed.
|
J. |
|
Did the Commission Improperly Approve the Merger Based in Part Upon Compliance
Filings and Future Actions? |
|
1. |
|
Requests for Rehearing |
34. Hoosier Energy, PaOCA and Illinois state that the Commission failed to meet the section 203
standard by approving the merger based on its understanding that further mitigation may be
required in the future if the proposed mitigation proves insufficient.40
35. NJBPU argues that the Commission violated section 203 by finding that the proposed merger is
consistent with the public interest after determining that the proposed mitigation and divestiture
may not adequately mitigate the mergers harm to competition.41 NJBPU states that the
Commission requirement of compliance filings to demonstrate that the mitigation actually does
mitigate the harm to competition after the merger has already been consummated does not satisfy the
public interest standard in section 203.42 This would be an after-the-fact
determination that the merger is consistent with the public interest and is contrary to the
requirement that we find that the merger is consistent with the public interest before approving
it.43
36. Based on the Commissions finding that additional mitigation may be required if the mitigation
conditions accepted in the Merger Order are not adequate to remedy the harm to competition,
Philadelphia Gas argues that the Commission has failed to make the statutorily required finding
that the merger is consistent with the public interest .44 Philadelphia Gas contends
that the Commission seeks to hedge its bets in approving the merger by stating its right to
impose additional future mitigation.45 Philadelphia Gas claims that, by asserting its
right to impose future mitigation, the Commission is
|
|
|
40 |
|
Hoosier Energy at 4. |
|
41 |
|
NJBPU at 10. |
|
42 |
|
Id. at 15. |
|
43 |
|
Id. at 16-17. |
|
44 |
|
Philadelphia Gas at 5. |
|
45 |
|
Id. at 7. |
|
|
|
|
|
Docket Nos. EC05-43-000 and 001 |
|
|
13 |
|
admitting that the merger is not in the public interest, even though the Merger Order found that
the merger does satisfy the public interest standard under section 203.46 Finally,
Philadelphia Gas states that it is not clear whether the Commission has the authority to impose
additional mitigation and divestiture obligations.47
|
2. |
|
Commission Determination |
37. Section 203(a) states that if the Commission determines that a proposed merger is consistent
with the public interest, then the Commission shall approve the proposed transaction.48
Section 203(b) clarifies that the Commission may approve a proposed merger upon a finding that it
is consistent with the public interest and ... upon such terms and conditions as it finds
necessary or appropriate to secure the maintenance of adequate service and the coordination in the
public interest of facilities subject to the jurisdiction of the Commission.49 Thus,
while the Commission must find that proposed mergers are consistent with the public interest before
they can be approved, the Commission can do this by imposing conditions and requiring supplemental
filings to demonstrate both that the additional conditions have been met and that the accepted
mitigation is actually ensuring that markets are not harmed.
38. The Commission determined in the Merger Order that the proposed merger of Exelon and PSEG is
consistent with the public interest. However, due to the size of the proposed merger, the
Commission decided to exercise its section 203(b) powers and order compliance filings to ensure
that the mitigation plan proceeds as expected to ensure that market power does not increase. The
Commission retains its right under section 203(b) to order future mitigation, if
necessary, to ensure that the proposed merger and mitigation remain consistent with the public
interest.
39. The Commission has ordered additional filings in previous mergers to ensure that the mitigation
will alleviate market power concerns resulting from the merger. In approving the merger of
American Electric Power Company, Inc. and Central and
|
|
|
46 |
|
Id. at 8. |
|
47 |
|
Id. at 7. |
|
48 |
|
16 U.S.C. § 824b(a) (2001). |
|
49 |
|
16 U.S.C. § 824b(b) (2001). |
|
|
|
|
|
Docket Nos. EC05-43-000 and 001 |
|
|
14 |
|
SouthWest Corporation, for instance, the Commission permitted the companies to divest different
generation upon a compliance filing with the Commission.50
40. Here, the Commission is requiring that Applicants provide compliance filings with an updated
Appendix A analysis upon completion of the divestiture to ensure that the Applicants are fulfilling
their mitigation obligations and to permit the Commission to monitor the market in the wake of the
merger. The compliance filings are just one method the Commission uses to be doubly sure that
market power concerns are resolved.
|
K. |
|
Should the Commission Have Required Applicants to Specify the Units to be
Divested? |
|
1. |
|
Requests for Rehearing |
41. Hoosier Energy states that the Commission did not engage in reasoned decision-making because
the Merger Order did not require Applicants to specify the exact units they plan to divest. The
Commission violated its own Merger Policy Statement51 and regulations, Hoosier Energy
argues, by approving the merger without knowing which specific units Applicants plan to divest.
Hoosier
Energy also states that the Commission did not explain why it did not follow the Merger Policy
Statement or section 33.3 of the Commissions regulations.52
42. NJ Ratepayer Advocate argues that the Commissions approval of the merger without requiring
Applicants to specifically identify the units they will divest raises issues of Applicants market
power and the effectiveness of the proposed mitigation plan.53
|
|
|
50 |
|
American Electric Power Company, Inc., Central and SouthWest Corporation, 100
FERC ¶ 61,316 at P 20 (2002). |
|
51 |
|
Inquiry Concerning the Commissions Merger Policy Under the Federal Power Act:
Policy Statement, Order No. 592, 61 Fed. Reg. 68,595 (1996), FERC Stats. & Regs., Regulations
Preambles July 1996-December 2000 ¶ 31,044 (1996), reconsideration denied, Order No. 592-A, 62 Fed.
Reg. 33,341 (1997), 79 FERC ¶ 61,321 (1997) (Merger Policy Statement). |
|
52 |
|
Hoosier Energy at 6. |
|
53 |
|
NJ Ratepayer Advocate at 14. |
|
|
|
|
|
Docket Nos. EC05-43-000 and 001 |
|
|
15 |
|
43. Philadelphia Gas argues that the Commissions failure to comply with the Merger Policy
Statement and require Applicants to specify exactly which facilities it will divest violated the
FPA and the Administrative Procedure Act54 and was arbitrary, capricious, an abuse of
discretion and a denial of due process.55
44. PPL argues that the Commissions failure to require Applicants to specify which units will be
required for divestiture increases the post-merger market uncertainty. In addition to ignoring the
Commissions Merger Policy Statement, this failure to require specificity also violates practices
of other antitrust enforcement agencies such as the Department of Justice.56 PPL
further argues that not requiring Applicants to specify the units available for divestiture makes
it more difficult for the Commission to determine if the mitigation will actually remedy the
merger-related harm in the Northern New Jersey market.57
|
2. |
|
Commission Determination |
45. We will reject arguments that we should have required Applicants to specify the exact units to
be divested prior to approval. As we stated in the Merger Order, under the Commissions Appendix A
analysis, we need to know the general location (i.e., control area or sub-region of an regional
transmission organization (RTO)) and cost characteristics of the generators being divested not
the actual units in order to calculate the post-merger-and-divestiture Herfindahl-Hirschman
Indexes (HHI) to determine market concentration. 58 Applicants provided that
information and performed the Delivered Price Test (DPT), which calculates the economic capacity of
all sellers in the market based on the running costs of the potential suppliers in the market and
the transmission available to those sellers that could export energy into the market. Generators
in the relevant geographic market are assumed to be able to supply all of their economic capacity
in the market, while those outside the market are assigned a pro rata share of the available import
capacity. The mitigation addresses the screen failures that occurred in the PJM-East, PJM Pre-2004,
and Northern PSEG markets. Therefore, in order to calculate the effectiveness of the mitigation,
we need to know the running costs
|
|
|
54 |
|
5 U.S.C. § 551 et seq. (2005). |
|
55 |
|
Philadelphia Gas at 16-17. |
|
56 |
|
PPL at 30. |
|
57 |
|
Id. at 31. |
|
58 |
|
Merger Order at P. 142. |
|
|
|
|
|
Docket Nos. EC05-43-000 and 001 |
|
|
16 |
|
of the plants to be divested that are in PJM-East, Pre -2004 PJM, or Northern PSEG. We address the
mitigation for the three specific markets below.
46. For PJM-East, the market with the most significant screen failures without mitigation,
Applicants committed to divest 5,500 megawatts (MWs) of generating capacity: 2,400 MWs of nuclear
capacity, 550 MWs of coal-fired capacity, 1,550 MWs of mid-merit capacity, and 1,000 MWs of peaking
capacity. Because of the differences in running costs of the four types of capacity, the amount of
effective mitigation ranges by season/load levels from 2,400 MWs in the winter and shoulder
off-peak periods (when only the nuclear capacity is economic, and
therefore is considered mitigation) to 5,500 MWs in the summer extreme peak period, when all of the
capacity is economic. As a result of the mitigation, the markets are moderately concentrated for
all season/load levels and the change in market concentration does not exceed 100 HHI (the
Commissions threshold for moderately concentrated markets) in any of the season/load levels.
Therefore, as we stated in the Merger Order, Applicants have shown that the proposed mitigation
adequately addresses any merger-related harm to competition in the PJM-East energy market.
47. For the larger PJM Pre-2004 market, which includes PJM-East, in addition to the 5,500 MWs in
PJM-East, Applicants committed to divest 1,100 MWs of generating capacity, consisting of 200 MWs of
nuclear capacity, 150 MWs of coal-fired capacity, 550 MWs of mid-merit capacity, and 200 MWs of
peaking capacity. Because of the differences between running costs of the four types of capacity,
the amount of mitigation ranges by season/load levels from 2,600 MWs in the winter and shoulder
off-peak periods (when only the nuclear capacity is economic, and therefore is considered
mitigation) to 6,600 MWs in the summer extreme peak period, when all of the capacity is economic.
As a result of the mitigation, the markets are either unconcentrated or moderately concentrated for
season/load levels and the change in market concentration does not exceed 100 HHI in any of the
season/load levels. Therefore, as we stated in the Merger Order, Applicants have shown that the
proposed mitigation adequately addresses any merger-related harm to competition in the PJM Pre-2004
energy market.
48. For the smaller Northern PSEG market, Applicants committed to divest 200 MWs of generating
capacity, consisting of 100 MWs of coal-fired capacity and 100 MWs of mid-merit capacity. As a
result of the mitigation, the markets are either unconcentrated or moderately concentrated for all
season/load levels and the change in market concentration does not exceed 100 HHI in any of the
season/load levels. Therefore, as we stated in the Merger Order, Applicants have shown that the
proposed mitigation adequately addresses any merger-related harm to competition in the Northern
PSEG energy market. We note that in the Merger Order, we misstated Applicants commitment as being
a 100 MW divestiture rather than the 200 MWs to which they committed. We
|
|
|
|
|
Docket Nos. EC05-43-000 and 001
|
|
|
17 |
|
clarify that we are relying on Applicants 200 MW mitigation commitment in finding that the
proposed mitigation adequately addresses any merger-related harm to competition in the Northern
PSEG energy market.
49. Applicants divesture commitment also addresses merger-related harm to competition in the
PJM-East capacity market. As with the PJM-East energy markets discussed above, by committing to
divest 5,500 MWs of capacity located within PJM-East, applicants have demonstrated that the
proposed mitigation addresses any merger-related harm to competition in the relevant
market.59
50. Finally, the rehearing requests ignore the fact that, as an additional measure of protection,
Applicants are required to submit a revised Appendix A analysis upon completion of the divestiture.
That analysis will show, given the exact units sold and the identities of the buyers, whether the
divestiture adequately mitigates the merger-related harm to competition. If the divestiture does
not sufficiently reduce market concentration, we will require additional mitigation. Moreover, the
interim mitigation, which adequately addresses the merger-related harm to competition, will remain
in place until Applicants have made an affirmative showing that the divestiture mitigates the harm
to competition the merger otherwise would cause. Therefore, any merger-related harm to competition
will be mitigated from the date of the merger consummation to the time when sufficient permanent
structural mitigation is in place.
|
L. |
|
Did the Commission Err in Accepting Applicants Proposal for
Virtual Divestiture? |
|
1. |
|
Requests for Rehearing |
51. Hoosier Energy challenges the Commissions approval of Applicants proposal to treat their
long-term energy sales as virtual divestiture. Specifically, it argues that the Commission
ignores Applicants ability to maintain control over this virtually divested capacity through
scheduling outages for maintenance and refueling.60 Hoosier Energy also argues that
Applicants will be able to raise short-term energy market prices, which would, in turn, result in
higher prices for long-term energy sales from the virtual divestiture.61
|
|
|
59 |
|
Dr. Hieronymuss analysis of the PJM-East capacity market shows that 5,325 MWs
of capacity needs to be divested in order to restore market concentration to within the
Commissions screening threshold of the pre-merger concentration. Exhibit J-21. |
|
60 |
|
Hoosier Energy at 8. |
|
61 |
|
Id. at 9. |
|
|
|
|
|
Docket Nos. EC05-43-000 and 001
|
|
|
18 |
|
52. PaOCA, Illinois, NJ Ratepayer Advocate and PPL argue that the Commissions approval of the
virtual divestiture plan is not consistent with the Merger Policy Statement or with the DOJ Merger
Guidelines,62 and thus, is not reasoned decision-making.63 PaOCA also argues
that the virtual divestiture will allow Applicants to retain full operational control of the
nuclear units, where the Applicants can control retirement and expansion of
facilities.64 Finally, PaOCA states that Applicants have not demonstrated that the
proposed virtual divestiture plan will be effective or sufficient in mitigating the merger-related
harm.65
|
2. |
|
Commission Determination |
53. Hoosier Energys argument that Applicants will be able to raise short-term energy market
prices, which would, in turn, result in higher prices for long-term energy sales from the virtual
divestiture, ignores that fact that Applicants do not have market
power in the short-term energy
market. The merger-related harm to competition is mitigated by the divestiture of 6,600 MWs of
generation in the PJM markets. In addition, in order to obtain market-based rate authority,
Applicants have previously shown that they lack market power in the relevant markets. Therefore,
Applicants lack the market power would need to effect the strategy proposed by Hoosier Energy.
Hoosier Energys argument is circular; it concludes that the mitigation will not be effective based
on its assumption that it will not be effective.
54. We also reject Hoosier Energys argument that Applicants will be able to maintain control over
this virtually divested capacity by the way they schedule outages. Hoosier ignores the fact that
Applicants commitment is to provide 2,400 MWs of baseload energy, not energy from a specific
nuclear unit. If the merged company withheld output by strategic outages for maintenance or
refueling of a specific nuclear unit, it would to provide baseload energy from another source at
the long-term contract price; therefore, there can be no net withholding of baseload capacity.
|
|
|
62 |
|
U.S. Department of Justice and Federal Trade Commission, Horizontal Merger
Guidelines, 57 Fed. Reg. 41,552, Sec. 2.0 (1992), revised, 4 Trade Reg. Rep (CCH) ¶ 13,104 (April
8, 1997) (DOJ Merger Guidelines). |
|
63 |
|
PaOCA at 15. |
|
64 |
|
Id. at 16. |
|
65 |
|
Id. |
|
|
|
|
|
Docket Nos. EC05-43-000 and 001
|
|
|
19 |
|
55. We also reject arguments that the virtual divestiture is inconsistent with the Merger Policy
Statement. The Merger Policy Statement recognizes that there are a number of ways to mitigate
merger-related increases in market power.66 In a horizontal merger such as this, the
elimination of a competitor may harm competition by increasing the merged firms ability to raise
price by withholding output. The virtual divestiture ensures that 2,400 MWs of baseload energy
will, in fact, be available at all times, so the Applicants will not be able to withhold output.
56. The arguments that the merged firm will have the ability and incentive to withhold the output
of nuclear plants make little economic sense. As we have stated in a number of cases, the
operational characteristics of, and regulatory scrutiny over, nuclear units virtually eliminates
the possibility of withholding output to drive up prices.67 Profit-maximizing firms may
have the incentive to withhold marginal units in order to increase the price they receive on other
sales, but withholding the output of low variable cost nuclear units would rarely be profitable.
PP&L argues that our approval of virtual divestiture fails to consider several key attributes of
ownership that would permit Applicants to retain control over the virtually divested units: (1)
perfect knowledge of the condition and operation of each nuclear unit; (2) the ability to control
the units maintenance schedules; (3) the timing of shutdown and restart after maintenance; and (4)
the timing of restart after an unscheduled outage. Applicants will retain those attributes of
ownership, but as we stated in the Merger Order, the terms of the baseload energy sales, along with
the operational characteristics and profitability of running nuclear units, eliminate the ability
and incentive to use those attributes of ownership to adversely affect competition. Regarding the
key attributes of ownership referred to PPL, the contractual provisions in the energy sales,
discussed in P134 of the Merger Order, along with the auction manager, the independent auction
monitor, and the Public Compliance Website, ensure that the merged firm will not be able to use its
retained ownership to affect the energy sales themselves.
57. PPL argues that the Commission will have to constantly supervise the virtual divestiture to
ensure that it adequately mitigates any merger-related harm to competition However, we addressed
that issue in detail in the Merger Order. We relied, in part, on Applicants commitments to
establish: (1) an independent monitor to oversee the baseload auction and Applicants compliance
with the long-term energy contracts; and (2) a public compliance website that will show how they
are complying with the virtual divestiture and other mitigation requirements. We directed
Applicants to make a compliance filing within 30 days of the Merger Order detailing the process for
the
|
|
|
66 |
|
Merger Policy Statement at 30,136 137. |
|
67 |
|
See Commonwealth Edison Co., 91 FERC ¶ 61,036 (2000). |
|
|
|
|
|
Docket Nos. EC05-43-000 and 001
|
|
|
20 |
|
selection of the independent monitor. On August 1, 2005, Applicants submitted a compliance
filing addressing their commitment to retain an independent party to administer the baseload
energy auction as well as a template for their Public Compliance Website. In that filing, Applicants stated
that they would add an additional layer of independence by hiring both an auction manager and an
independent auction monitor.
68
|
M. |
|
Did the Commission Err in Reasoning that the Merger Will Not Harm
Competition Because Mitigation Will Restore HHIs to Minimum Pre-Merger
Levels? |
|
1. |
|
Requests for Rehearing |
58. PaOCA and Illinois argue that the Commission erred in relying only on its analysis of the
post-merger and mitigation HHI levels in evaluating the mergers
effect on competition, given
Applicants proposed mitigation. According to PaOCA, the Commission relies upon the
post-mitigation HHI that simply restores the HHIs to the bare minimum to avoid screen violations, as
the foundation for its finding that Applicants have met their burden for the Commission to approve the
proposed
merger.69
PaOCA argues that there are many other factors that the Commission
should have
considered.70
|
2. |
|
Commission Determination |
59.
We reject this argument. As we state in P 132 of the Merger Order,
there are a number of ways to
mitigate increases in market power (such as generation divestiture, transmission expansion, or behavioral
measures such as must-offer requirements), and we have imposed
various forms of market power mitigation depending on the
circumstances. The key element of any mitigation plan is addressing
the specific harm to competition that
could result from a transaction. In the Merger Order, we explained
that Applicants proposal to divest
sufficient capacity to reduce market concentration enough to pass the screen is a reasonable way to
mitigate the merger-related harm to competition. This is because the HHI conveys information about the
likelihood of both coordinated and unilateral exercises of market power the exact harm to
competition that could result from a large horizontal merger such as the one before us. Moreover, in a
straightforward horizontal merger, where market concentration
(rather than other competitive issues such as transmission
access or barriers to entry) is the key issue, divesting sufficient
generation to restore pre-merger levels
of market concentration is appropriate mitigation.
|
|
|
68 |
|
August 1 Compliance Filing, pp 4-8, Docket No. EC05-43-000. |
|
69 |
|
PaOCA at 11. |
|
70 |
|
Id. at 12. |
|
|
|
|
|
Docket Nos. EC05-43-000 and 001
|
|
|
21 |
|
|
N. |
|
Did the Commission Err in Approving a Megawatt-for-Megawatt Reduction in Baseload
Energy Mitigation? |
|
1. |
|
Requests for Rehearing |
60. Hoosier Energy challenges the Commissions decision to allow Applicants to reduce their
required baseload energy mitigation megawatt-for-megawatt (MW-for-MW) for any reduction in their
nuclear generating capacity due to derating, decommissioning or sales of nuclear capacity in the
PJM East market. It states that the Commissions approval of this MW-for-MW reduction assumes that
all of any increased nuclear capacity would be used by entities other than the Applicants
themselves.71 Hoosier Energy argues that there is no evidentiary basis for this
assumption.72
61. PPL argues that allowing Applicants to reduce mitigation requirements MW-for-MW for any retired
nuclear assets is an error. PPL states that allowing such a reduction based on retirement is
tantamount to withholding capacity from the market and should not be the basis for a reduction in
mitigation obligations. Thus, PPL argues that Applicants should not be able to reduce their
mitigation obligations MW-for-MW based on retirement of facilities.73
62. APPA/NRECA states that derating or retirement of Applicants nuclear generation capacity should
not allow a MW-for-MW reduction in baseload energy mitigation.74 Rather, APPA/NRECA
argue that Applicants should be required to demonstrate that the existing mitigation is appropriate
in the event of an unforeseen derating or retirement of some part of Applicants nuclear generating
capacity.75
|
|
|
71 |
|
Hoosier Energy at 11. |
|
72 |
|
Id. |
|
73 |
|
PPL at 32. |
|
74 |
|
APPA/NRECA at 16. |
|
75 |
|
Id. at 17-18. |
|
|
|
|
|
Docket Nos. EC05-43-000 and 001
|
|
|
22 |
|
|
2. |
|
Commission Determination |
63. We deny rehearing requests regarding the MW-for-MW reduction in baseload energy mitigation for
increases in import capacity into PJM East. As we stated in the Merger Order, increasing transfer
capability into PJM East would enable competitive suppliers to defeat attempts to increase prices
there. In fact, in Oklahoma Gas and Electric Company, we found that a transmission expansion
mitigated the increase in market power associated the elimination of a rival generator. 76
If the merger eliminates competitor in PJM-East, a transmission expansion would create new
competitive alternatives to offset the mergers effect.
64.
We also deny rehearing requests regarding the MW-for-MW reduction in
baseload energy mitigation for any
de-rating or retirements of Applicants nuclear plants. As we stated in the Merger Order, Applicants
made a convincing argument that a decrease in their nuclear capacity would mitigate market power,
because the incentive to exercise market power is directly related to the amount of inframarginal
capacity they control that could benefit from higher prices. For the numerous reasons discussed in the
Merger Order (e.g. operational realities, regulatory oversight, and profit-maximization) the merger
did not increase Applicants ability or incentive to withhold nuclear capacity; rather, it increased their incentive
to withhold marginal capacity in order to increase their profits from baseload sales. Even if
operationally feasible, withholding output from low cost nuclear units would rarely be profitable. We
agreed with Applicants argument that the incentive to withhold output of marginal units is a function
of the amount of baseload capacity from which the merged firm could
profit due to higher energy prices. Therefore,
reducing the amount of baseload capacity under Applicants control would reduce their incentive to
withhold marginal capacity in order to raise the market price, which is the key concern in a
horizontal merger creating a large supplier with a large portfolio of generation capacity along all
portions of the supply curve.
|
O. |
|
Did the Commission Fail to Appropriately Evaluate the Northern PSEG Market? |
|
1. |
|
Requests for Rehearing |
65. NJ Ratepayer Advocate challenges the Commissions decision that Applicants commitment to
divest 100 MW of generation in the Northern PSEG market would remedy any concentration issue in
that market.77 It contends that Applicants did not
|
|
|
76 |
|
Oklahoma Gas and Electric Company, 108 FERC ¶ 61,044 at P 32 (2004) (OG&E). |
|
77 |
|
NJ Ratepayer Advocate at 11. |
Docket Nos. EC05-43-000 and 001 |
|
|
23 |
explicitly commit to divesting 100 MW of generation from the Northern PSEG market, so the
Commission erred in approving the merger based on the vague mention of this
divestiture.78
|
2. |
|
Commission Determination |
66. We reject NJ Ratepayer Advocates argument that Applicants failed to show that the merger would
not harm competition in the Northern PSEG. As discussed in P 32 above, Applicants committed to
divest 200 MWs of generating capacity consisting of 100 MWs of coal-fired capacity and 100 MWs of
mid-merit capacity in the Northern PSEG market. We relied on that commitment in making our finding
that the merger would not adversely affect competition. As a result of the mitigation, the markets
will be unconcentrated or moderately concentrated for all season/load levels and the change in
market concentration does not exceed 100 HHI in any of the season/load levels. Therefore, as we
stated in the Merger Order, Applicants have shown that the proposed mitigation adequately addresses any merger-related harm to
competition in the Northern PSEG energy market.
|
P. |
|
Does the Commission Lack Jurisdiction Over Key Aspects of the Mitigation
Plan? |
|
1. |
|
Requests for Rehearing |
67. Public Citizen claims that EPAct 2005 will lead to a corrosion of the required mitigation by
altering the Commissions jurisdiction over generation, which could permit Applicants to simply
reacquire divested facilities and generation without Commission approval.79
|
2. |
|
Commission Determination |
68. While the new section 203 language in EPAct 2005 increases the monetary value required for
Commission authorization of the disposition of facilities, as a practical matter, the increased
dollar threshold will easily be met in most cases. Particularly in the geographic markets at issue
in this transaction, any generation facility that would sell for less than $10 million would be de
minimis. Therefore, we do not believe that the new $10 million threshold under section 203 would
lead to Applicants ability to buy back divested generation without Commission approval.
Additionally, the new statute provides the Commission with greater authority in some respects,
since we have authority
|
|
|
78 |
|
Id. |
|
79 |
|
Public Citizen at 17. |
|
|
|
|
|
Docket Nos. EC05-43-000 and 001
|
|
|
24 |
|
over the disposition of facilities involving generation only, which we did not have under pre-EPAct
2005 section 203.80
|
Q. |
|
Should the Commission Clarify the Timing and Content of the Required Compliance
Filings? |
|
1. |
|
Requests for Rehearing |
69. In order to ensure that the Commission can verify that the mitigation eliminates the
merger-related increase in market concentration, APPA/NRECA requests that the Commission require
Applicants to file a single, comprehensive Appendix A market analysis of the generation
divestitures before the divestitures begin and then another compliance filing demonstrating that the required divestitures have been
completed.81 This would ensure that Applicants are meeting all their
obligations.82
70. Similarly, APPA/NRECA argues that the Commission should establish a strict deadline for
Applicants to complete generation divestitures, with consequences for failure to meet that
deadline.83
71. APPA/NRECA also requests that the Commission establish a specific procedure for Applicants
divestiture of generation, such as requiring Applicants to auction off the pool of generating units
they have identified as eligible for divestiture and appointing an independent auction monitor to
oversee the auction process and ensure the transparency and fairness of the auction.84
|
2. |
|
Commission Determination |
72. We find the requests of APPA/NRECA reasonable. The Commission required Applicants to make
compliance filings to ensure that the mitigation is alleviating market power concerns. Requiring
Applicants to file a comprehensive Appendix A analysis
|
|
|
80 |
|
Energy Policy Act of 2005 §§ 261 et seq., Pub. L. No. 109-58, 199 Stat 594
(2005). |
|
81 |
|
APPA/NRECA at 8. |
|
82 |
|
Id. at 9. |
|
83 |
|
Id. at 10. |
|
84 |
|
Id. at 13-14. |
|
|
|
|
|
Docket Nos. EC05-43-000 and 001
|
|
|
25 |
|
before the generation divestitures begin will provide the Commission with a solid basis on which to
analyze the progress of the mitigation. Similarly, after the required divestitures are complete,
the Commission will require Applicants to make another filing to demonstrate that the divestitures
have complied with the necessary actions ordered by the Commission.
73. On August 1, 2005, Applicants submitted a compliance filing that outlined the baseload energy
auction and explained the independent oversight of the auction through an auction manager and an independent auction monitor to serve as an additional
layer or independence in the baseload energy auction. The City of Philadelphia protested the
compliance filing and argued that the plan did not contain any requirement that the auction manager
and independent auction monitor not have any ownership interests in one another and will not
collude in the auction proceedings. The City of Philadelphia requests that we require Applicants
to include language in the agreements that neither the auction manager nor the independent auction
monitor will have ownership interests in one another and will not collude in the auction
proceedings. We find the City of Philadelphias request reasonable and will require Applicants to
provide a new agreement with such language incorporated.
74.
Additionally, we find that Applicants compliance filing addresses APPA/NRECAs concerns about the independence and transparency of the auction process. Therefore,
that aspect of APPA/NRECAs request for rehearing is moot.
|
R. |
|
Did the Commission Accept Unsupported Claims of Benefits? |
|
1. |
|
Requests for Rehearing |
75. PaOCA and Illinois argue that the Commission approved the merger based, in part, on unsupported
evidence offered by Applicants that the proposed merger benefits the public interest. While
Applicants claim that the merger will provide benefits to the public interest, such as lower costs,
higher capacity and greater stability in the electricity market, PaOCA asserts that Applicants fail
to produce substantial evidence to support these claims.85 It argues that Applicants
did not demonstrate that the claimed benefits and efficiencies could only result from the proposed
merger, as allegedly required under the Commissions Merger Policy Statement and the DOJ Merger
Guidelines.86
|
|
|
85 |
|
PaOCA at 17. |
|
86 |
|
Id. at 17-18. |
|
|
|
|
|
Docket Nos. EC05-43-000 and 001
|
|
|
26 |
|
|
2. |
|
Commission Determination |
76. The Commission approved the merger under the standard set forth in section 203 of the FPA, upon
a finding that the proposed merger is consistent with the public interest. The Commission
determined that, based on the market analysis and Applicants proposed mitigation, Applicants
demonstrated that the proposed merger would not adversely affect competition, rates or regulation.
PaOCA and Illinois are correct that Applicants cite a more efficient nuclear operation, which would
provide the market with increased energy for sale in the PJM wholesale market, as one of the chief
benefits of the merger. However, we did not rely on Applicants efficiency argument in our
conclusion that the merger, as mitigated, would not harm competition in any relevant wholesale
market. Therefore, Applicants did not need to make a showing that efficiency gains from the merger
would benefit the public interest in order for us to conclude that the merger is consistent with
the public interest.
|
S. |
|
Whether the Commission Should Have Expanded Its Analysis Beyond the Merger Policy
Statement |
|
1. |
|
Requests for Rehearing |
77. Philadelphia Gas argues that the Commissions refusal to consider elements of the public
interest beyond those described in the [Merger Policy Statement] was arbitrary, capricious, an
abuse of discretion and a violation of section 557(c)(3)(A) of the Administrative Procedure
Act.87 Among the public interest elements Philadelphia Gas claims that the Commission
ignored are the effects the merger may have on the price and availability of natural gas in the
Philadelphia area, the Philadelphia area spot market for natural gas and the price of electricity
in the Philadelphia area.88
|
2. |
|
Commission Determination |
78. Under the Commissions Merger Policy Statement, the Commission generally evaluates three
factors in determining whether a proposed merger is consistent with the public interest: the
proposed mergers effect on competition, on rates and on regulation.89 While these
three factors are generally the basis for the Commissions determination, each of these three
general factors consider many specific circumstances that influence the Commissions analysis.
Among those additional circumstances are the
|
|
|
87 |
|
Philadelphia Gas at 13. |
|
88 |
|
Id. at 11. |
|
89 |
|
Merger Policy Statement at 30,111. |
|
|
|
|
|
Docket Nos. EC05-43-000 and 001
|
|
|
27 |
|
proposed mergers effects on markets and market concentration in the relevant geographic and
product markets, the possibility of unnecessary rate increases and additional ratepayer protection
stemming from the proposed merger and the impact of the merger on state regulation.
79. Specifically, in our review of the mergers effect on competition in wholesale electricity
markets, we considered Applicants and intervenors analysis of the relevant upstream natural gas
markets and concluded that Applicants had shown that the upstream natural gas markets were not
highly concentrated, a necessary condition for the concerns about natural gas prices and
availability expressed by Philadelphia Gas. Regarding the price of electricity in the Philadelphia
area, we did find that the merger, as mitigated, would not harm competition in PJM-East, where
Philadelphia is located. To the extent Philadelphia Gas is referring to retail electricity prices
in Philadelphia, we found that the merger would not adversely affect regulation in any state,
including Pennsylvania.
80. Philadelphia Gas argues that the Commission violated section 557(c)(3)(A) of the Administrative
Procedure Act. Section 557(c)(3)(A) states that the Commission must include a statement of the
findings and conclusions and a basis for the decision on all issues of law or fact discussed in the
record. Throughout the 75 page Merger Order, the Commission explained the basis for its decision
to approve the merger as consistent with the public interest. The Commission explained in the
discussion of each issue how its decision was consistent with and based on the analysis of the
Merger Policy Statement and other antitrust principles. Therefore, the Commission did provide a
basis for the conclusions of each decision on all issues of law and fact discussed in the record,
as required by section 557(c)(3)(A) of the Administrative Procedure Act.
|
T. |
|
Should the Commission Consider the Effect on Regulation of the Repeal of
PUHCA? |
|
1. |
|
Requests for Rehearing |
81. Public Citizen argues that the Commission should analyze the effect that the repeal of the
PUHCA 193590 would have on the regulation of the merger. It states that the Commission
shifted the question of effective regulation to the NJBPU and other state commissions. Upon the
repeal of PUHCA, no federal or state body will have jurisdiction over the finances of the
interstate holding companies and their interactions with utility subsidiaries.91
|
|
|
90 |
|
15 U.S.C. §§ 79 et seq. |
|
91 |
|
Public Citizen at 14. |
|
|
|
|
|
Docket Nos. EC05-43-000 and 001
|
|
|
28 |
|
82. Similarly, NJBPU also argues that the Commission failed to evaluate the effect the PUHCA 1935
repeal would have on the states regulation and review of this merger. While the NJBPU intends to
consider the effect the repeal of PUHCA 1935 may have and any changes in the regulation that may be
necessary, NJBPU argues that the Commission erred in failing to conduct such an
evaluation.92
|
2. |
|
Commission Determination |
83. The Commission approved this merger on June 30, 2005; PUHCA 1935 was in effect at that time and
the Commission took account of that fact.93
84. Effective February 8, 2006, the Energy Policy Act of 2005, replaces PUHCA 1935 with PUHCA
2005.94 The Commission issued an order repealing PUCHA 1935 and implementing PUHCA
2005.95
85. The Commission cannot make decisions based on what laws Congress may enact; we can only
regulate according to those laws that exist when we make our decisions. At the time the Commission
approved Applicants merger, PUHCA 1935 was in effect and the Commission considered the effect that
PUHCA 1935 would have on the proposed transaction.96
|
U. |
|
Did the Commission Improperly Rely on State Regulation to Ensure Just & Reasonable
Wholesale Rates? |
|
1. |
|
Requests for Rehearing |
86. Public Citizen argues that the merger will lead to higher rates for residential customers, and
that residential consumers will have no alternatives to the higher
|
|
|
92 |
|
NJBPU at 46. |
|
93 |
|
Merger Order at P 217. |
|
94 |
|
Energy Policy Act of 2005 (EPAct 2005) §§ 261 et seq., Pub. L. No. 109-58, 199
Stat. 594 (2005). |
|
95 |
|
Order No. 667, Repeal of the Public Utility Holding Company Act of 1935 and
Enactment of the Public Utility Holding Company Act of 2005, 113 FERC ¶ 61,248 (2005). |
|
96 |
|
Merger Order at 72-3. |
|
|
|
|
|
Docket Nos. EC05-43-000 and 001
|
|
|
29 |
|
wholesale prices created by the market power of the Exelon-PSEG merger.97 It accuses
the Commission of abdicating its responsibility to ensure just and reasonable wholesale rates to
the relevant state commissions.98
|
2. |
|
Commission Determination |
87. We deny Public Citizens rehearing request on two grounds. First, as discussed above and in
the Merger Order, we find that the increased market power that would otherwise occur will be
mitigated by the various required divestitures. Therefore, we do not agree that there will be
higher wholesale prices created by the market power of the Exelon-PSEG merger. Second,
Applicants have committed to hold wholesale customers harmless from any merger-related costs that
exceed demonstrated merger-related benefits and we have found that such a commitment protects
customers.99
|
V. |
|
Did the Commission Improperly Accept Applicants May 10, 2005 Answer as an Amendment
to the Filing? |
88. Philadelphia Gas argues that the Commission violated its own regulations, the FPA and the
Administrative Procedure Act in treating Applicants May 10, 2005 answer as an amendment under Rule
215 of the Commissions regulations rather than as an answer under Rule 213.100
|
2. |
|
Commission Determination |
89. Applicants May 10, 2005 filing responded to many concerns raised by protestors by clarifying
Applicants market power analysis and offering additional mitigation. Such an amendment to a
pleading is permitted under rule 215(a)(3)(i) of the Commissions regulations.101
|
|
|
97 |
|
Public Citizen at 16. |
|
98 |
|
Id. |
|
99 |
|
Merger Policy Statement at 30,124. |
|
100 |
|
18 C.F.R. § 385.215 and § 385.213 (2005). |
|
101 |
|
18 C.F.R. § 385.215(a)(3) (2005). |
|
|
|
|
|
Docket Nos. EC05-43-000 and 001
|
|
|
30 |
|
90. While Applicants titled their May 10, 2005 filing an Answer, in fact it contained new
information. Therefore, under Rule 215, the Commission accepted the filing as an amendment and
provided an opportunity to comment on it, which benefited all parties.
|
W. |
|
Did the Commission Violate Ex Parte Rules and the Administrative Procedure Act by
Holding Pre-Filing Meetings with Applicants? |
|
1. |
|
Requests for Rehearing |
91. Public Citizen and Illinois argue that the Commission should have discussed in the Merger Order
their objections to pre-filing meetings between the Commissioners and Applicants.102 It
claims that the failure to produce a record of these meetings violates the parties rights under
the Administrative Procedure Act,103 to an impartial decision maker. Without a record
of these meetings, the public has no way of knowing that the Commissioners are not
biased.104
|
2. |
|
Commission Determination |
92. We reject Public Citizens argument that the Commissioners pre-filing meetings were in
violation of either the Commissions own regulations or the APA. First, the regulations prohibit
off-the-record communications in any contested on-the-record proceedings.105 The
regulations define a contested on-the-record proceeding as any proceeding before the Commission
to which there is a right to intervene and in which an intervenor
disputes any material issue ...106 The regulations prohibit such off-the-record
|
|
|
102 |
|
Public Citizen at 4. |
|
103 |
|
5 U.S.C. § 551 et seq. (2005). |
|
104 |
|
Public Citizen at 9. |
|
105 |
|
18 C.F.R. § 385.2201(a) (2005). |
|
106 |
|
18 C.F.R. § 385.2201 (c)(1) (2005). In Order No. 607, the final rule
implementing the Commissions ex parte rules, we noted that [t]he explicit requirement that the
proceeding be contested before ex parte rules attach reflects the notion that procedural
requirements and constraints originally developed to preserve the rights of parties in an
adjudication have no place in an administrative proceeding in which there is no contest
comparable to the controversy in a judicial case. Regulations Governing Off-the-Record
Communications, Order No. 607, FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 31,079 at 30,881, 64 Fed. Reg. 51,222 at
51,230 (1999). |
|
|
|
|
|
Docket Nos. EC05-43-000 and 001
|
|
|
31 |
|
communications in a contested on-the-record proceeding from the time of filing of an intervention
disputing any material fact that is the subject of a proceeding.107
93. At the time that employees of the Applicants met with the Commissioners, the Commissions
prohibition against off-the-record communications did not apply because there was no proceeding
whatsoever, much less a contested on-the-record proceeding, nor were there any parties. As the
prohibition against off-the-record communications did not apply at this point, we find that the
Commissioners acted according to the rules set forth in the Commissions regulations.
94. Second, we reject Public Citizens argument that any pre-filing meetings between the
Commissioners and the Applicants violated the APA because, when the pre-filing meetings occurred,
there was no proceeding, so the pre-filing meeting was not an ex parte communication. The APA
defines an ex parte communication as an oral or written communication not on the public record
with respect to which reasonable prior notice to all parties is not given.108 A
party is a person or agency named or admitted as a party, or properly seeking and entitled as of
right to be admitted as a party, in an agency proceeding.109 Prior to filing, as there
was no Commission proceeding, the APAs prohibition on ex parte communication could not apply.
Public Citizens protest would effectively read out of the statute the requirement that there be an
agency proceeding to which parties are named, admitted, or are entitled as of right to seek
admission, and we must therefore reject it as inconsistent with the APAs definition of ex parte
communication. Furthermore, we note that Public Citizen makes no effort to explain when, in its
view of the APA, a proceeding begins. Under Public Citizens view, there is no limit to how
early a proceeding begins.
95. In Order No. 607, we similarly concluded that pre-filing meetings are not ex parte
communications, as defined by the APA. In the Notice of Proposed Rulemaking underlying that order,
the Commission proposed to explicitly provide an exemption for pre-filing meetings.110
However, we determined in Order No. 607 that no pre-filing
|
|
|
107 |
|
18 C.F.R. § 385.2201(d)(1)(iv) (2005). |
|
108 |
|
5 U.S.C. § 551(14) (2000) (emphasis added). |
|
109 |
|
5 U.S.C. § 551(3) (2000) (Emphasis added). |
|
110 |
|
Regulations Governing Off-the-Record Communications, Notice of Proposed
Rulemaking, FERC Stats. & Regs. ¶ 32,534 at 33,506-07 (1998) (pre-filing communications are often
useful in educating applicants as to the appropriate format, content, and form that an application
or other filing should take. Such consultations can therefore improve the chances that filings,
once made, will be ready for evaluation on the merits.). |
|
|
|
|
|
Docket Nos. EC05-43-000 and 001
|
|
|
32 |
|
exemption was necessary and thus that pre-filing communications were not covered by the APA
prohibition on ex parte communications because they take place prior to the filing of an
application, and therefore prior to any proceeding at the Commission.111
96. Public Citizen cites Electric Power Supply Association v. FERC112 to support its
argument that the Commissioners pre-filing meetings violated the APA. However, EPSA v. FERC dealt
with ex parte communications related to a specific pending on-the-record proceeding and
post-filing meetings. The Court indicated in EPSA v. FERC that the overriding concern of section
557 is to ensure that an adequate record exists for purposes of judicial review and that the
fairness of the proceedings is above reproach.113 In the situation at hand, there was no
pending on-the-record proceeding because no application had yet been filed. Therefore, the APA
was not violated.
97. Finally, we note that the current proceeding is not the proper venue for Public Citizen to
challenge the validity of the Commissions regulations; its arguments are, in fact, a collateral
attack on those regulations. We will not ignore our regulations because a party to a specific case
argues that the regulations are invalid. If Public Citizen believes that the Commission should
amend its regulations, Public Citizen should submit a petition for rulemaking setting forth the
changes it believes are necessary.114
The
Commission orders:
(A) Parties requests for rehearing are hereby denied.
(B) Applicants are ordered to submit the required updated market analysis and compliance
filings, as discussed in the body of this order.
(C) The Commission clarifies that we rely on Applicants 200 MW mitigation commitment in
finding that the proposed mitigation adequately addresses any merger-related harm to competition in
the Northern PSEG energy market.
|
|
|
111 |
|
Order No. 607 at 30,879. |
|
112 |
|
Electric Power Supply Association v. FERC, 391 F.3d 1255 (2004) (EPSA v. FERC). |
|
113 |
|
EPSA v. FERC, 391 F.3d at 1266 (2004). |
|
114 |
|
18 C.F.R. § 385.207(a)(4) (2005). |
|
|
|
|
|
Docket Nos. EC05-43-000 and 001
|
|
|
33 |
|
(D) The Commission hereby accepts Applicants August 1, 2005 compliance filing, as discussed
in the body of this order.
By the Commission.
( S E A L )
Magalie R. Salas,
Secretary.